Generic Demand Model Considering the Impact of … Demand Model Considering the Impact of Prosumers...

11
1 Generic Demand Model Considering the Impact of Prosumers for Future Grid Scenario Analysis Shariq Riaz, Student Member, IEEE, Hesamoddin Marzooghi, Member, IEEE, Gregor Verbiˇ c, Senior Member, IEEE, Archie C. Chapman, Member, IEEE, and David J. Hill, Life Fellow, IEEE Abstract—The increasing uptake of residential PV-battery sys- tems is bound to significantly change demand patterns of future power systems and, consequently, their dynamic performance. In this paper, we propose a generic demand model that captures the aggregated effect of a large population of price-responsive users equipped with small-scale PV-battery systems, called prosumers, for market simulation in future grid scenario analysis. The model is formulated as a bi-level program in which the upper-level unit commitment problem minimizes the total generation cost, and the lower-level problem maximizes prosumers’ aggregate self-consumption. Unlike in the existing bi-level optimization frameworks that focus on the interaction between the wholesale market and an aggregator, the coupling is through the prosumers’ demand, not through the electricity price. That renders the proposed model market structure agnostic, making it suitable for future grid studies where the market structure is potentially unknown. As a case study, we perform steady-state voltage stability analysis of a simplified model of the Australian National Electricity Market with significant penetration of renewable generation. The simulation results show that a high prosumer penetration changes the demand profile in ways that significantly improve the system loadability, which confirms the suitability of the proposed model for future grid studies. Index Terms—Demand response, aggregators, prosumers, PV- battery systems, generic demand model, future grids, scenario analysis, bi-level optimization. NOMENCLATURE B Set of buses. G Set of generators g. M Set of demand aggregators m. L Set of lines: L⊆B×B. R Set of regions r. H Set of time slots h. x / x Minimum/maximum value of x. r +/- g Ramp-up/down rate of supplier g. τ u/d g Minimum up/down time of supplier g. B i,j Susceptance of line between buses i and j . θ i,h Voltage angle at bus i in h. p i,j l,h Power flow on line i-j : p i,j l,h = B i,j (θ i,h - θ j,h ). Shariq Riaz, Gregor Verbiˇ c, Archie C. Chapman, and David J. Hill are with the School of Electrical and Information Engineering, The University of Syd- ney, Sydney, New South Wales, Australia. e-mails: shariq.riaz, gregor.verbic, archie.chapman, [email protected]. Hesamoddin Marzooghi is with School of Engineering and Technology, Central Queensland University (CQ University), Brisbane, Australia. e-mail: [email protected]. Shariq Riaz is also with the Department of Electrical Engineering, Univer- sity of Engineering and Technology Lahore, Lahore, Pakistan. David J. Hill is also with the Department of Electrical and Electronic Engineering, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Δp i,j l,h Power loss on line i-j . p g,h Generated power of supplier g in h. p m b,h Battery storage power of aggregator m in h. e m b,h Battery storage state of charge of aggregator m in h. p inf,m d,h Inflexible demand of aggregator m in h. p flx,m d,h Flexible demand of aggregator m in h. p u,m d,h Underlying prosumer demand of aggregator m in h. p m pv,h PV generation of aggregator m in h. p res r,h Required reserve in region r in the system in h. s g,h Binary decision variable on/off status of supplier g. u g,h Binary start-up decision variable of supplier g. d g,h Binary shut-down decision variable of supplier g. c fix/var g Fix/variable cost of supplier g. c su/sd g Start-up/shut-down cost of supplier g. η b Battery round-trip efficiency. λ Dual variable associated with an equality constraint. μ Dual variable associated with an inequality constraint. b Binary variable introduced to maintain complementary slackness. M Large positive number used in the MILP formulation of the lower-level KKT conditions. I. I NTRODUCTION P OWER systems are undergoing a major transformation driven by the increasing uptake of variable renewable energy sources (RES). At the demand side, the emergence of cost-effective “behind-the-meter” distributed energy resources, including on-site generation, energy storage, electric vehicles, and flexible loads, and the advancement of sensor, computer, communication and energy management technologies are changing the way electricity consumers source and consume electric power. Indeed, recent studies suggest that rooftop PV- battery systems will reach retail price parity from 2020 in the USA grids and the Australian National Electricity Market (NEM) [1]. A recent forecast by Morgan Stanley has suggested that the uptake can be even faster, by boldly predicting that up to 2 million Australian households could install battery storage by 2020 [2]. This has been confirmed by the Energy Networks Australia and the Australian Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation (CSIRO) who have estimated the projected uptake of solar PV and battery storage in 2050 to be 80 GW and 100 GWh [3], which will represent between 30%–50% of total demand, a scenario called “Rise of the Prosumer” [4]. Here, the prosumer they refer to is a small- scale (residential, commercial and small industrial) electricity consumer with on-site generation. A similar trend has been arXiv:1605.05833v5 [math.OC] 13 Sep 2017

Transcript of Generic Demand Model Considering the Impact of … Demand Model Considering the Impact of Prosumers...

1

Generic Demand Model Considering the Impact ofProsumers for Future Grid Scenario Analysis

Shariq Riaz, Student Member, IEEE, Hesamoddin Marzooghi, Member, IEEE, Gregor Verbic, SeniorMember, IEEE, Archie C. Chapman, Member, IEEE, and David J. Hill, Life Fellow, IEEE

Abstract—The increasing uptake of residential PV-battery sys-tems is bound to significantly change demand patterns of futurepower systems and, consequently, their dynamic performance. Inthis paper, we propose a generic demand model that captures theaggregated effect of a large population of price-responsive usersequipped with small-scale PV-battery systems, called prosumers,for market simulation in future grid scenario analysis. The modelis formulated as a bi-level program in which the upper-levelunit commitment problem minimizes the total generation cost,and the lower-level problem maximizes prosumers’ aggregateself-consumption. Unlike in the existing bi-level optimizationframeworks that focus on the interaction between the wholesalemarket and an aggregator, the coupling is through the prosumers’demand, not through the electricity price. That renders theproposed model market structure agnostic, making it suitablefor future grid studies where the market structure is potentiallyunknown. As a case study, we perform steady-state voltagestability analysis of a simplified model of the Australian NationalElectricity Market with significant penetration of renewablegeneration. The simulation results show that a high prosumerpenetration changes the demand profile in ways that significantlyimprove the system loadability, which confirms the suitability ofthe proposed model for future grid studies.

Index Terms—Demand response, aggregators, prosumers, PV-battery systems, generic demand model, future grids, scenarioanalysis, bi-level optimization.

NOMENCLATURE

B Set of buses.G Set of generators g.M Set of demand aggregators m.L Set of lines: L ⊆ B × B.R Set of regions r.H Set of time slots h.x/x Minimum/maximum value of x.r+/−g Ramp-up/down rate of supplier g.τ

u/dg Minimum up/down time of supplier g.Bi,j Susceptance of line between buses i and j.θi,h Voltage angle at bus i in h.pi,jl,h Power flow on line i-j: pi,jl,h = Bi,j(θi,h − θj,h).

Shariq Riaz, Gregor Verbic, Archie C. Chapman, and David J. Hill are withthe School of Electrical and Information Engineering, The University of Syd-ney, Sydney, New South Wales, Australia. e-mails: shariq.riaz, gregor.verbic,archie.chapman, [email protected].

Hesamoddin Marzooghi is with School of Engineering and Technology,Central Queensland University (CQ University), Brisbane, Australia. e-mail:[email protected].

Shariq Riaz is also with the Department of Electrical Engineering, Univer-sity of Engineering and Technology Lahore, Lahore, Pakistan.

