Final Draft

43
International Capital Flows: Remedy or Curse? Keith Mellott Commonwealth Honors College Isenberg School of Management May 4, 2015 Abstract Capital account liberalization has increased the importance and prevalence of international capital flows. There is much debate over the risks and benefits of freely moving capital, especially during times of crisis and especially for developing countries. Capital flow “volatility” is often blamed for worsening the effects of financial crises in developing countries. In an attempt to control the behavior of capital flows, countries have implemented different types of capital controls to varying extents. I argue that capital controls have a relationship with capital inflow volume both during crises and in general. Specifically, I determine that capital account restrictiveness is related to lower volumes of capital inflows and vice versa.

Transcript of Final Draft

   

International  Capital  Flows:  Remedy  or  Curse?    

Keith  Mellott    

Commonwealth  Honors  College  

Isenberg  School  of  Management  

May  4,  2015  

   

Abstract    

Capital   account   liberalization   has   increased   the   importance   and   prevalence   of  

international   capital   flows.     There   is   much   debate   over   the   risks   and   benefits   of  

freely  moving  capital,  especially  during  times  of  crisis  and  especially  for  developing  

countries.     Capital   flow   “volatility”   is   often   blamed   for   worsening   the   effects   of  

financial   crises   in   developing   countries.     In   an   attempt   to   control   the   behavior   of  

capital   flows,   countries   have   implemented   different   types   of   capital   controls   to  

varying  extents.    I  argue  that  capital  controls  have  a  relationship  with  capital  inflow  

volume   both   during   crises   and   in   general.     Specifically,   I   determine   that   capital  

account  restrictiveness  is  related  to  lower  volumes  of  capital  inflows  and  vice  versa.      

 

1.  Literature  Review  

1.1   The  Growth  of  International  Capital  Flows  International  capital  flows  are  movements  of  money  across  country  borders  for  the  

purpose   of   investment,   business   activities,   or   trade.     Gross   international   capital  

flows  have  increased  drastically  over  the  past  half-­‐century  as  a  result  of  a  globalized  

economy,   changes   in   the   international   political   landscape,   and   advances   in  

technology.    As  gross   international   capital   flows  have  grown   in  volume,   they  have  

also   grown   in   importance,   especially   for   developing   countries.     The   growth   in  

international   capital   flows   became   markedly   more   rapid   in   the   mid   1990’s,   and  

exploded  in  the  mid  2000’s,  as   indicated  in  Figure  1.    Although  the  majority  of  the  

increases  in  capital  flows  are  attributable  to  advanced  countries,  Figure  1  indicates  

that  developing   countries  are   starting   to  account   for  a  bigger  portion  of   the  gross  

flows.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  The   dissipation   of   the   Soviet   Union,  which   occurred   in   1991,   is   one   of   the  

most   important   political   events   of   the   last   50   years.     The   collapse   of   the   USSR  

Figure  1:  Global  Gross  Capital  Inflows,  Advanced  and  Developing  Countries,  1980-­‐2010  This  figure  shows  annual  changes  in  global  gross  capital  inflows  and  separates  the  flows  that  are  attributable  to  developing  and  advanced  countries.  

Source:  Calculations  by  Adams-­‐Kane  &  Yueqing  Jia  (2013),  based  on  data  from  the  IMF  International  Financial  Statistics  (IFS)  database;  annual  basis.  

 

subsequently   created   15   states,   all   of   which   represented   new   opportunity   for  

international   investors.     According   to   World   Bank   data,   these   newly   formed  

countries   experienced   a   period   of   economic   depression   that   lasted   until   the   mid  

1990’s,  with  GDP  declining  and  poverty  increasing.    Domestic  financial  liberalization  

policies   allowed   these   countries   to   attract   outside   investors,   helping   to   satisfy  

domestic  needs  for  financial  capital,  savvy  management,  and  advanced  technologies.    

