Giles Thompson - ‘To what extent should the current African commodity boom be viewed in a positive...

5
Giles Thompson ‘To what extent should the current African commodity boom be viewed in a positive light?’ The Politics of SubSaharan Africa Word count: 1993 1 The commodity boom has expedited Africa’s 4.9% GDP rise between 20002008 (MGI, 2010: 2), and has provoked recent claims that ‘celebrations are in order on the poorest continent’ (The Economist, 2013). These claims are too positive; they overlook the extensive costs that commodity exportation incurs. The African commodity boom, which I define as the incremental increase in market price of both oil and minerals in the first decade of this millennium, must be viewed in a predominantly negative light. The surge in price of SubSaharan African (hereafter SSA) commodities, incentivises increased extraction and export of these natural commodities. This shortterm incentive does not account for the incrementally negative effect that increased resource extractionspecialisation has on longterm economic growth and the resulting economic divergence between SSA (as extractioneconomies) and the developed world (as centres of manufacturing). The shortterm economic growth that’s fuelled by extraction is also a misleading indicator of success, diverting attention from this concerning trend of divergence. Despite this reality, if one accepts that the boom’s impact is so substantial that the overall impact of the boom is inexorably negative, one can still cautiously identify qualified positives. Increased government tax revenue from boom has resulted in qualified positive impacts for SSA, because it provides opportunities. However, in SSA, substantial structural obstacles have pervasively prevented these positive opportunities from being materially realised. Even so, these opportunities are sometimes materially realised, despite structural obstacles, when agency triumphs over structure. Examples of this agency are: forwardthinking government policymaking and the ‘benevolent’ infrastructural positiveexternalities of Chinese foreign investment in SSA. In addition, qualified positive opportunities that the commodity boom presents are: opportunity for increased public spending on public services in order to benefit the poor, and opportunity to pursue diversification (and subsequent reduction in exposure to fluctuations in the market price of commodities). The first qualified positive is the opportunity for increased public spending on public services in order to benefit the poor. Most countries in SSA have tax bases that are ‘built overwhelmingly on [commodity] exports’ (Leonard and Straus 2003: 12). The boom raises additional tax revenue that could potentially benefit the poor through immediate spending on vital services such as hospital and schools. Importantly, this extra revenue also gives opportunity for more government investment for the future, as in ‘resourcerich societies, investment is particularly important since this is how resource surplus can be transformed into sustained increases in income’ (Collier, 2007: 44). These opportunities have been largely squandered in SSA due to the structural obstacle of ‘neo patrimonialism’. In neopatrimonialism, power is exercised ‘through the informal sector’ in a system of ‘political reciprocity which link[s] patrons with their clients along vertical social lines’ (Chabal, 2002: 450). In this system, government tax revenue is misappropriated and used as political patronage by public officials, to gain political loyalty from ‘clients’. The extra revenue generated by the boom is particularly hard to trace account for, and this helps engender informal misappropriation of government funds. This misappropriation occurred in Nigeria for instance. Nigeria borrowed heavily during the boom in the 1980s and undertook ‘massively wasteful projects saturated with corruption’ to facilitate patronage, and consequently, Nigerian living standards ‘approximately halved’

Transcript of Giles Thompson - ‘To what extent should the current African commodity boom be viewed in a positive...

Giles  Thompson  -­‐  ‘To  what  extent  should  the  current  African  commodity  boom  be  viewed  in  a  positive  light?’  The  Politics  of  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa  -­‐  Word  count:  1993  