David J. Hill is also with the Department of Electrical and ElectronicEngineering, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong.

∆pi,jl,h Power loss on line i-j.pg,h Generated power of supplier g in h.pmb,h Battery storage power of aggregator m in h.emb,h Battery storage state of charge of aggregator m in h.pinf,m

d,h Inflexible demand of aggregator m in h.pflx,m

d,h Flexible demand of aggregator m in h.pu,m

d,h Underlying prosumer demand of aggregator m in h.pmpv,h PV generation of aggregator m in h.presr,h Required reserve in region r in the system in h.sg,h Binary decision variable on/off status of supplier g.ug,h Binary start-up decision variable of supplier g.dg,h Binary shut-down decision variable of supplier g.c

fix/varg Fix/variable cost of supplier g.c

su/sdg Start-up/shut-down cost of supplier g.ηb Battery round-trip efficiency.λ Dual variable associated with an equality constraint.µ Dual variable associated with an inequality constraint.b Binary variable introduced to maintain complementary

slackness.M Large positive number used in the MILP formulation

of the lower-level KKT conditions.

I. INTRODUCTION

POWER systems are undergoing a major transformationdriven by the increasing uptake of variable renewable

energy sources (RES). At the demand side, the emergence ofcost-effective “behind-the-meter” distributed energy resources,including on-site generation, energy storage, electric vehicles,and flexible loads, and the advancement of sensor, computer,communication and energy management technologies arechanging the way electricity consumers source and consumeelectric power. Indeed, recent studies suggest that rooftop PV-battery systems will reach retail price parity from 2020 inthe USA grids and the Australian National Electricity Market(NEM) [1]. A recent forecast by Morgan Stanley has suggestedthat the uptake can be even faster, by boldly predicting that upto 2 million Australian households could install battery storageby 2020 [2]. This has been confirmed by the Energy NetworksAustralia and the Australian Commonwealth Scientific andIndustrial Research Organisation (CSIRO) who have estimatedthe projected uptake of solar PV and battery storage in 2050to be 80 GW and 100 GWh [3], which will represent between30%–50% of total demand, a scenario called “Rise of theProsumer” [4]. Here, the prosumer they refer to is a small-scale (residential, commercial and small industrial) electricityconsumer with on-site generation. A similar trend has been

arX

iv:1

605.

0583

3v5

[m

ath.

OC

] 1

3 Se

p 20

17

2

observed in Europe as well [5]. Given this, it is expected thata large uptake of demand-side technologies will significantlychange demand patterns in future grids1, which will in turnaffect their dynamic performance.

Existing future grid feasibility studies [6]–[10] typically useconventional demand models, possibly using some heuristicsto account for the effect of emerging demand-side technolo-gies, and the synergies that may arise between them. Theyalso assume specific market arrangements by which RES areintegrated into grid operations. The challenge associated withfuture grid planning is that the grid structure and the regulatoryframework, including the market structure, cannot be simplyassumed from the details of an existing one. Instead, severalpossible evolution paths need to be accounted for. Future gridplanning thus requires a major departure from conventionalpower system planning, where only a handful of the mostcritical scenarios is analyzed. To account for a wide rangeof possible future evolutions, scenario analysis has been pro-posed in many industries, e.g. in finance and economics [11],and in energy [12]–[14]. As opposed to power system planningwhere the aim is to find an optimal transmission and/orgeneration expansion plan, the aim in scenario analysis is toanalyze possible evolution pathways to inform policymaking.Given the uncertainty associated with long-term projections,the focus of future grid scenario analysis is limited to theanalysis of what is technically possible, although it mightalso consider an explicit costing [15]. Our work is part of theFuture Grid Research Program funded by the CSIRO, whoseaim is to explore possible future pathways for the evolutionof the Australian grid out to 2050 by looking beyond simplebalancing. To this end, a comprehensive modeling frameworkfor future grid scenario analysis has been proposed in [16],which includes a market model, power flow analysis, andstability analysis. The demand model, however, assumes thatthe users are price-takers, which does not properly capturethe aggregated effect of prosumers on the demand profile, asdiscussed later.

A. Related Work

Due to the influence of a demand profile on power systemsperformance and stability, recent studies have attempted tointegrate the aggregated impact of prosumers into the de-mand models [17]–[22]. The focus, however, is usually onscheduling of particular emerging demand-side technologies,e.g. HVAC [17]–[19], flexible loads [20], PV-battery systems[21], and plug-in electrical vehicles (PEVs) [22]. Most ofthese modeling approaches assume an existing market struc-ture, with the impact of prosumers incorporated by allowingdemand and supply to interact in some limited or predefinedways. Specifically, this is mainly done via three differentapproaches:

1) Only the supply-side is modeled physically while pro-sumers are considered by a simplified representation ofdemand-side technologies. In [20], flexible loads’ effects

1We interpret a future grid to mean the study of national grid type structureswith the above-mentioned transformational changes for the long-term out to2050.

on reserve markets are analyzed by modeling prosumerswith a tank model; however, the reserve market is greatlysimplified. In [17], prosumers are represented by a price-elasticity matrix, which is used to model changes inthe aggregate demand in response to a change in theelectricity price, and are acquired from the analysis ofhistorical data.

2) Demand-side technologies are physically modeled whilea simplified representation of supply-side is employed.For instance, in [21], the supply-side is represented byan electricity price profile.

3) Both supply and demand sides can be modeled physi-cally and optimized jointly, as in [18], [22], which canproduce more realistic results. For example, the studyin [22] integrates the aggregated charging managementapproaches for PEVs into the market clearing process,with a simplified representation of the latter.

Although the above models have shown their merits, they aredependent on specific practical details such as the electricityprice or the implementation of a mechanism for demandresponse (DR) aggregation, which limits their usefulness forfuture grid scenario analysis where the detailed market struc-ture is potentially unknown.

Against this backdrop, the paper proposes a principledmethod for generic demand modeling including the aggregatedeffect of prosumers. The model is formulated as a bi-levelprogram in which the upper-level unit commitment problemminimizes the total generation cost, and the lower-level prob-lem maximizes the aggregate prosumers’ self-consumption.In more detail, the lower-level objective is motivated by theemerging situation in Australia, where rooftop PV owners areincreasingly discouraged from sending power back to the griddue to very low PV feed-in-tariffs versus increasing retailelectricity prices. In this setting, an obvious cost-minimizingstrategy is to install small-scale battery storage, to maximizeself-consumption of local generated energy and offset energyused in peak pricing periods. Similar tariff settings appearlikely to occur globally in the near future, as acknowledged in[23]. Moreover, self-consumption within an aggregated blockof prosumers is a good approximation of many likely behaviorsand responses to other future incentives and market structures,such as (peak power-based) demand charges, capacity con-strained connections, virtual net metering across connectionpoints, transactive energy and local energy trading, and a(somewhat irrational) desire for self-reliance.

A key difference from existing bi-level optimization frame-works is that in our formulation, the levels are coupled throughthe prosumers’ demand, not through the electricity price. Incontrast, other models, which focus on the interaction betweenan aggregator and the prosumers [19] or the aggregator andthe wholesale market [22], couple the levels through prices.These approaches essentially define a market structure, thatis, a pricing rule to support an outcome. In contradistinction,our proposed model is market structure agnostic. That is, itimplicitly assumes that an efficient mechanism for demandresponse aggregation is adopted, with prices determined bythat unspecified mechanism, which support the outcomescomputed by our optimization framework.