Levels   of   foreign   direct   investment   (FDI)   to   the   post-­‐Soviet   states   are   shown   in  

Figure  2.    It  is  obvious  that,  in  the  5  years  following  the  collapse  of  the  USSR,  there  

was  an  upward  trend  of  FDI  flows  to  these  countries.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

    1  

 

 

 

Communism  not  only  stymied   the  economic  relationship  between  capitalist  

nations   and   the   Soviet   Union.     The   influence   of   communism   had   spread   to   other  

parts  of   the  globe,  such  as  Latin  America.    Once  the  Soviet  regime  collapsed,  other  

countries   also   abandoned   their   communist   regimes.     Countries   such   as  Argentina,                                                                                                                  1  Figure  2  depicts  the  mean  net  FDI  inflow  volume  as  a  %  of  GDP  for  the  15  post-­‐Soviet  states:  Armenia,  Azerbaijan,  Belarus,  Estonia,  Georgia,  Kazakhstan,  Kyrgyzstan,  Latvia,  Lithuania,  Moldova,  Russia,  Tajikistan,  Turkmenistan,  Ukraine  &  Uzbekistan.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  for  FDI  as  a  %  of  GDP.  

0  

0.5  

1  

1.5  

2  

2.5  

3  

3.5  

4  

1992   1993   1994   1995   1996  

FDI  Net  InHlows  (%

 GDP)  

Year  FDI  Net  Inglows  (%  of  GDP)  

Figure  2:  Net  FDI  Inflows  to  Post-­‐Soviet  States  (%  of  GDP),  1992-­‐19961  This  figure  measures  the  average  annual  net  FDI  inflow  volume  to  post-­‐Soviet  States  from  1992  to  1996.      

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

Uruguay,   Chile   and   Brazil   all   instituted   democracy,   no   longer   viewing   the  

democratic,  developed  countries  of   the  world  as  political   and   ideological   enemies.    

These   countries   also   liberalized   their   international   trade   policies,   opening   their  

borders   to   foreign   investors   and   capital.     Foreign   direct   investment   inflows   to  

former  communist  Latin  America  nations  rose  quickly  throughout  the  1990’s,  which  

is  evident  in  Figure  3.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 2  

 

 

 

   

China’s  emergence  as  a  global  economic  power  is  another  political  factor  that  

has   contributed   to   the   vast   increases   in   global   gross   capital   flows.     During   the  

1980’s,   China   became   a   member   of   the   International   Monetary   Fund,   the   World  

Bank,   the   Asian   Development   Bank,   and   the   General   Agreement   on   Tariffs   and                                                                                                                  2  Figure  3  depicts  the  mean  net  FDI  inflow  volume  as  a  %  of  GDP  for  selected  Latin  American  countries  with  a  history  of  domestic  communist  regimes:  Argentina,  Bolivia,  Brazil,  Chile,  Colombia,  Ecuador,  Paraguay,  Peru,  Uruguay,  Venezuela,  El  Salvador  &  Guatemala.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  for  FDI  as  a  %  of  GDP.  

Figure  3:  Net  FDI  Inflows  to  Selected  Latin  American  Countries  (%  GDP),  1990-­‐19982  This  figure  illustrates  the  annual  changes  in  Net  FDI  inflows  to  Latin  American  countries  with  a  history  of  domestic  communist  regimes  from  1990-­‐1998.  

0  0.5  1  

1.5  2  

2.5  3  

3.5  4  

4.5  5  

1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998  

FDI  Net  InHlows  (%

 GDP)  

Year  

FDI  Net  Inglows  (%  GDP)  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  Data.  

 

Trade.     China   also   retooled   their   international   trade   policies,   becoming   more  

receptive   to   foreign   sources   of   capital   and   even   allowing   foreign   banks   to   open  

branches  within   the   country.     The  Chinese   government   implemented  policies   that  

incentivized  foreign  investment,  a  stark  contrast  from  the  policies  that  were  in  place  

prior   to   the   1980’s,   when   China   was   still   influenced   by   the   ideologies   of   Mao  

Zedong’s  regime.    The  economic  changes  instituted  in  China  had  their  desired  effect.    