  1  

The  commodity  boom  has  expedited  Africa’s  4.9%  GDP  rise  between  2000-­‐2008  (MGI,  2010:  2),  and  has  provoked  recent  claims  that  ‘celebrations  are  in  order  on  the  poorest  continent’  (The  Economist,  2013).  These  claims  are  too  positive;  they  overlook   the   extensive   costs   that   commodity   exportation   incurs.   The   African  commodity  boom,  which  I  define  as  the  incremental  increase  in  market  price  of  both  oil  and  minerals  in  the  first  decade  of  this  millennium,  must  be  viewed  in  a  predominantly   negative   light.   The   surge   in   price   of   Sub-­‐Saharan   African  (hereafter   SSA)   commodities,   incentivises   increased   extraction   and   export   of  these   natural   commodities.   This   short-­‐term   incentive   does   not   account   for   the  incrementally   negative   effect   that   increased   resource   extraction-­‐specialisation  has   on   long-­‐term   economic   growth   and   the   resulting   economic   divergence  between  SSA  (as  extraction-­‐economies)  and  the  developed  world  (as  centres  of  manufacturing).  The  short-­‐term  economic  growth  that’s  fuelled  by  extraction  is  also  a  misleading   indicator  of   success,  diverting  attention   from  this  concerning  trend  of  divergence.  Despite  this  reality,  if  one  accepts  that  the  boom’s  impact  is  so  substantial  that  the  overall  impact  of  the  boom  is  inexorably  negative,  one  can  still   cautiously   identify   qualified   positives.   Increased   government   tax   revenue  from  boom  has  resulted  in  qualified  positive  impacts  for  SSA,  because  it  provides  opportunities.  However,  in  SSA,  substantial  structural  obstacles  have  pervasively  prevented  these  positive  opportunities   from  being  materially  realised.  Even  so,  these   opportunities   are   sometimes   materially   realised,   despite   structural  obstacles,   when   agency   triumphs   over   structure.   Examples   of   this   agency   are:  forward-­‐thinking  government  policymaking  and  the  ‘benevolent’  infrastructural  positive-­‐externalities  of  Chinese  foreign  investment  in  SSA.  In  addition,  qualified  positive   opportunities   that   the   commodity   boom  presents   are:   opportunity   for  increased   public   spending   on   public   services   in   order   to   benefit   the   poor,   and  opportunity  to  pursue  diversification  (and  subsequent  reduction  in  exposure  to  fluctuations  in  the  market  price  of  commodities).      The   first  qualified  positive   is   the  opportunity   for   increased  public   spending  on  public  services  in  order  to  benefit  the  poor.  Most  countries  in  SSA  have  tax  bases  that   are   ‘built   overwhelmingly   on   [commodity]   exports’   (Leonard   and   Straus  2003:  12).  The  boom  raises  additional  tax  revenue  that  could  potentially  benefit  the   poor   through   immediate   spending   on   vital   services   such   as   hospital   and  schools.   Importantly,   this   extra   revenue   also   gives   opportunity   for   more  government  investment  for  the  future,  as  in  ‘resource-­‐rich  societies,  investment  is  particularly  important  since  this  is  how  resource  surplus  can  be  transformed  into  sustained  increases  in  income’  (Collier,  2007:  44).  These  opportunities  have  been   largely   squandered   in   SSA   due   to   the   structural   obstacle   of   ‘neo-­‐patrimonialism’.  In  neo-­‐patrimonialism,  power  is  exercised  ‘through  the  informal  sector’  in  a  system  of  ‘political  reciprocity  which  link[s]  patrons  with  their  clients  along   vertical   social   lines’   (Chabal,   2002:   450).   In   this   system,   government   tax  revenue  is  misappropriated  and  used  as  political  patronage  by  public  officials,  to  gain  political   loyalty  from  ‘clients’.  The  extra  revenue  generated  by  the  boom  is  particularly   hard   to   trace   account   for,   and   this   helps   engender   informal  misappropriation   of   government   funds.   This   misappropriation   occurred   in  Nigeria  for  instance.  Nigeria  borrowed  heavily  during  the  boom  in  the  1980s  and  undertook   ‘massively   wasteful   projects   saturated  with   corruption’   to   facilitate  patronage,   and   consequently,   Nigerian   living   standards   ‘approximately   halved’  

Giles  Thompson  -­‐  ‘To  what  extent  should  the  current  African  commodity  boom  be  viewed  in  a  positive  light?’  The  Politics  of  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa  -­‐  Word  count:  1993  