3

The paper builds on our previous work [24], [25]. In [25],we have assumed that a prosumer aggregation representsa homogeneous group of loads; that is, we have assumedthat they all behave in the same way and have the samecapacity, and are allowed to send power back to the grid.In the absence of an explicit transmission pricing, this cancreate perverse outcomes, such as power exchange betweenaggregators located in different parts of the network. In themodel proposed in this paper, the aggregators are not allowedto send the power back to the grid, which better models theassumption of self-consumption within an aggregated blockof prosumers. The model proposed in [24] is similar to themodel in this paper, however, the prosumer battery storage ismodeled implicitly, which requires a heuristic search to capturethe prosumer behavior.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: SectionII presents the proposed modeling framework. In Section III,the efficacy of the proposed framework is demonstrated ona simplified 14-generator network model of the NEM with asignificant RES penetration. Finally, Section IV concludes.

II. GENERIC DEMAND MODEL CONSIDERING THE IMPACTOF PROSUMERS

Generic demand models are essential for power systemstudies. They are commonly used to reflect the aggregatedeffect of numerous physical loads [26], [27]. Conventionaldemand models only account for the accumulated effect ofindependent load changes and some relatively minor controlactions, that is, they are by necessity simplified to not includeall details of the loads. In the following, we explain themotivation behind this work and the modeling assumptions.

A. Research Motivation and Modeling Assumptions

The main purpose of developing generic demand models isto provide accurate dispatch decisions for balancing and sta-bility analysis of future grid scenarios. Given the uncertaintyassociated with future grid studies, the modeling frameworkshould be market structure agnostic, and capable of easyintegration of various types and penetrations of emergingdemand-side technologies. To this effect, we make the fol-lowing assumptions:

1) The loads are modeled as price anticipators. It is wellunderstood that price-taking load behavior, which simplyresponds to a given price profile, can result in loadsynchronization, i.e. all users move their consumption toa low-price period, resulting in an inefficient market out-come. In contrast, price anticipatory loads influence theelectricity price by playing “a game” with the wholesalemarket. The game is captured by the proposed bi-levelmodel. Specifically, the price-anticipating assumptionimplies that the aggregate effect of the prosumers is tochange the market clearing prices and quantities, and,moreover, that the prosumers have a model of this effect.Given this, the prosumer aggregation bids follow anequilibrium strategy, with an accurate expectation aboutthe response of the market; this is the standard reason-ing behind a Cournot or Stackelberg game formulation

corresponding to a bi-level optimization problem. Thisequilibrium strategy can be thought of as being gener-ated by the following iterative process: First, the marketoperator creates a price profile by clearing the marketbased on the predicted demand. Second, the prosumers(and other price-anticipatory participants) respond byshifting their consumption to cheaper time slots. Thisgives a new demand profile, and the market operatorclears the market again, and the process repeats untilconvergence. Note that the proposed model does notspecify an iterative mechanism, but rather, it encodesthe optimality conditions for any price profile for theprosumers in Karush-Kuhn-Tucker (KKT) conditions,and in this way it captures the outcome resulting fromthe price-anticipatory prosumer behavior. In our previ-ous work [16], [28], we modeled the loads as price-takers, inspired by the smart home concept [29], inwhich the loads respond to the electricity price tominimize energy expenditure. The study has shown thatwith large penetration of price-taking prosumers, themarginal benefit might become negative when secondarypeaks are created due to the load synchronization (seeFig. 1 showing the operational demand with differentpenetrations of prosumers). Therefore, demand responseaggregators (henceforth simply called aggregators) havestarted to emerge to fully exploit the demand-side flex-ibility. To that effect, the model implicitly assumes anefficient mechanism for demand response aggregation(an interested reader might refer to [30] for a discussionon practical implementation issues). However, specificimplementation details, like price structure or the divi-sion of the profit earning by the aggregated collectionof prosumers, are not of explicit interest in the proposedmodel.

2) The demand model representing an aggregator consistsof a large population of prosumers connected to an un-constrained distribution network who collectively max-imize self-consumption (made possible by an efficientinternal trading and balancing mechanism).

3) Aggregators do not alter the underlying power con-sumption of the prosumers. That is, except for batterylosses, the total power consumption before and afteraggregation remains the same; however, the grid powerintake profile does change, as a result of the prosumersusing batteries to maximize self-consumption.

4) Prosumers have smart meters equipped with home en-ergy management (HEM) systems for scheduling of thePV-battery systems. Also, a communication infrastruc-ture is assumed that allows a two-way communicationbetween the grid, the aggregator and the prosumers,facilitating energy trading between prosumers in theaggregation.

These assumptions appear to be appropriate for scenariosarising in time frame of several decades into the future.

B. Bi-level Optimization FrameworkIn the model, we are specifically interested in the aggregated

effect of a large prosumer population on the demand profile,

4

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

Pow

er (

GW

)

6

8

10

12

Price takers

No prosumers Low prosumers High prosumers

Time (hours)12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

Pow

er (

GW

)

6

8

10

12

Price anticipators

No prosumers Low prosumers High prosumers

Fig. 1. Operational demand with different penetrations of price-taking (top)and price-anticipating prosumers (bottom).

assuming that the prosumers collectively maximize their self-consumption. Given that the objective of the wholesale marketis to minimize the generation cost, the problem exhibits a bi-level structure. In game theory, such hierarchical optimizationproblems are known as Stackelberg games. They can beformulated as bi-level mathematical programs of the form [19]:

minimizex,y

Φ (x, y)

subject to (x, y) ∈ Zy ∈ S = arg min

yΩ (x, y) : y ∈ C (x)

where x ∈ Rn, y ∈ Rm, are decisions vectors, and Φ (x, y) :Rn+m → R and Ω (x, y) : Rn+m → R are the objective func-tions of the upper- and the lower-level problems, respectively.Z is the joint feasible region of the upper-level problem andC(x) the feasible region of the lower-level problem inducedby x. In the existing market models that adopt a hierarchicalapproach, the coupling variable y is the electricity price (e.g.[19], [22]). That is, the upper-level (the wholesale market inour case) determines the price schedule, while the lower-level(the aggregator acting on behalf of the prosumers), optimizesits consumption based on this price schedule.

Fig. 2 shows the structure of the proposed modeling frame-work. The demand model consists of two parts: (i) inflexibledemand, pinf,m

d , with a fixed demand profile, representinglarge industrial loads and loads without flexible resources; and(ii) flexible demand, pflx,m

d , comprising a large population ofprosumers who collectively maximize self-consumption. Notethat not every bus in the system has a load connected to it,hence the distinction between an aggregator m ∈M and busi ∈ B. Unlike in most existing studies, the interaction betweenthe wholesale market and the aggregators in our model isthrough the demand profile of the aggregator, pflx,m

d . Note thatin contradistinction to the price-taking assumption when theelectricity price is known in advance, now the collective actionof the prosumers affects the wholesale market dispatch, whichis the salient feature of the proposed model.

Market

ppvmpd

inf,m pbm

pdu,m

pdflx,m

G1 G2 Gn

pG1 pG2 pGn

Bus i

Aggregator m

Fig. 2. Structure of the proposed modeling framework.

