From Land to Laborious Labour

6
Handout 1 4 We don’t explain exogenous variable We do explain endogenous variables We want to see how endo. Vars change when we tweak exo vars. 5 Start with individual decision makers (consumers and firms) Choose our objective And consider our constraints This is very much like micro But then aggregate from individuals to the whole economy (this is the more difficult part of macro) We want to understand how we reach a general equilibrium under different markets where everything is consistent with assumptions, and how things change with changing exo variables. Macroeconomics gives a crucial role to what happens over time, people’s expectations play a crucial role, (the lack of acknowledgement of this was an empirical downfall of early macroeconomic theory) What’s the point of having a model? Well in one sense it’s scientific, we want to explain phenomena; we might also want to make predictions about the future or to inform policy, we need a model to understand the counterfactual. 6 The 2 big overarching issues are long run growth and business cycles (economic fluctuations), both of these are references to GDP. 7 This is a time-series of US real GDP. Here we see the 2 significant fluctuations, the great depression, and the bounce-back in reaction to the war. 8 It’s helpful to think of the series in slide 7 with a logarithmic scale, as we see an exponential pattern to the raw data, so by taking logs we see a more or less straight plot, with our 2 important deviations. Taking logs is useful as then we can interpret the gradient of the graph as the growth rate (you can’t do that with raw numbers). So we see that most of the 20 th century US expansion is growing at a fairly constant rate 9

description

An aesthetic study of the industrialisation of the western society since the industrial revolution, and the atomisation which comes with this.

Transcript of From Land to Laborious Labour

Handout 1

4

We dont explain exogenous variable

We do explain endogenous variables

We want to see how endo. Vars change when we tweak exo vars.

5

Start with individual decision makers (consumers and firms)

Choose our objective

And consider our constraints

This is very much like micro

But then aggregate from individuals to the whole economy (this is the more difficult part of macro)

We want to understand how we reach a general equilibrium under different markets where everything is consistent with assumptions, and how things change with changing exo variables.

Macroeconomics gives a crucial role to what happens over time, peoples expectations play a crucial role, (the lack of acknowledgement of this was an empirical downfall of early macroeconomic theory)

Whats the point of having a model? Well in one sense its scientific, we want to explain phenomena; we might also want to make predictions about the future or to inform policy, we need a model to understand the counterfactual.

6

The 2 big overarching issues are long run growth and business cycles (economic fluctuations), both of these are references to GDP.

7

This is a time-series of US real GDP.

Here we see the 2 significant fluctuations, the great depression, and the bounce-back in reaction to the war.

8

Its helpful to think of the series in slide 7 with a logarithmic scale, as we see an exponential pattern to the raw data, so by taking logs we see a more or less straight plot, with our 2 important deviations.

Taking logs is useful as then we can interpret the gradient of the graph as the growth rate (you cant do that with raw numbers).

So we see that most of the 20th century US expansion is growing at a fairly constant rate

9

A mathematical justification for the above, underlined claim in slide 8.

In addition we may want to explicitly take out the trend, that is to show a version of this graph that includes just the business cycle, so remove anything that we think of as the trend. Its helpful to keep those long-run and shirt-run issues separate when thinking about the data.

11

In this case you take the difference between the log of the difference of the actual GDP series and your trend line, this is called the residual. Because it is the residual of a variable you have taken logs of, it can be interpreted as the percentage deviation from the trend. That residual we call the business cycle.

12

So you see the order of magnitude of business cycle fluctuations.

A typical business cycle is +/- 5% above and below trend

A big debate in macroeconomics is whether we could od better by having monetary policy try to smooth out the business cycle.

13

So that was the data on the 2 big issues, growth and business cycles.

Some other key macroeconomic debates we will talk about are illustrated by the following data.

14

Surprising post-war growth of the state.

What are the consequences of this? In particular to what extent does that extra govt spending come at the cost of less private spending on consumption and investment. To what extent is there crowding out? (by saving as a reaction to anticipated tax rises, and increased govt. borrowing raising the interest rate, on the other hand will the increasing govt. spending pay for itself by raising productivity?)

Should the govt. use fiscal policy to try to smooth out the business cycle, Keynesian vs. Monetarism.

15

US govt. debt is special because historically a lot of US debt is held by US citizens, so as a country it is not necessarily that the US is indebted, we only have a liability for the govt. and an asset for the citizens (it is internal). In recent years more creditors come from outside the US, and this debt starts to become a liability for the US as a whole.

16

In recent decades inflation targeting is the paradigm monetary policy which central banks have wanted to adopt.

Throughout WW2, the start of the cold war and the Korean war, the policy of the fed was explicitly to hold down borrowing costs for the US govt.