  2  

(Collier,   2007:   40-­‐41).   This   is   statistic   is   striking,   highlighting   evident  deprivation  of  ‘resources  that  might  otherwise  be  spent  on  public  goods’  (Kelsall  et  al.,  2013:  13)  by  neo-­‐patrimonialism.  Governments  across  SSA  instigate  these  ‘white-­‐elephant’  (Collier,  2007:  44)  contracts,  which  embody  the  blurring  of  the  state’s  boundaries  between  ‘public  and  private’  (Kelsall  et  al.,  2013:  13)  that  is  a  central   characteristic   of   neo-­‐patrimonialism.   Neo-­‐patrimonialism   hinders  ‘planning   for   the   common   good   [and   instead   systematically   promotes  purveyance]   for   private   accumulation’   (Leonard   And   Straus   2003:   4).   The  obstacle   of   neo-­‐patrimonialism   is   hard   to   overcome  as   it’s   not   straightforward  embezzlement,  it’s  more  subtle  and  pervasive,     ‘corruption  is  rarely  centralized’  it   is   ‘instead   an   interminable   series   of   negotiations  with   an   endless  number  of  petty  officials’  (Chabal  and  Daloz,  1999:  102).      However,   while   neo-­‐patrimonialism   is   a   significant   obstacle,   it   is   not  insurmountable  and  extra  government  revenue  from  the  boom  still  represents  a  qualified   positive.   Botswana   has   overcome   this   obstacle   with   effective  government   policy-­‐making   agency.   They   have   created   ‘effective   checks   and  balances   on   power’   (Collier,   2007:   46)   and   promoted   a   genuine   degree   of  transparency   in   government   expenditure   despite   ‘anti-­‐corruption   discourse  [which   is]   primarily   rhetorical’   in   SSA   (Chabal   and  Daloz   1999:   104).   This   has  been   implemented  through  a  mandatory   ‘minimum  rate  of  return   for  all  public  projects’   (Collier,   2007:   46-­‐50).   Cautionary   evidence   that   Botswana   is   ‘saved  from  patronage  politics’  can  be  found  in  the  very  large  amount  of  surplus  funds  that  government  has  accumulated  in  foreign  assets  (Collier,  2007:  50).        The   second   qualified   positive   of   the   boom   is   the   opportunity   that   extra   tax  revenue   presents   to   pursue   diversification   and   a   subsequent   reduction   in  exposure  to  fluctuations  in  the  market  price  of  commodities.  This  opportunity  is  salient   because,   commodities’   increased   ‘boom’   price   is   not   indefinite,   as   The  Economist   (2013)   reports,     ‘one   third   of   Africa’s   GDP   growth   comes   from  commodities  …  this  will  not  last’.  Exposure  to  price  fluctuations  come  about  as  a  result   of   a   substantial   proportion   of   growth   being   reliant   on   the   price   of   one  commodity,  which   in   turn  makes   forecasting  a  sustainable   level  of  government  borrowing   difficult   and   perilous.   This   difficulty   is   exemplified   by   erroneous  projections  made  by  many  SSA  governments  as  a  result  of  inflated  expectations  in  the  context  of  the  ‘doubling  of  oil  prices  from  1979  to  1981’  (Jackson,  1985),  immediately  before  the  onset  of  the  debt  crisis  in  the  1980s.  Given  the  risks  of  a  non-­‐diversified  economy,  a  structural  obstacle  is  necessary  to  explain  why  in  SSA  there  is  ‘little  diversification’  (World  Bank,  2000:  1)  and  countries  remain  largely  dependent  on  ‘a  narrow  range  of  commodities’  (ACET,  2014:  2).  This  explanatory  structural  obstacle  is  know  as  the  ‘Dutch  disease’,  it  is,  in  essence,  where,  a  ‘sharp  inflow   of   foreign   currency   [due   to   the   export   of   commodities]   …   leads   to  currency  appreciation,  making  the  country's  other’  exports  less  competitive  (FT,  2015).   The   Dutch   disease   in   coordination   with   a   commodity   boom   makes  diversification  more  challenging  because  as  government  receives  extra  revenue,  which   it   can   invest   in   infant   industries,   the   competitiveness   and   commercial  viability   of   those   industries   is   simultaneously   reduced.   However,   whilst   the  structural   obstacle   of   the  Dutch  disease  mostly   triumphs   over   the   opportunity  for  diversification,  the  Dutch  disease  is  not  insuperable  and  the  extra  tax  revenue  

Giles  Thompson  -­‐  ‘To  what  extent  should  the  current  African  commodity  boom  be  viewed  in  a  positive  light?’  The  Politics  of  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa  -­‐  Word  count:  1993  