C. Upper-level Problem (Wholesale Market)

To emulate the market outcome, the upper-level problem iscast as a unit commitment (UC) problem aiming to minimizethe generation cost:

minimizes,u,d,p,θ

∑h∈H

∑g∈G

(cfixg sg,h+csu

g ug,h+csdg dg,h+cvar

g pg,h

), (1)

where sg,h, ug,h, dg,h ∈ 0, 1, pg,h ∈ R+, θi,h ∈ R are thedecision variables of the problem. The problem is subject tothe following constraints:∑g∈Gi

pg,h =∑

m∈Mi

(pinf,md,h + pflx,m

d,h ) +∑l∈Li

(pl,h + ∆pl,h), (2)

|Bi,j(θi,h − θj,h)| ≤ pl, (3)pgsg,h ≤ pg,h ≤ pgsg,h, (4)

ug,h − dg,h = sg,h − sg,h−1, (5)∑gsynch∈R

(pgsg,h − pg,h) ≥ presr,h, (6)

ug,h +∑τ u

g−1

h=0dg,h+h ≤ 1, (7)

dg,h +∑τ d

g−1

h=0ug,h+h ≤ 1, (8)

− r−g ≤ pg,h − pg,h−1 ≤ r+g , (9)

arg minpflx

d ,pb,eb

∑h∈H

pflx,md,h subject to (12)-(15)

, (10)

where (2) is the power balance equation at each bus i inthe system2, with Gi, Mi, Li representing respectively thesets of generators, aggregators and lines connected to bus i,and pinf,m

d,h , pflx,md,h , pi,jl,h and ∆pi,jl,h representing respectively the

inflexible and flexible demand of aggregator m, line powerand line power loss (assumed to be 10% of the line flow)on each line connected to bus i; (3) represents line powerlimits; (4) limits the dispatch level of a generating unit betweenits respective minimum and maximum limits; (5) links thestatus of a generator unit to the up and down binary decisionvariables; (6) ensures sufficient spinning reserves are availablein reach region of the grid; (7) and (8) ensure minimum up and

2Note that the flexible demand of each aggregator m, pflx,md,h , couples

the upper-level (wholesale market) problem with each of the m lower-level(aggregator) problems.

5

minimum down times of the generators; (9) are the generatorramping constraints; and (10) is the constraint resulting fromthe prosumer aggregation optimization problem, as explainedin Section II-D.

D. Lower-level Problem (Aggregators)

The prosumer aggregation is formulated in the lower-levelproblem. The loads within an aggregator’s domain are assumedhomogeneous, which allows us to represent the total aggrega-tor’s demand with a single load model. The flexibility providedby the battery is only used to maximize self-consumption,with grid supply readily available. This implies that the end-users’ power consumption pattern is left unaltered, so that theircomfort is not jeopardized.

The coupling between the upper-level (wholesale) and thelower-level (retail) problem in the proposed model is throughthe power demand. This removes the need to define the marketin terms of a pricing mechanism or rule, and it follows thatthe electricity price is not explicitly shown in the optimizationproblem. This is why it is called a generic model.

This approach stands in contrast to other existing bi-levelformulations [19], [22], in which the loads and wholesalemarket are coupled through the electricity price. The pricesgenerated by any market depend inherently on the specificpricing mechanism adopted. However, in practice, severaldifferent pricing rules can implement a desired outcome, in-cluding the widely-used uniform price reverse auction or nodalpricing mechanisms. For example, the electricity price couldcomprise the dual variables associated with the power balanceconstraint (2) and power flow constraints (3) of the upper-level problem, plus retail/aggregator and network charges.Moreover, a range of different pricing rules result in differentretail/aggregator and network charges, with all supporting anefficient outcome. However, by instead coupling the upper- andlower-level problems via power demand, our proposed modelavoids the need to specify a particular pricing rule, whichmakes it market-structure agnostic (see also Assumptions 1and 2 in Section II-A). Nonetheless, it is fair to assumethat in any practical system, users will have access to aprice forecast3 and other bidders’ historical behavior–but theseare all market design-specific. In the absence of pricing ruledetails, the proposed optimization model does not require suchinformation.

Specifically, the lower-level problem is formulated as fol-lows for each demand aggregator m ∈M:

minimizepflx

d ,pb,eb

∑h∈H

pflx,md,h , (11)

where the decision variables of the problem are flexibledemand pflx

d , battery power pb, and battery capacity eb. The

3Note that in a HEM problem [29], a HEM system is an agent actingon behalf of a prosumer, and the electricity price is known ahead of time,resulting in a price-taking behavior.

problem is subject to the following constraints:

pflx,md,h = pu,m

d,h − pmpv,h + pmb,h, (12)

emb,h = ηmb emb,h−1 + pmb,h, (13)

pmb≤ pmb,h ≤ pmb , (14)

emb ≤ emb,h ≤ emb , (15)

where (12) is the power balance equation; and (13)-(15) arethe battery storage constraints. Power pu,m

d,h is the underlyingpower demand of the prosumers. Note that according to theAssumption 3 in Section II-B, except for battery losses, theunderlying power demand does not change, however the powerintake from grid can. Finally, the KKT optimality conditionsof the lower-level problem are added as the constraints to theupper-level problem, which reduces the problem to a singlemixed integer linear program that can be solved using of-the-shelf solvers. Note that because the two levels interacts througha power, not through a price, unlike in [19], no linearizationis required.

III. CASE STUDIES

To showcase the efficacy of the model, we analyze steady-state voltage stability of a simplified model of the NEM withscenarios reflecting different prosumer penetrations.

A. Model of the Australian National Electricity Market (NEM)

The 14-generator IEEE test system shown in Fig. 3 wasinitially proposed in [31] as a test bed for small-signal analysis.The system is loosely based on the NEM, the interconnectionon the Australian eastern seaboard. The network is stringy,with large transmission distances and loads concentrated in afew load centers. It consists of 59 buses, 28 loads, and 14generators. The test system consists of four areas representingthe states of Queensland, New South Wales, Victoria andSouth Australia, and 28 aggregators, one for each load bus.The generator technologies and modeling assumptions follow[24]. We consider two RES penetration rates. In the businessas usual (BAU) scenario, the generation portfolio includes39.36 GW coal, 5.22 GW gas, and 2.33 GW hydro. In thehigh-RES scenario, 40 % of the total demand is coveredby variable RES. Inspired by two recent Australian 100%renewables studies [6], [10], part of coal generation is replacedwith wind and utility PV using wind and solar traces from theAEMO’s planning document [32], which results in 28.94 GWcoal, 5.22 GW gas, 2.33 GW hydro, 21 GW wind, and 12 GWutility PV. Given the deterministic nature of the model, weassume 10 % reserves for each region in the system to caterfor demand and RES forecast errors. In market simulations,generators are assumed to bid according to their short-runmarginal costs, while RESs bid at zero cost. Simulations areperformed using a rolling horizon approach with hourly reso-lution assuming a perfect foresight. The optimization horizonis three days with a two-day overlap. Last, wind and solargenerators are assumed to operate in a voltage control mode.

6

NQ

CQ

SEQ

SWQ

NNS

NCEN

CAN

SWNSW

NVIC

LV

MEL

NSA

ADE

SESA

Wind Farm

Utility PV

Fig. 3. Single-line diagram of the 14-generator model of the NEM with the16 zones that define wind and solar traces [32].

B. Prosumer Scenarios

We assume four different prosumer penetrations: zero, low,medium and high. With no prosumer penetration, the demandis assumed inflexible. For the other three scenarios, we as-sume that part of the demand is equipped with small-scale(residential and small commercial) PV-battery systems. Theuptake of PV loosely follows a recent AEMO study [33]. ThePV capacities are respectively 5 GW, 10 GW, and 20 GW forthe low, medium and high uptake of prosumers (the existingpenetration in the NEM is 5 GW). We consider three differentamounts of storage: zero, 2 kW h, and 4 kW h of storage for1 kW of rooftop PV.4 Hourly demand and PV traces are fromthe AEMO’s planning document [32].