According   to   data   from   the   World   Trade   Organization,   Chinese   trade   totaled   US  

$27.7   billion   in   1979,   which   accounted   for   0.7%   of   worldwide   trade.     By   1985,  

Chinese  trade  totaled  US  $70.8  billion,  which  accounted  for  2%  of  worldwide  trade.      

  Technological  advances  in  the  financial  industry  have  also  contributed  to  the  

increase   in   global   gross   capital   flows.     New   computing   capabilities   have   enabled  

financial   firms   to  cost-­‐effectively  create   index   funds  composed  of  assets   in   foreign  

countries.     These   indices   have   reduced   the   necessary   amount   of   capital   to   invest  

abroad,  making  it  feasible  for  individual  investors  to  include  foreign  assets  in  their  

portfolios.    Developing   countries  have   experienced   the   largest   relative   increase   in  

portfolio   inflows.      Mihaljek   (2008)  measured  changes   in  portfolio   flow  volume   to  

emerging  market   economies   over   time.       2005,   global   portfolio   flows   to   emerging  

market  economies  totaled  US  $127  billion.    By  2007,  this  number  had  increased  to  

US  $432  billion.      

 

1.2   Types  of  International  Capital  Flows  International   capital   flows   can   take   on   a   variety   of   forms,   one   of  which   is   foreign  

direct  investment  (FDI).    FDI  is  defined  as  a  party  buying  controlling  ownership  in  a  

business  enterprise  in  a  country  other  than  their  own.    The  IMF  defines  “controlling  

ownership”  as  an   investment   that  equates   to  10%  or  more  of  voting  stock.    FDI   is  

differentiated  from  other  types  of  capital  flows  because  it  generally  implies  that  the  

investor  has  long-­‐term  confidence  in  both  the  investment  and  the  economic  outlook  

of  the  country  where  the  capital  is  being  invested.    FDI  sometimes  brings  benefits  to  

the  host   country  aside   from  the  capital   itself.    The   foreign   investor  often  provides  

technology,   infrastructure,   and  managerial   skills   in   order   to   operate   the   business  

 

venture   to   their   liking.     A   2002   report   from   the   Organization   for   Economic  

Cooperation   and   Development   addressed   the   benefits   of   FDI.     “FDI   triggers  

technology  spillovers,  assists  human  capital  formation,  contributes  to  international  

trade   integration,   helps   create   a   more   competitive   business   environment   and  

enhances   enterprise   development.     All   of   these   contribute   to   higher   economic  

growth,  which  is  the  most  potent  tool  for  poverty  alleviation.”  

As   with   the   other   types   of   capital   flows,   the   level   of   global   FDI   flows   has  

grown  considerably  over  the  past  two  decades.    The  levels  of  net  global  FDI  inflows  

from   1980   to   20012   are   depicted   in   Figure   4.     Global   net   FDI   inflow   volume  

increased   rapidly   starting   in   the   early   1990’s   and   the   upward   trend   has   been  

consistent   throughout   time.         The   figure   shows   decreases   in   global   FDI   inflow  

volume  in  2000  and  2007,  which  are  attributable  to  global  crises  that  had  a  negative  

impact  on  investor  confidence.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure  4:  Global  FDI  Net  Inflow  Volume  ($US  Millions),  1980-­‐2012  This  figure  shows  annual  changes  in  global  FDI  Net  inflow  Volume  between  1980-­‐2012.  

-­‐$500,000.00  

$0.00  

$500,000.00  

$1,000,000.00  

$1,500,000.00  

$2,000,000.00  

$2,500,000.00  

$3,000,000.00  

Global  FDI  Net  InHlow  Volum

e  ($US  Millions)  

Year  

FDI  Net  Inglows  Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  for  KAOPEN  values.  