As you see, inflation at that time was very volatile.

He continues on with a history of 20th century monetary policy

17

What people were getting on their money in real terms, the nominal interest rate cannot go ve, though the real one spends about as much time ve as they do +ve.

Why is this possible, is this a good or bad thing? What are the consequences of a ve real interest rate? Is the central bank even responsible for this?

18

This graph shows us the volatility of growth and interest rates (not their nominal levels).

19

There has been huge growth in international trade in recent decades, which is reflected by this graph.

We see that he US current account deficit has been increasing significantly.

20

We see that there are fluctuations in interest rates faced by real-world borrowers, as well as those set by central banks.

22

The labour market is special in the sense that it is predicated on a long-term relationship between consumer and producer of labour.

Handout 2

3

If you were able to implement the 3 approaches perfectly, they should all agree.

5

There is no long-term investment, and the economy is closed (there is no trade with other islands)

8

Some firms pay wages, 5 million from the farm, and 4 million from the government, but we must also consider the government.

So far we have 4.5 million in taxes from firm, and a further 1 million levied directly on households (maybe a labour income tax or something), so total 5.5 million in taxes

Supposing the govt balances its budget, then it spends its 5.5 million on hiring employees (maybe soldiers or whatever).

So from the consumers perspective we have a total of 5+4+5.5 = 14.5 million income from wages.

Someone on the island must have made the loan to the farmer, so at some point someone has to get the 0.5 million interest the farmer pays in the form of income.

Similarly someone somewhere on the island receives the 24 million in profits in the form of income.

9

The restaurant gets 30 million revenue (so produces 30 million in value), but 12 million was spent on intermediate goods of coconuts. (If they were just a middle man breaking even they would sell all the coconuts to someone else for 12 million, the same price they bought them for from the farmer, they have done something to the coconuts to get 30 million in revenue, so have added a value of 18 million through their labour).

18

Govt. services are counted as a cost for accounting consistency, but doing this we have no measure of how much the services which the govt. provides are valued by the society (they do not enter the market or the GDP figures)

Shadow economy is not included in GDP statistics.

Handout 3

5

Looking at the difference in the nominal rise in GDP across 2 years in the same economy, how much of the change is due to the natural rise in the real quantity of goods produced and how much of it is simply inflation.

10

GDP Price Deflator by definition includes all the goods and services that go into measuring GDP, including I, G and X. CPI takes into account only C and M. That is the substantive difference of what it measures.

The method of calculating it is also different.

CPI uses less information, it uses the quantities from year 1, and prices from both years. The Deflator uses quantities and prices from both years.

The CPI will systematically turn out to be a little bit higher on average than the GDP deflator, because the deflator (by taking the quantities from year 2) is taking account of the fact that when the prices of goods go up, people typically substitute away, they will buy less of what gets expensive, more of what gets relatively cheaper, meaning that the cost of living doesnt go up by as much as if the consumers simply stuck to the spending patterns from the previous year (they are smart).

By accumulating these small differences in estimations over many decades you can create a significant discrepancy, which can matter if youre pension is tied to the inflation rate or whatever.

11

If youre an energy importer, then energy prices are going to be in the CPI but not in the GDP deflator.

13

In theory there is an assumption that there is no difference between what we classify as a mobile phone, or an apple in year 1, and what we classify as a mobile phone or an apple in year 2. However this assumption is not true so we cannot compare like-for-like, e.g. the cost of a mobile phone increasing over 10 years is not just inflation, it may also be the perceived (perceived by the market) quality of the good increasing.

What happens when a new product enters the market all together? E.g. go back long enough and there are no mobile phones at all, so no price to use when comparing with previous year. You can think of this as an extreme case of product improvement. The consensus view is that most measures of inflation are overstating inflation by 1 or 2 percent.

14

The problem here is that simply using the exchange rate can distort the picture.

P is price index of goods in the US; P* is the price index of goods in China; e is the price of 1 Yuan in dollars, the exchange rate.

Suppose, for the sake of argument, that people in China and the US are consuming the same basket of goods, and that those goods can be traded.

As the goods can be traded, we expect P and eP* to be very close, otherwise firms would just buy goods in one country and ship them to the other to make a profit, this in turn would equalise the market by increasing the supply of the good in the country with the higher sale price.

In practice we dont see this relationship P=eP*.

It holds fairly well for goods which can be traded very easily, but goods which cannot be (like haircuts) do not follow this rule.

So if its not equal, what do we expect? We tend to observe that prices tend to be higher in ricer countries.

A country is richer because in some section of the economy (where goods are traded, not home production) it is very very productive, but of course because workers can choose which occupation they take, you can expect the wages between the traded-goods and non-traded-goods sectors not to be completely unrelated.