C. Dispatch Results

Dispatch results for a typical summer week with highdemand (12-15 January) for a few representative scenariosare shown in Figs. 4 and 5. The figures show, respectively,generation dispatch results (top row), combined flexible de-mand of all aggregators (middle row), and a combined batterycharging profile of all aggregators (bottom row). Fig. 4 showsresults for a medium prosumer penetration with, respectively,zero, 2 h and 4 h hours of storage. Fig. 5 shows results for

4A typical ratio in the NEM today is 2h of storage [33], however, in thefuture, this will likely increase due to the anticipated cost reduction.

different prosumer penetrations (zero, medium, high) with 4 hof storage. Observe that in all six cases peak demand occurs atmid-day due to a high air-conditioning load. After the sunset,however, the demand is still high, so gas generation is neededto cover the gap. In the available generation mix, gas has thehighest short-run marginal cost, which increases the electricityprice in late afternoon/early evening. The balancing resultsover the simulated year have revealed that the increased RESpenetration in the renewable scenarios requires more energyfrom gas generation compared to the BAU scenario. This isdue to RES intermittency, and the ramp limits of conventionalcoal-fired generation. An increased penetration of prosumerswith higher amounts of storage, however, reduces the usageof gas due to a flatter demand profile.

Observe in Fig. 4 how an increasing amount of storageincreases prosumers’ self-sufficiency. Without storage, the loadis supplied by PV during the day, and the rest is suppliedfrom the grid. When storage is added to the system, batteriesare charged when electricity is cheap (mostly from rooftopPV during the day and from wind during the night) anddischarged in late afternoon to offset the demand when theelectricity is most expensive. Note that the plots in the bottomtwo rows show a combined load profile of all aggregators inthe system, which explains why storage is seemingly chargedand discharged simultaneously. Observe how high amounts ofstorage (rightmost columns in Figs. 4 and 5) flatten the demandprofile. During the day, the flexible demand is supplied byrooftop PV, which reduces the operational demand, whileduring the night, with sufficient wind generation, batteries arecharged, which increases the operational demand. This has asignificant beneficial effect on loadability and voltage stability,as discussed in the next section.

D. Loadability and Voltage Stability Results

Dispatch results from the market simulations are used toperform a load flow analysis, which is then used in theassessment of loadability and voltage stability. In the analysis,only scenarios with 4 h of storage were considered. Theprosumer scenarios are thus called, according to the respectivepenetration rates, zero (ZP), low (LP), medium (MP), and high(HP). Note that the market model only considers a simplifiedDC power flow with the maximum angle limit set to 30.This can sometimes result in a non-convergent AC powerflow in scenarios with a high RES penetration. The numberof non-convergent hours is, respectively, 175, 37, 12, and 0,in scenarios ZP, LP, MP, and HP. An increased penetrationof prosumers thus improves voltage stability, as explained inmore detail later.

In loadability assessment, N-1 security is considered, soa contingency screening is performed first. We screened allcredible N-1 contingencies to identify the most severe onesbased on the maximum power transfer level [34]. Twentymost critical contingencies were selected for each hour of thesimulated year.

1) Loadability calculation: To calculate system loadability(LDB), the load in the system is progressively increased usingthe results of the market dispatch as the base case. After each

7

0

10

20

30

Hydro Brown Coal Black Coal WF Utility PV GT Op. Demand pd

inf+pd

up inf

0

5

Po

we

r (G

W)

Rooftop-PV to Load Grid to Load Battery to Load pd

u

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

-505

Rooftop-PV to battery (Charg) Grid to Battery (Charg) Battery to load (Discharg)

0

10

20

30

0

5

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

Time (hours)

-505

0

10

20

30

0

5

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

-505

Fig. 4. Dispatch results for a typical summer week with high demand (12-15 January) for a medium prosumer penetration with different amounts of storage:zero (left), 2h (middle) and 4h (right).

0

10

20

30

Hydro Brown Coal Black Coal WF Utility PV GT Op. Demand pd

inf+pd

up inf

0

5

Po

we

r (G

W)

Rooftop-PV to Load Grid to Load Battery to Load pd

u

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

-505

Rooftop-PV to battery (Charg) Grid to Battery (Charg) Battery to load (Discharg)

0

10

20

30

0

5

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

Time (hours)

-505

0

10

20

30

0

5

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

-505

Fig. 5. Dispatch results for a typical summer week with high demand (12-15 January) for different penetrations of prosumers with 4h of storage: zero (left),medium (middle), high (right).

increase, load flow is calculated twice; first for the case afterthe last load increase without a contingency, and then againfor each of the preselected critical contingencies. When theload flow does not converge for a particular contingency, thelast convergent load flow solution without a contingency isconsidered the loadability margin. We considered two differentload increase patterns, where load and generation are increaseduniformly, in proportion to the base case: (i) NEM: only loadand generation in the NEM are increased; (ii) SA/VIC: onlyload in VIC and generation in SA are increased. The resultsare summarized in Table I. Comparing the BAU scenarioand the renewable scenario with conventional demand (ZP),it can be seen that with the increased RES penetration, theaverage loadability margin over the simulated year in thedemand increase scenario NEM is decreased from 7.8 GWto 2.5 GW. Similarly, the average loadability margin in thedemand increase scenario SA/VIC is reduced from 2.2 GWto 0.8 GW. With a high RES penetration, conventional syn-chronous generation is replaced by inverter-based generation

with inferior reactive power support capability5, which re-sults in a reduced reactive power margin in the system andhence lower stability margin. With an increased penetrationof prosumers, the system loadability improves. Observe thatthe average system loadability margin in both load increasescenarios, NEM and SA/VIC, is increased from 2.5 GW and0.8 GW for the renewable scenario with no prosumers (ZP) to7.1 GW and 1.7 GW for high penetration of prosumers (HP),respectively, which indicates a considerable improvement inthe system loadability margin. This is explained by a demandreduction when prosumer demand is supplied by rooftop PV. Inthe night hours, however, even with high prosumer penetration,the loadibility can be reduced when prosumers charge theirbatteries, as observed in Figs. 4 and 5. The situation is furtherillustrated in Fig. 6 that compares the loadability margin for

5For synchronous generation, a 0.8 power factor is assumed. For RES,we used the reactive power capability curve for the generic GE Type IVwind farm model [35], in which the reactive power generation is significantlyconstrained close to the nominal active power generation. In practice, detailedplanning studies are required before connection is granted, which can resultin an increased requirement for reactive power support.

8

TABLE ILOADABILITY RESULTS

LDBCases Scenarios

BAU ZP LP MP HPAvg. LDB

margin (GW)NEM 7.8 2.5 4.3 5.9 7.1

SA/VIC 2.2 0.8 1.1 1.5 1.7

TABLE IIMODAL ANALYSIS RESULTS

ScenariosBAU ZP LP MP HP

Avg. of minimumReal(eig) (Neper/s) 49.5 42.3 44.8 45.6 48.4

Nodes with highestparticipation factor incritical voltage modes

506306308

506505410

506505410

505506410

505410408

Unstable hours 0 175 37 12 0

the load increase scenario NEM and the results of the modalanalysis, discussed next.

2) Modal analysis: Using the market dispatch results,modal analysis of the reduced V-Q sub-matrix of the powerflow Jacobian is performed to assess voltage stability. Thesmallest real part of the V-Q sub-matrix’ eigenvalues is usedas a relative measure of the proximity to voltage instability.Furthermore, the associated eigenvectors provide informationon the critical voltage modes and the weak points in the grid,that is, the areas that are most prone to voltage instability. Theresults are summarized in Table II. With the increased RESpenetration, the average of the minimum of the real part ofall eigenvalues, henceforth called the minimum eigenvalue, isreduced from 49.5 Np/s for the BAU scenario to 42.3 Np/s forthe ZP scenario. With an increased prosumer penetration, theaverage of the minimum eigenvalue over the simulated yearincreases from 42.3 Np/s (ZP) to 48.8 Np/s (HP). Observe inFig. 6 that the results of the modal analysis confirm the resultsloadability analysis. The general trend remains the same;higher RES penetration with conventional demand reduces theminimum real value of an eigenvalue, which implies a lowervoltage stability margin.