 

A  2009  United  Nations  Conference  on  Trade  and  Development  report  noted  

that  FDI  inflow  volume  to  developing  countries  has  grown  at  a  faster  rate  than  FDI  

inflow  volume  to  developed  countries.    Prior  to  the  1990’s,  global  outward  FDI  from  

developing  economies  was  very  minimal.    Over   the  past  20  years  however,   global  

outward   FDI   from  developing   economies   has   grown   significantly   in   both   nominal  

terms  and  relative  to  the  global  outward  FDI  from  developed  countries.    The  most  

important  determinant  of  a  country’s  outward  FDI  level  is  economic  growth,  which  

dictates  the  demand  side  of  investment  and  the  demand  for  goods  and  services  from  

foreign   countries.     As   developing   economies   continue   to   grow,   their   demand   for  

investment  and  foreign  goods  and  services  will  increase  and  their  levels  of  outward  

FDI  are  expected  to  do  the  same.  

Foreign   portfolio   investment   (FPI),   a   financial   transaction   in   which   an  

individual  or  institution  purchases  foreign  bonds  or  equity,  is  another  type  of  capital  

flow.    Portfolio  flows  are  more  liquid  than  FDI  flows,  as  they  can  be  transferred  to  

other  parties  more  easily.    Portfolio   flows  are  generally   regarded  as  more  volatile  

than  FDI  flows  and  liquidity  is  one  of  the  primary  reasons  for  this.    Another  reason  

for  this  volatility  is  herding  behavior  in  financial  markets,  which  is  the  tendency  of  

asset  managers  to  follow  the  behavior  of  other  asset  managers,  causing  them  to  take  

action   in  ways   that   they   independently  would   not.    Hwang  &   Salmon   (2004)   find  

that  herding  towards  the  market  is  significant,  both  when  the  market  is  falling  and  

rising.     Another   reason   for   portfolio   flow   volatility   is   asymmetric   information  

between  financial  markets.    Portes  &  Rey  (2005)  find  that  inter-­‐country  differences  

in  informational  wealth,  proxied  by  variables  such  as  telephone  traffic  and  amount  

of   bank   branches,   had   significant   effects   on   the   behavior   of   cross-­‐border   equity  

flows.     Informational  advantages   incentivize  the   international  movement  of  capital  

as  information  bearers  seize  opportunities  to  profit.  

Figure  5  shows  how  global  FDI  and  portfolio  flows  have  changed  in  volume  

between   1995   and   2009.     The   figure   indicates   that,   after   peaking   around   1997,  

portfolio   flows   declined   until   around   2002.     A   2002   UNDP   Report   attributes   this  

decrease  to  the  Asian  financial  crisis,  which  made  asset  managers  wary  of  investing  

in   foreign   equities   and   bonds.     Portfolio   flows   had   an   even   more   pronounced  

 

reversal   in   response   to   the   2008   financial   crisis,   dropping   precipitously   before  

rebounding   in   2009.     The   figure   indicates   that   FDI   flows   reversed   one   year   after  

portfolio   flows.     This   reflects   the   difference   in   liquidity   between   the   two   types   of  

flows.    When   the   crisis   began   in   2008,   asset  managers   could   immediately   sell   off  

their  portfolio  investments,  whereas  investors  had  to  remain  committed  to  their  FDI  

flows  in  the  short-­‐term.      

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Ananchotikul   &   Zhang   (2014)   discovered   that   portfolio   flows   to   emerging  

markets  have  grown   in   volume  and  volatility   since  2003.    The  authors   found   that  

portfolio  flows  to  emerging  markets  are  very  responsive  to  market  trends,  such  as  

monetary  policies  in  advanced  economies  and  global  aversion  to  risk.    The  authors’  

calculations   indicated   that   there   is   statistically   significant   correlation  between   the  

behavior  of  portfolio  flows  to  emerging  markets  and  asset  prices  in  those  markets,  

specifically   stock   market   indices,   10-­‐year   government   bond   yields   and   exchange  

Figure  5:  Composition  of  Private  Capital  Flows,  1995-­‐2009  (US$  billions)  This  figure  measures  annual  changes  in  global  portfolio  investment  flows  and  FDI  flows  between  1995  and  2009.  