  3  

still   represents   a   qualified   positive.   The   obstacle   has   been   overcome   in   some  cases,   through   forward-­‐thinking   government   agency   in   policy-­‐making   and   also  through  the  ‘benevolent’  infrastructural  positive-­‐externalities  of  Chinese  foreign  investment  in  SSA.    Forward-­‐thinking   government   policy-­‐making   agency   can   capture   the  opportunity  of  the  boom.  The  exemplary  case  is  again  Botswana,  while  ‘lucky  to  have  rich  diamond  mines’  Botswana’s  government,  unlike  ‘other  poor  countries’  has   not   squandered   its   natural   resources   (Easterly   2007:   25).   The   Botswana  government   enlisted   ‘De   Beers’   diamond   mining   and   marketing   expertise’  (Easterly   2007:   315)   and   with   income   it   raised   from   this,   it   committed   to  diversifying   its   economy   beyond   the   diamond   industry   (Easterly,   2007:   315).  Diversification   is   far   from  complete   in  Botswana,  but  positive  steps  were  taken  towards   diversification   in   2008,   immediately   after   the   commodity   boom.   The  government   published   and   has   to   a   large   extent   implemented   a   ‘Strategy   for  Economic  Diversification  and  Sustainable  Growth’  with  the  aim  of  ‘‘diversify[ing]  the  economy  to  ensure  that  Botswana  continues  to  enjoy  the  fruits  of  sustained  economic  growth  [regardless  of  the  market-­‐price  of  minerals  and]  post  depletion  of  minerals’  (GICO,  2008:  3).      The   second   form   of   agency   I   will   explore   is   the   ‘benevolent’   infrastructural  positive-­‐externalities   of   Chinese   foreign   investment   in   SSA.   The   commodity  boom  has  coincided  with,  and  has  partially  been  triggered  by  increased  Chinese  imports  from  SSA  of  fuel  and  minerals.  ‘China’s  major  interest  in  Africa  is  oil  and  minerals,  which   constitute   60   percent   of   its   imports   from  Africa’   (Gordon   and  Gordon,   2012:   426).   Chinese   investors   have   been   highly   criticized   for   human  rights  abuses  in  their  SSA  investments.  An  extreme  example  of  this,   is  the  2005  ‘explosion   at   a   Chinese-­‐owned   explosives   manufacturing   plant   in   Chambishi  [which]   killed   46   Zambian   workers’   and   the   subsequent   riot   ‘over   work  conditions  [that]  culminated  in  the  shooting  of  at  least  five  miners’  (HRW,  2011).  Despite   these   abhorrent   abuses,   thinking   purely   in   terms   of   diversification,  Chinese   investors   have   been   ‘benevolent’.   For   instance,   the   Chinese   have  invested  $3.8bn  in  and  begun  to  implement  the  refurbishment  and  extension  of  the   380-­‐mile   ‘New   East   Africa   Railway’,   which   is   predicted   to   cut   the   cost   of  sending   a   tonne   of   freight   one   kilometre   from   $0.20   to   $0.08   in   Kenya   (BBC,  2014).  Increased  involvement  of  Chinese  foreign  investors  has  resulted  in  a  fairly  comprehensive   ‘Chinese-­‐built   infrastructure   boom   across   the   continent  [comprising   of]   roads   and   railways,   dams,   telecoms,   hospitals,   schools,   power  plants,   and   even   new   towns’   (Gordon   and   Gordon   2012:   426).   This  infrastructural   boom   provides   a   route   to   circumnavigate   the   obstacle   of   the  Dutch   disease.   Improved   infrastructure   has   reduced   business   costs,   has  improved   efficiency   and   in   theory   has  made   a   contribution   to   SSA   businesses’  competitiveness.   Thus,   the   agency   of   the   ‘benevolent’   infrastructural   positive-­‐externalities   of   Chinese   foreign   investment   in   SSA   has   also,   in   additional   to  government   agency,   presented   an   opportunity   for   agency   to   triumph   over   the  structural  obstacle  of  the  Dutch  disease   in  order  to  realise  a  material  qualified-­‐positive.    On   a   different   but   crucial   note,   it   is   important   to   remember   that   the   vital  

Giles  Thompson  -­‐  ‘To  what  extent  should  the  current  African  commodity  boom  be  viewed  in  a  positive  light?’  The  Politics  of  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa  -­‐  Word  count:  1993  