Another observation that can be made from the modalanalysis concerns the location of the weak points in thesystem, that is, the buses with the highest participation factorin the critical voltage modes. These clearly change with theincreased RES penetration. In the BAU Scenario, the weakestpoints are typically buses with large loads (e.g. 306 and 308,representing Melbourne). With the increased RES penetrationand no prosumers (ZP), however, the weakest part of thesystem become buses located close to RESs (e.g. 505 and410, representing, respectively a large wind farm in SA and alarge solar PV farm in QLD).

Further, we observed that the voltage stability margin inthe system improves significantly when there are more syn-chronous generators in the grid, due to their superior reactivepower support capability compared to RES. The participationfactor analysis of the renewable scenarios revealed that SAand QLD are the most voltage constrained regions where thepenetration of WFs and utility PVs is higher compared to

12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96

Load

abili

ty M

argi

n (G

W)

0

2

4

6

8Loadability analysis

BAU Low prosumer penetration High prosumer penetration

Time (hours)12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96R

eal(e

igen

valu

e) (

Nep

er/s

)

48

50

52

Modal analysis

BAU Low prosumer penetration High prosumer penetration

Fig. 6. Comparison of the loadability and modal analysis results for a typicalsummer week with high demand (12-15 January) for the load increase scenarioNEM for BAU, and low and high prosumer penetration.

other regions in the NEM, which can be, to a large extent,mitigated with a sufficiently large penetration of prosumers.This clearly illustrates that RESs and prosumers change powersystem stability in ways that have not been experienced before,which requires a further in-depth analysis.

IV. CONCLUSION

The emergence of demand side technologies, in particularrooftop PV, battery storage and energy management systems ischanging the way electricity consumers source and consumeelectric power, which requires new demand models for thelong-term analysis of future grids. In this paper, we proposea generic demand model that captures the aggregate effectof a large number of prosumers on the load profile that canbe used in market simulation. The model uses a bi-leveloptimization framework, in which the upper level employs aunit commitment problem to minimize generation cost, andthe lower level problem maximizes collective prosumers’ self-consumption. To that effect, the model implicitly assumesan efficient mechanism for demand response aggregation, forexample peer-to-peer energy trading or any other form oftransactive energy. Given that any efficient mechanism fordemand response aggregation that aims to minimize gener-ation cost will utilize self-generation first, the self-consumingassumption appears reasonable at the level of abstractionassumed in long-term future grid scenario analysis. Moreover,the model is generic in that it does not depend on specificpractical implementation details that will vary in the long-run.

To showcase the efficacy of the proposed model, we studythe impact of prosumers on the performance, loadability andvoltage stability of the Australian NEM with a high RESpenetration. The results show that an increased prosumerpenetration flattens the demand profile, which increases load-ability and voltage stability, except in situations with a lowunderlying demand and an excess of RES generation, wherethe aggregate demand might increase due to battery charging.The analysis also revealed that with a high RES penetration,the weakest points in the network move from large load

9

centers to areas with high RES penetration. Also, loadabilityand voltage stability are highly dependent on the amount ofsynchronous generation due to their superior reactive powercapability compared to RES, which requires further analysis.

Our future work will focus on designing market mechanismsfor large scale aggregation of distributed energy resourcesto enable the participation of prosumers in power systemoperation.

APPENDIX

MILP FORMULATION OF THE LOWER-LEVEL KKTOPTIMALITY CONDITIONS

For the sake of completeness, we provide the completeoptimization problem below. The upper-level problem (1)-(9)remains the same. The price-anticipatory prosumer behavior iscaptured in constraint (10), defined as the solution to the lower-level prosumer aggregation problem. To be able to incorporateit in the upper-level problem, we first need to convert it intoa set of MILP constraints. We do that by using the optimality(KKT) conditions of the underlying optimization problem. TheKKT conditions follow from the associated Lagrangian:

L(x,λ,µ) = f(x) + λ>g(x) + µ>h(x), (16)

where x = pflxd , pb, eb is the decision vector of the lower-

level problem; f(x) is the objective function (11); g(x) is thevector of equality constraints (17)-(18); h(x) is the vector ofinequality constraints (19)-(23); λ> = λm,ph , λm,eh is thevector of Lagrange multipliers associated with the equalityconstraints, and µ> = µflx,m

h , µm,p

h , µm,ph , µm,eh , µm,eh is the

vector of Lagrange multipliers associated with the inequalityconstraints.

The KKT optimality conditions consist of:• primal feasibility (17)-(23) with the associated Lagrange

multipliers given in parentheses:

pflx,md,h + pmpv,h − pmb,h − p

u,md,h = 0, (λm,ph ) (17)

emb,h − ηmb emb,h−1 − pmb,h = 0, (λm,eh ) (18)

− pflx,md,h ≤ 0, (µflx,m

h ) (19)

pmb− pmb,h ≤ 0, (µ

m,p

h ) (20)

pmb,h − pmb ≤ 0, (µm,ph ) (21)

emb − emb,h ≤ 0, (µm,eh ) (22)

emb,h − emb ≤ 0, (µm,eh ) (23)

• dual feasibility:

µflx,mh , µ

m,p

h , µm,ph , µm,eh , µm,eh ≥ 0, (24)

• stationarity (25)-(27):

∂L∂pflx,m

d,h

= 1 + λm,ph − µflx,mh = 0, (25)

∂L∂pmb,h

= −λm,ph − λm,eh − µm,ph + µm,ph = 0, (26)

∂L∂emb,h

= λm,eh − ηmb λm,eh+1 − µ

m,eh + µm,eh = 0, (27)

• complementary slackness (28)-(32):

pflx,md,h µflx,m

h = 0, (28)

(−pmb

+ pmb,h)µm,p

h = 0, (29)

(−pmb,h + pmb )µm,ph = 0, (30)

(−emb + emb,h)µm,eh = 0, (31)

(−emb,h + emb )µm,eh = 0. (32)

Complementary slackness conditions (28)-(32) are bilinear,however they can be linearized by introducing one binaryvariable b and a sufficiently large and positive constant Mresulting in two constraints per complementarity slacknesscondition (42)-(51).

Given that the KKT conditions are sufficient and necessaryfor optimality, the bi-level constraint (10) can be replaced withmixed integer linear constraints (33)-(51):

pflx,md,h + pmpv,h − pmb,h − p

u,md,h = 0, (33)

emb,h − ηmb emb,h−1 − pmb,h = 0, (34)

1− µflx,mh + λm,ph = 0, (35)

− λm,ph − µm,ph + µm,ph − λm,eh = 0, (36)

− µm,eh + µm,eh + λm,eh − ηmb λm,eh−1 = 0, (37)

pmb− pmb,h ≤ 0, (38)

pmb,h − pmb ≤ 0, (39)

emb − emb,h ≤ 0, (40)

emb,h − emb ≤ 0, (41)

pflx,md,h −M

flxbflx,mh ≤ 0, (42)

µflx,mh −Mflx(1− bflx,m

h ) ≤ 0, (43)

pmb,h −Mpbm,p

h ≤ 0, (44)

µm,p

h −Mp(1− bm,ph ) ≤ 0, (45)

− pmb,h −Mpbm,ph ≤ 0, (46)

µm,ph −Mp(1− bm,ph ) ≤ 0, (47)emb,h −Meb

m,eh ≤ 0, (48)

µm,eh −Me(1− bm,eh ) ≤ 0, (49)

− emb,h −Mebm,eh ≤ 0, (50)

µm,eh −Me(1− bm,eh ) ≤ 0, (51)

which adds the following additional decision variables to theupper-level problem (1)-(9):

bflx,mh , b

m,p

h , bm,ph , bm,eh , bm,eh ∈ 0, 1,

pmb,h, λm,ph , λm,eh ∈ R,

pflx,md,h , emb,h, µ

flx,mh , µ

m,p

h , µm,ph , µm,eh , µm,eh ∈ R+.