Source:  Calculated  for  2002  UNDP  Report,  based  on  data  from  World  Bank,  Global  Finance  for  Development,  and  IMF,  Balance  of  Payment  Statistics  2009.  

 

rates.    During   times  of  portfolio  outflows   from  emerging  markets,   there  also  were  

drops   in   the   value   of   stock   market   indices   and   increases   in   10-­‐year   government  

bond   yields.     Periods   of   portfolio   outflows   from   emerging  market   economies   also  

were   concurrent  with  depreciation   in   those  markets.     The   authors   concluded   that  

portfolio   flows   are   generally   more   volatile   than   other   types   of   capital   flows,   but  

especially   so  during   times  of   financial   recession.    The  measured  effect  of  portfolio  

flows  on  asset  prices  during  a  recession  was  5-­‐10  times  greater  than  the  magnitude  

during  non-­‐recessionary  time  periods.  

The  United  Nations  Development  Programme  published  a  report  in  2001  on  

Millenial  Development  Goals,  acknowledging  the  risks  that  emerging  markets  face  as  

a  result  of  portfolio  flow  volatility.    “The  consequences  of  such  volatility  for  growth  

are   obvious,   especially   in   countries   highly   reliant   on   such   flows   for   investment.    

When   investment   sources   are   unpredictable   and   volatile,   so   is   growth.     This   is  

especially  the  case  for  the  smaller,  lower-­‐income  countries  where  many  FDI  projects  

are   huge   in   relation   to   the   size   of   the   host   economy   and   because   these   countries  

tend  to  be  much  less  diversified  and  depend  on  one  or  two  large  projects  or  sectors.”  

  Private  loans  are  another  type  of  capital  flow.    They  consist  of  every  type  of  

bank   loan   as   well   as   loans   from   other   sectors,   such   as   trade   financing   loans,  

mortgages   and   repurchase   agreements.     Private   loans   are   often   divided   into   two  

categories:  short-­‐term  and  long-­‐term.    The  likelihood  of  short-­‐term  debt  to  expose  

countries  to  risk  of  crisis  is  contested  in  economic  literature.    Stiglitz  (2000)  argues  

that,  by  liberalizing  the  short-­‐term  capital  account,  a  country  opens  itself  to  the  risk  

of   capital   flight,  which   occurs  when   assets   quickly   flow   out   of   a   country.     Capital  

flight  decreases   the   level  of  domestic  wealth  and   is  almost  always  associated  with  

depreciation   of   the   domestic   currency.     Diamond   &   Rajan   (2001)   assert   that  

structural  flaws  are  to  blame  for  countries  being  exposed  to  such  risks.    “Short-­‐term  

debt   mirrors   the   nature   of   the   investment   being   financed   and   the   institutional  

environment   that   enables   investors   to   enforce   repayment.     It   is   no   surprise   that  

illiquid   or   poor   quality   investment  when   a   bank   or   banking   system   is   close   to   its  

debt  capacity  will   result   in  a  buildup  of   short-­‐term  debt.    The  higher   likelihood  of  

crisis   stems,  not   from   the   short-­‐term  debt,  but   from   the   illiquidity  and  potentially  

 

low   creditworthiness   of   the   investment   being   financed.”     Conventional   economic  

wisdom  dictates  that  countries,  especially  those  with  developing  economies,  should  

be  wary   of   short-­‐term   loan   flows   because   they   are  more   liquid   and   volatile   than  

long-­‐term  loan  flows.  