  4  

qualification  for  these  positives  is  that  the  balance  sheet  of  the  commodity  boom  is  predominantly  negative.  The  incentivisation  of  increased  extraction  of  natural  commodities   from   SSA   for   sale   to   the   developed   world   is   incontrovertibly  detrimental.   The   primary   reason   for   this   is   observed   by   the   ‘Prebsich-­‐Singer  hypothesis’  (Toye,  2003).   ‘Prebisch-­‐Singer’  highlights  that  over  time  the  market  value   of   primary   products   depreciates   exponentially   and   irretrievably   when  compared   to   that   of   (manufactured)   goods.   Therefore   the   incentivisation   of  specialisation   in   primary   commodities   is   abhorrent   because   it   commits   SSA  extraction-­‐economies   countries   to   a   trend   of   persistent   economic   divergence,  where   the   price   that   they   can   fetch   for   their   factors   of   production   depreciates  compared   to   the   price   that   developed   countries   can   achieve   for  manufactured  goods.   SSA   countries,   by   exporting   their   primary   commodities,   incur   the  ‘opportunity  cost’  of  not  being  able  to  use  the  commodities  they  sell  to  undertake  manufacturing  and   thus  benefit   from  the  additional   ‘value  added’   (GDP)   that   is  gained   from  manufacturing  goods.  The  boom  has  also  been  negative  because   it  has  shrouded  this  predominant  negative  in  confusion  by  providing  a  ‘misleading  indicator’   of   economic   success   (GDP   growth).   Apart   from   the   fact   that   the  increased   GDP   growth   rates   ‘come   on   a   very   low   base’   (Gordon   and   Gordon  2012:   419),   the   celebration   of   this   growth   by   financial   periodicals   and  international  agencies  has  distracted  from  this   ‘globalized  double  standard  –  of  market   fundamentalism   for   the   non-­‐west   and   an   enduring   unorthodoxy,  protectionism   and   even  mercantilism   in   the  west’   (Harrison,   2010:   23)   which  serves  ‘the  interests  of  the  more  advanced  economies…  rather  than  those  of  the  developing   world’   (Stiglitz,   2002:   214).   This   globalised   ‘double   standard’   has  been  best  embodied  in  the  IMF  SAPs,  and  despite  the  SAPs  being  replaced  by  the  PRSP   in  1999,   ‘in  a  basic  empirical   sense   the  PRSP  maintains   the  same’   flawed  fundamentals  of  ‘macroeconomic  liberalism’  (Harrison,  2010:  42).    The  commodity  boom  should  be  viewed   in  an   inexorably  negative   light  overall  because  it  causes  SSA  countries  to  advance  in  their  adoption  of  their  extraction-­‐economy  role,  which   triggers   increased  economic  divergence  between  SSA  and  the  developed  world  as  observed  by  the  ‘Prebisch-­‐Singer  hypothesis’.  However,  conciliatory   qualified   positives   of   the   commodity   boom   can   cast   cracks   of  positive   light  on  one’s  view  of   the  commodity  boom.  These  cracks  of  positivity  are   limited,   because   the   agency   on   which   these   qualified   positives   are   totally  reliant   on,   in   order   to   be   prevalently   and   tangibly   realised,   is   predominantly  blocked   by   the   substantial   structural   obstacles   of   ‘Dutch   disease’   and   ‘Neo-­‐Patrimonialism’.  To  summarise  the  qualified  positives  of  the  commodity  boom,  I  draw   on   the   analogy   that   President   Sirleaf   makes   between   Liberia   and   SSA,  ‘Liberia   is   not   a   poor   country,   but   rather   a   rich   country   that   has   been   poorly  managed.  The  same  is  true  for  much  of  SSA’  (Radelet  and  Sirleaf,  2010:  5).                  

Giles  Thompson  -­‐  ‘To  what  extent  should  the  current  African  commodity  boom  be  viewed  in  a  positive  light?’  The  Politics  of  Sub-­‐Saharan  Africa  -­‐  Word  count:  1993  

  5  

Bibliography:    Books:  

• Chabal,  P.,  and  Daloz,  J-­‐P.  (1999).  “Africa  Works:  Disorder  as  Political  Instrument”.  Bloomington:  International  African  Institute.  

• Collier,  P.  (2007).  “The  Bottom  Billion:  Why  the  poorest  countries  are  failing  and  what  can  be  done  about  it”.  New  York,  NY:  Oxford  University  Press.  

• Easterly,  W.  (2007).  “The  White  Man’s  Burden:  Why  the  West's  Efforts  to  Aid  the  Rest  Have  Done  So  Much  Ill  and  So  Little  Good”.  United  Kingdom:  Oxford  University  Press.  