The resulting optimization problem is an MILP that can besolved efficiently with off-the-shelf solvers.

REFERENCES

[1] EPRI, “The Integrated Grid Realizing the Full Value of Central andDistributed Energy Resources,” Tech. Rep., 2014.

[2] Morgan Stanley, “Australia Utilities Asia Insight: Solar & Batteries,”Tech. Rep., 2016.

10

[3] Energy Networks Australia and CSIRO, “Electricity Network Transfor-mation Roadmap: Key Concepts Report,” Tech. Rep. December, 2016.

[4] CSIRO, “Future Grid Forum: Change and Choice for Australian Elec-tricity System,” Tech. Rep., 2013.

[5] B. Kampman, M. Afman, and J. Blommerde, “The potential of energycitizens in the European Union,” CE Delft, Tech. Rep., 2016.

[6] M. Wright and P. Hearps, “Zero Carbon Australia Stationary EnergyPlan,” The University of Melbourne Energy Research Institute, Tech.Rep., 2010.

[7] B. Elliston, I. MacGill, and M. Diesendorf, “Least Cost 100% RenewableElectricity Scenarios in the Australian National Electricity Market,”Energy Policy, vol. 59, pp. 270–282, Aug. 2013.

[8] C. Budischak, and et al., “Cost-Minimized Combinations of WindPower, Solar Power and Electrochemical Storage, Powering the Gridup to 99.9% of the Time,” Journal of Power Sources, vol. 225, pp.60–74, Mar. 2013.

[9] I. G. Mason, S. C. Page, and A. G. Williamson, “A 100% renewableelectricity generation system for New Zealand utilising hydro, wind,geothermal and biomass resources,” Energy Policy, vol. 38, pp. 3973–3984, Aug. 2010.

[10] Australian Energy Market Operator (AEMO), “100 per cent renewablestudy - modelling outcomes,” Tech. Rep., 2013.

[11] L. Fahey and R. M. Randall, Learning From the Future. Wiley, 1998.[12] J. Foster, C. Froome, C. Greig, O. Hoegh-Guldberg, P. Meredith,

L. Molyneaus, T. Saha, L. Wagner, and B. Ball, “Delivering a com-petitive Australian power system Part 2: The challenges, the scenarios,”Tech. Rep. Oct, 2013.

[13] G. Sanchis, “e-Highway2050: Europe’s future secure and sustainableelectricity infrastructure. Project results.” Tech. Rep., 2015.

[14] M. Hand, S. Baldwin, E. DeMeo, J. Reilly, T. Mai, D. Arent, G. Porro,M. Meshek, and D. Sandor, “Renewable Electricity Futures Study),”National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), Tech. Rep., 2012.

[15] B. Elliston, J. Riesz, and I. MacGill, “What cost for more renewables?The incremental cost of renewable generation An Australian NationalElectricity Market case study,” Renewable Energy, vol. 95, pp. 127 –139, 2016.

[16] H. Marzooghi, D. J. Hill, and G. Verbic, “Performance and stabilityassessment of future grid scenarios for the Australian NEM,” in 2014Australasian Universities Power Engineering Conference (AUPEC), Sep2014.

[17] F. Ramos, C. Canizares, and K. Bhattacharya, “Effect of price responsivedemand on the operation of microgrids,” in 18th International Confer-ence on the Power Systems Computation (PSCC 2014), Aug 2014.

[18] K. Bruninx, D. Patteeuw, E. Delarue, L. Helsen, and W. D’haeseleer,“Short-term demand response of flexible electric heating systems: Theneed for integrated simulations,” in 10th International Conference onthe European Energy Market (EEM 2012), May 2012.

[19] M. Zugno, J. Miguel Morales, P. Pinson, and H. Madsen, “A bilevelmodel for electricity retailers’ participation in a demand response marketenvironment,” Energy Economics, vol. 36, pp. 182 – 197, 2013.

[20] S. Mathieu, Q. Louveaux, D. Ernst, and B. Cornelusse, “A quantitativeanalysis of the effect of flexible loads on reserve markets,” in 18thInternational Conference on the Power Systems Computation (PSCC2014), Aug 2014.

[21] O. Megel, J. L. Mathieu, and G. Andersson, “Scheduling distributedenergy storage units to provide multiple services under forecast error,”International Journal of Electrical Power & Energy Systems, vol. 72,pp. 48 – 57, 2015.

[22] M. Gonzalez Vaya, and G. Andersson, “Optimal bidding strategy of aplug-in electric vehicle aggregator in day-ahead electricity markets underuncertainty,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 30, no. 5, pp.2375–2385, Sep 2015.

[23] S. Teske, T. Brown, E. Troster, P.-P. Schierhorn, and T. Ackermann,“PowE[R] 2030 - A European Grid for 3/4 Renewable Energy by 2030,”Greenpeace Germany, Tech. Rep., 2014.

[24] H. Marzooghi, G. Verbic, and D. J. Hill, “Aggregated demand responsemodelling for future grid scenarios,” Sustainable Energy, Grids andNetworks, vol. 5, pp. 94 – 104, 2016.

[25] S. Riaz, H. Marzooghi, G. Verbic, A. C. Chapman, and D. J. Hill,“Impact study of prosumers on loadability and voltage stability offuture grids,” in 2016 IEEE International Conference on Power SystemTechnology (POWERCON), 2016.

[26] P. Kundur, Power System Stability and Control. EPRI Power SystemEngineering Series, McGraw-Hill, 1994.

[27] T. Van Cutsem, and C. Vournas, Voltage Stability of Electric PowerSystems, ser. Kluwer international series in engineering and computerscience. Springer, 1998.

[28] H. Marzooghi, D. J. Hill, and G. Verbic, “Aggregated Effect of Price-Taking Users Equipped with Emerging Demand-Side Technologies onPerformance of Future Grids,” in 2016 IEEE International Conferenceon Power System Technology (POWERCON), 2016.

[29] H. Tischer, and G. Verbic, “Towards a Smart Home Energy ManagementSystem-A Dynamic Programming Approach,” in Innovative Smart GridTechnologies Asia, 2011.

[30] A. C. Chapman, G. Verbic, and D. J. Hill, “Algorithmic and strategicaspects to integrating demand-side aggregation and energy managementmethods,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 7, no. 6, pp. 2748–2760, Nov 2016.

[31] M. Gibbard, and D. Vowles, “Simplified 14-generator model of the SEAustralian power system,” The University of Adelaide, Tech. Rep., 2010.

[32] Australian Energy Market Operator (AEMO), “2012 NTNDP Assump-tions and Inputs,” Tech. Rep., 2012.

[33] ——, “Emerging Technologies Information Paper, National ElectricityForecasting Report,” Tech. Rep., 2015.

[34] E. Vaahedi, C. Fuchs, W. Xu, Y. Mansour, H. Hamadanizadeh, and G. K.Morison, “Voltage stability contingency screening and ranking,” IEEETransactions on Power Systems, vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 256–265, Feb 1999.