 

1.3   Benefits  of  Capital  Flows  &  Recessionary  Trends  One   feature   of   the   globalized   economy   is   an   integrated   international   financial  

market.    An  interconnected  financial  system  facilitates  the  uninhibited  movement  of  

capital  across  countries.    In  theory,  international  financial  integration  should  allow  

for  capital  to  be  allocated  in  the  most  efficient  ways.    Fischer  (1997)  elaborated  on  

these  benefits.    “Free  capital  movements  facilitate  a  more  efficient  global  allocation  

of   savings,   and   help   channel   resources   into   their   most   productive   uses,   thus  

increasing   economic   growth   and   welfare.”     Bailliu   (2000)   agrees   with   Fischer’s  

assertion   that   freely   moving   capital   does   indeed   have   the   potential   to   maximize  

economic   growth   and   welfare,   but   argues   that,   in   developing   countries,   freely  

moving  capital  can  only  maximize  economic  benefits  if  the  domestic  banking  sector  

has   achieved   a  minimum   level   of   development   and   sophistication.     Bailliu   (2000)  

suggested   that   there   are   three   ways   capital   flows   can   foster   domestic   growth:  

increasing  domestic   investment   rates,   facilitating   investments   from   foreign  agents  

with   positive   spillover   effects   (such   as   technology   transfers),   and   increasing  

domestic  financial  intermediation.  

Fischer  (1997)  points  out  that  free  capital  movement  benefits  capital-­‐seeking  

agents   because   institutions,   firms   and   individual   investors   have   access   to   ever-­‐

increasing   sources   of   capital.     The   author   notes   that   foreign   capital  markets   have  

grown  substantially  in  terms  of  the  volume  of  funds  being  distributed  on  an  annual  

basis.     Enhanced   capital   access   can   also   reduce   the   cost   of   capital.     International  

sources   of   capital   are   oftentimes   cheaper   than   those   available   in   the   domestic  

market.     Stulz   (2005)   discovered   that   the   largest   reductions   in   capital   cost   are  

enjoyed   by   developing   countries   that   are   gaining   access   to   international   capital  

markets   for   the   first   time.     He   determined   that   developed   countries   with   a  

 

longstanding   presence   in   the   international   financial  market   can   also   reduce   their  

capital  costs,  but  to  a  lesser  extent.    

International  capital  account  liberalization  has  not  only  benefitted  recipients  

of  capital,  but  also  distributors  of  capital.    The  interconnected  financial  system  has  

created   new   opportunities   for   investors   to   diversify   their   portfolios   and   achieve  

higher   returns.     Levey   and   Sarnat   (1970)   found   that   investment   portfolios   can  

achieve   “material   improvements”   in   risk   reduction   by   diversifying   their   holdings,  

specifically  by  purchasing  equities  in  developing  countries  to  complement  holdings  

in  developed  countries.  

As   Bailliu   (2000)   noted,   another   benefit   of   international   capital   flow  

liberalization   is   the   transfer   of   technology,   infrastructure,   and   intellectual   capital  

that  often  comes  with  FDI.    Acknowledging  that  multinational  corporations  account  

for   a   large   portion   of   global   research   and   development   investment,   Borensztein,  

Gregorio  &  Lee  (1998)  found  that  FDI  is  important  for  the  international  transfer  of  

technology   and,   in   developing   countries,   leads   to   more   growth   than   domestic  

investment   as   long   as   the   host   country’s   infrastructure   is   advanced   enough   to  

absorb  the  technology  spillovers.  

Despite   their   benefits,   freely   moving   international   capital   flows   have   not  

always  created  positive  outcomes  for  emerging  market  economies.    One  of  the  most  

important  drawbacks  of  capital  flows  is  the  pattern  of  reversals  in  periods  of  crises.    