• George,  S.  (1988).  “A  Fate  Worse  Than  Debt”.  United  Kingdom:  Penguin  Books.  • Gordon,  A.  A.,  and  Gordon,  D.  L.  (2012).  “Understanding  contemporary  Africa”.  Boulder,  CO:  Lynne  

Rienner  Publishers.  • Harrison,  G.  (2010).  “Neoliberal  Africa:  The  Impact  of  Global  Social  Engineering”.  United  Kingdom:  

Zed  Books.  • Kelsall,  T.  et  al.  (2013).  “Business,  Politics,  and  the  State  in  Africa:  challenging  the  orthodoxies  on  

growth  and  transformation”.  London:  Palgrave  Macmillan.  • Leonard,  D.  K.  and  Straus,  S.  (2003).  “Africa’s  Stalled  Development:  International  Causes  and  Cures”.  

United  States:  Lynne  Rienner  Publishers.  • Radelet,  S.,  and  Sirleaf,  E.  J.  (2010).  “Emerging  Africa:  How  17  Countries  are  Leading  the  Way”.  

United  States:  Centre  for  Global  Development.  • Stiglitz,  J.  E.  and  Stiglitz,  J.  (2002).  “Globalization  and  its  discontents”.  New  York:  Norton,  W.  W.  &  

Company.    

Economic  Reports:  • African  Center  for  Economic  Transformation  (ACET)  (2014).  “2014  African  Transformation  Report:  

Growth  with  Depth”.  African  Center  for  Economic  Transformation.  Available  at:  http://acetforafrica.org/wp-­‐content/uploads/2014/03/2014-­‐African-­‐Transformation-­‐Report.pdf.  (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

• McKinsey  Global  Institute  (MGI)  (2010).  "Lions  on  the  Move:  The  Progress  and  Potential  of  African  Economies".  McKinsey  Global  Institute/Mckinsey  &  Company.  Available  at:  http://www.mckinsey.com/~/media/McKinsey/dotcom/Insights%20and%20pubs/MGI/Research/Productivity%20Competitiveness%20and%20Growth/Lions%20on%20the%20move%20The%20progress%20of%20African%20economies/MGI_Lions_on_the_move_african_economies_full_report.ashx.  (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

• World  Bank  (2000).  “Can  Africa  claim  the  21st  century?”.  World  Bank  Publications.  Available  at:  http://www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/canafricaclaim.pdf.    (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

 Government  Documents:  

• Botswana  Government  Implementation  Coordination  Office  (GICO)  (2008).  "Botswana  Excellence:  A  Strategy  for  Economic  Diversification  and  Sustainable  Growth".  Botswana  Government  Implementation  Coordination  Office.  Available  at:  www.gov.bw/global/portal%20team/botswanaexcellencestrategynovember08.pdf.  (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

 Journal  Articles:  

• Chabal,  P.  (2002).  “The  Quest  for  Good  Governance  and  Development  in  Africa:  Is  NEPAD  the  Answer?.  International  Affairs,  78(3),  pp.  447-­‐462.  

• Jackson,  H.  F.  (1985).  “The  African  Crisis:  Drought  and  Debt”.  Foreign  Affairs,  63(5).  • Toye,  J.  (2003).  “The  Origins  and  Interpretation  of  the  Prebisch-­‐Singer  Thesis”.  History  of  Political  

Economy,  35(3),  pp.  437–467.      

Newspaper  Reports:  • The  Economist  (2013).  “The  World’s  Fastest  Growing  Continent:  Aspiring  Africa”.  

Available  at:  http://www.economist.com/news/leaders/21572773-­‐pride-­‐africas-­‐achievements-­‐should-­‐be-­‐coupled-­‐determination-­‐make-­‐even-­‐faster  (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

 Webpages:  

• British  Broadcasting  Company  (BBC)  (2014).  “China  to  build  new  East  Africa  railway  line”.  Available  at:  http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-­‐africa-­‐27368877  

• Financial  Times  (FT)  (2015).  “Dutch  Disease  Definition  from  Financial  Times  Lexicon”.    Available  at:  http://lexicon.ft.com/Term?term=Dutch-­‐disease  (Accessed:  6  May  2015)  

• Human  Rights  Watch  (HRW)  (2011).  “You’ll  Be  Fired  if  You  Refuse:  Labor  Abuses  in  Zambia’s  Chinese  State-­‐owned  Copper  Mines”.  

• Available  at:  http://www.hrw.org/reports/2011/11/04/you-­‐ll-­‐be-­‐fired-­‐if-­‐you-­‐refuse