[35] K. Clark, N. W. Miller, and J. J. Sanchez-Gasca, “Modeling of GE WindTurbine Generators for Grid Studies,” Tech. Rep., 2013.

Shariq Riaz (S’14) received the B.Sc. and M.Sc. de-grees in electrical engineering from the University ofEngineering and Technology Lahore, Lahore, Pak-istan in 2009 and 2012, respectively. He is currentlypursuing the Ph.D. degree from The University ofSydney, Sydney, Australia. His expertise is in powersystem operation, demand response, and electric-ity markets. His current research interests includeintegration of renewable generation, storage andprosumers into electricity markets, demand responseand operation of concentrated solar thermal plants.

Hesamoddin Marzooghi (S’13-M’16) graduatedwith Bachelor and Masters degrees in electricalengineering (power) both with first class honorsfrom Shiraz University, Iran in 2009 and 2011,respectively. He was awarded his PhD degree inelectrical engineering (power) at The University ofSydney in 2016. He is now a research associate atThe Central Queensland University (CQUniversity),Australia, and an academic visitor at The Universityof Manchester, UK. Hesamoddin’s research interestsare in stability analysis and control of power systems

with high penetration of renewable energy sources, distributed generation andenergy storage, planning of future grids, and applications of intelligent systemsin power engineering.

Gregor Verbic (S’98-M03-SM’10) received theB.Sc., M.Sc., and Ph.D. degrees in electrical engi-neering from the University of Ljubljana, Ljubljana,Slovenia, in 1995, 2000, and 2003, respectively. In2005, he was a NATO-NSERC Postdoctoral Fellowwith the University of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON,Canada. Since 2010, he has been with the Schoolof Electrical and Information Engineering, The Uni-versity of Sydney, Sydney, NSW, Australia. Hisexpertise is in power system operation, stability andcontrol, and electricity markets. His current research

interests include integration of renewable energies into power systems andmarkets, optimization and control of distributed energy resources, demandresponse, and energy management in residential buildings. He was a recipientof the IEEE Power and Energy Society Prize Paper Award in 2006. He is anAssociate Editor of the IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid.

11

GARMROODI et al.: IMPACT OF TIE-LINE POWER ON INTER-AREA MODES WITH INCREASED PENETRATION OF WIND POWER 3059

Mehdi Garmroodi (S'13) received the B.Sc. degreein electrical engineering from Sharif University ofTechnology, Tehran, Iran, and the M.Sc. degree inpower engineering from Amirkabir University ofTechnology, Tehran, Iran. He is currently workingtoward the Ph.D. degree at The University ofSydney.His research interests include power system

stability and control, integration of renewableenergy sources into power systems, and smart gridtechnologies.

David J. Hill (S'72–M'76–SM'91–F'93–LF'14)received the Ph.D. degree in electrical engineeringfrom the University of Newcastle, Australia, in 1976.He holds the Chair of Electrical Engineering in the

Department of Electrical and Electronic Engineeringat the University of HongKong. He is also a part-timeProfessor of Electrical Engineering at The Universityof Sydney, Australia. During 2005–2010, he was anAustralian Research Council Federation Fellow at theAustralian National University. Since 1994, he hasheld various positions at the University of Sydney,

Australia, including the Chair of Electrical Engineering until 2002 and againduring 2010–2013 along with an ARC Professorial Fellowship. He has also heldacademic and substantial visiting positions at the universities of Melbourne,California (Berkeley), Newcastle (Australia), Lund (Sweden), Munich, HongKong (City and Polytechnic). His general research interests are in control sys-tems, complex networks, power systems and stability analysis. His work is nowmainly on control and planning of future energy networks and basic stabilityand control questions for dynamic networks.Prof. Hill is a Fellow of the Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics,

the Australian Academy of Science, and the Australian Academy of Techno-logical Sciences and Engineering. He is also a Foreign Member of the RoyalSwedish Academy of Engineering Sciences.

Gregor Verbič (S'98–M'03–SM'10) received theB.Sc., M.Sc., and Ph.D. degrees in electrical engi-neering from the University of Ljubljana, Ljubljana,Slovenia, in 1995, 2000, and 2003, respectively.In 2005, he was a North Atlantic Treaty Organ-

ization-Natural Sciences and Engineering ResearchCouncil of Canada Post-Doctoral Fellow with theUniversity of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON, Canada.Since 2010, he has been with the School of Electricaland Information Engineering, University of Sydney,Sydney, NSW, Australia. His expertise is in power

system operation, stability and control, and electricity markets. His currentresearch interests include integration of renewable energies into power systemsand markets, optimization and control of distributed energy resources, demandresponse, and energy management in residential buildings.Dr. Verbič was a recipient of the IEEE Power and Energy Society Prize Paper

Award in 2006. He is an associate editor of the IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON SMARTGRID.

Jin Ma (M'06) received the B.S. and M.S. degreefrom Zhejiang University, Hangzhou, China, in 1997and 2000, respectively, and the Ph.D. degree fromTsinghua University, Beijing, China, in 2004, all inelectrical engineering.From 2004 to 2013, he was a Faculty Member

of North China Electric Power University. SinceSeptember, 2013, he has been with the School ofElectrical and Information Engineering, Universityof Sydney. His major research interests are loadmodeling, nonlinear control system, dynamic power

system, and power system economics.Dr. Ma is a registered Chartered Engineer in the U.K. He is the member of

CIGRE W.G. C4.605 “Modeling and aggregation of loads in flexible powernetworks” and the corresponding member of CIGRE Joint Workgroup C4-C6/CIRED “Modeling and dynamic performance of inverter based generation inpower system transmission and distribution studies.”

David J. Hill (S’72-M’76-SM’91-F’93-LF’14) re-ceived the Ph.D. degree in electrical engineeringfrom the University of Newcastle, Australia, in 1976.He holds the Chair of Electrical Engineering in theDepartment of Electrical and Electronic Engineeringat the University of Hong Kong. He is also apart-time Professor of Electrical Engineering at TheUniversity of Sydney, Australia. During 20052010,he was an Australian Research Council FederationFellow at the Australian National University. Since1994, he has held various positions at the University

of Sydney, Australia, including the Chair of Electrical Engineering until 2002and again during 20102013 along with an ARC Professorial Fellowship. Hehas also held academic and substantial visiting positions at the universitiesof Melbourne, California (Berkeley), Newcastle (Australia), Lund (Sweden),Munich, Hong Kong (City and Polytechnic). His general research interests arein control systems, complex networks, power systems and stability analysis.His work is now mainly on control and planning of future energy networksand basic stability and control questions for dynamic networks.

Prof. Hill is a Fellow of the Society for Industrial and Applied Mathe-matics, the Australian Academy of Science, and the Australian Academy ofTechnological Sciences and Engineering. He is also a Foreign Member of theRoyal Swedish Academy of Engineering Sciences.

Archie C. Chapman (M’14) received the B.A.degree in math and political science, and the B.Econ.(Hons.) degree from the University of Queensland,Brisbane, QLD, Australia, in 2003 and 2004, re-spectively, and the Ph.D. degree in computer sciencefrom the University of Southampton, Southampton,U.K., in 2009. He is currently a Research Fellowin Smart Grids with the School of Electrical andInformation Engineering, Centre for Future EnergyNetworks, The University of Sydney, Sydney, NSW,Australia. He has expertise is in game-theoretic

and reinforcement learning techniques for optimization and control in largedistributed systems. His research focuses on integrating renewables into legacypower networks, using distributed energy and load scheduling methods, and ondesigning tariffs and market mechanisms that support efficient use of existinginfrastructure and new controllable devices.