Capital  flight  occurs  when  a  large  volume  of  capital  flows  out  of  a  country.    Capital  

flight  is  almost  always  a  symptom,  rather  than  a  cause,  of  a  financial  crisis.    Capital  

flight  was  present   in   the  global   recession  of  2008.     Total  net  private   capital   flows  

had  reached  a  historic  high  of  US  $1.2  trillion  in  2007,  only  to  fall  to  US  $649  billion  

in  2008.    According  to  Suchanek  &  Vasishtha  (2009),  they  fell  even  further  in  2009,  

to  US  $435  billion.    This  affirms  the  findings  of  Kaminsky,  Reinhart,  &  Vegh  (2005).  

The  authors  calculated  that,  for  all  groups  of  countries,  capital  flows  are  pro-­‐cyclical,  

with  higher   inflows  during  periods  of  growth  and   lower   inflows  during  periods  of  

crisis.    

Capital   flow   reversals   during   a   recession   can  worsen   a   crisis,   especially   in  

emerging   market   economies.     Calvo   &   Reinhart   (1999)   discovered   that   during   a  

 

crisis,   developing   countries   often   experience   decreased   access   to   sources   of  

international   capital,  which  makes   recovery  more   difficult.     They   point   out   that   a  

country  hoping   to   enact   expansionary  policies   to   recover   from   recession  will   find  

this   increasingly   difficult   as   their   sources   of   international   capital   disappear.     Not  

only  does  capital  decrease  in  availability,  but  it  also  increases  in  cost.      

Bernanke   (2000)   discovered   that   reduced   access   and   increased   cost   of  

capital   discourages   investment,   contributing   to   reduced   aggregate   demand   and  

decreased  output  during  a  crisis.    During  recessions,  there  is  heightened  uncertainty  

in  the  domestic  economy  and,  from  the  perspective  of  a  foreign  loaner,  risk.    Banks  

become   reluctant   to   lend   as   liberally   as   they   did   during   the   pre-­‐crisis   period.    

Bernanke   (2000)   discovered   that   banks’   unwillingness   to   lend   during   crises   has  

gotten   more   severe   over   time.   Cyclical   decreases   in   bank   loans   contribute   to  

decreases  in  private  loan  flows  during  a  recession.    Countries  cannot  expect  private  

loan   flows   to   be   as   abundant   during   a   crisis   as   they   are   in   a   stabile   economic  

environment.    Decreased  loan  flows  indicate  that  firms  are  not  undertaking  as  many  

investment   projects   during   a   recession,   which   makes   it   difficult   to   recover   via  

economic  growth  and  expansion.  

Capital   flight   is   not   always   caused  by   a   financial   crisis  within   the  domestic  

economy.     Capital   flow   reversals   can   also   be   triggered   by   exogenous   factors.     If  

investment  opportunities  with  higher  returns  and  less  risk  are  available   in  foreign  

entities,   investors   have   an   incentive   to   remove   their   money   from   the   domestic  

economy   and   reallocate   it   to   the   more   attractive   investment.     When   this   occurs,  

investors   demand   repayment   and   the   domestic   country  will   face   high   volumes   of  

capital  outflows,  which   it  can  respond  to   in  two  ways.    First,   the  country  can  raise  

the  domestic  interest  rate,  which  reduces  or  eliminates  the  opportunity  cost  that  the  

investor  incurs  by  keeping  his  or  her  money  in  the  domestic  country.    This  will  be  

effective   in   reducing   capital   outflows,   but   it   also   discourages   investment   because  

interest   rate   hikes   increase   the   cost   of   borrowing.     Decreased   investment  

contributes  to  a  growth  stall,  exasperating  the  effects  of  a  recession.    If  the  country  

does  not  wish  to  raise  the  domestic   interest  rate,   it  can  opt  to  repay  the  investors.    

 

Since  many  foreign  investments  are  denominated  in  foreign  currency,  the  domestic  

country  has  to  deplete  their  foreign  reserves  to  meet  their  repayment  obligations.      

In  extreme  cases,  depleted  foreign  reserves  can  lead  a  country  to  insolvency.    

According  to  World  Bank  data,  in  2008,  when  the  global  financial  crisis  was  starting  

to  reach  its  apex,  Brazil  had  foreign  exchange  reserves  of  $205.5  billion,  which  was  

12.9%  of  their  GDP.    According  to  The  Economist3,  these  foreign  reserves  gave  Brazil  

the  ability  to  intervene  in  foreign  exchange  markets  and  stabilize  the  Brazilian  real.    

They  also  were  able   to  provide   foreign  exchange  swaps   for  Brazilian  corporations  

that   were   struggling   to   pay   back   US   dollar-­‐denominated   debt.     If   Brazil   hadn’t  

possessed  substantial  pre-­‐crisis  amounts  of  foreign  reserves,  they  would  have  been  

less   able   to   pay   back   their   short-­‐term   debts,  which   could   have   led   them   towards  

insolvency.    

   Capital   flow   reversals   can   also   be   caused   by   the   exogenous   factor   of  

quantitative  easing  (QE).    QE  is  the  process  of  a  central  bank  buying  securities  from  

the  market   to   lower  global   interest  rates  and   increase   the  money  supply,  with   the  

goals  of  promoting  more  lending  and  increasing  liquidity.    QE  is  most  effective  when  

it   is   conducted   by   an   economy   of   large   scale,   such   as   that   of   the   US.     During  

quantitative   easing,   countries   ideally   use   the   money   they   receive   from   selling  

domestic   securities   in  ways   that   stimulate  growth   in   the  domestic  economy.    This  

theoretically   increases   investor   confidence   in   the  domestic   economy,   promoting   a  

resurgence  of  international  trade  and  investment.      

In   response   to   the   2008   financial   crisis,   the   Federal   Reserve   instituted  

aggressive  QE   policies,   eventually   purchasing   trillions   of   dollars   of   securities.     QE  

creates  a  risk  of  capital  flow  reversals  when  the  policies  are  eventually  phased  out,  

or   tapered.     In   May   2013,   Ben   Bernanke,   the   former   Chairman   of   the   Federal  

Reserve,  provided  a  glimpse  of   the  chaos   that  can  ensue  when  quantitative  easing  

policies  are  tapered.    According  an  article  published  by  Forbes4,  Bernanke  sparked  

                                                                                                               3  The  article  Just  in  Case  was  authored  by  multiple  writers  for  The  Economist  and  was  electronically  published  on  October  12,  2013.  4  The  article  Bernanke’s  QE  Dance:  Fed  Could  Taper  in  Next  Two  Meetings,  Tightening  Would  Collapse  the  Market  was  electronically  published  on  May  22,  2013.    The  article  was  authored  by  Agustino  Fontevecchia.  

 

wild   swings   in   the  market  when  he  hinted  at   the  possibility  of   tapering  QE   in   the  

near  future.    The  Dow  Jones  Industrial  Average,  a  stock  market  index  composed  of  

30   large   publically   owned  American   companies,   increased   and   decreased   by   over  

100   points   at   various   points   throughout   Bernanke’s   speech.     It   is   inevitable   that  

quantitative  easing  will  eventually  be  phased  out  and,  to  some  extent,  investors  will  

probably   respond   by   withdrawing   their   capital   from   developing   countries.     The  

degree  to  which  investors  respond  to  QE  tapering  by  withdrawing  their  capital  from  

developing   countries   will   determine   how   severely   economic   growth   in   emerging  

markets  will  be  hindered.      

1.4   Capital  Controls:  History  &  Types  

 Most,   if   not   all,   of   countries   institute   at   least   some   capital   controls,   which   are  

domestic   policies   that   regulate   flows   to   and   from   capital   markets.   Throughout  

history,   capital   controls   have   been   used   for   varying   purposes   and   to   different  

extents.     Eichengreen   (2008)   explains   that   capital   controls   initially   gained  

popularity   in  mainstream  economics  during  the  time  period  between  World  War  I  

and  World  War  II.    The  purpose  of  capital  controls  at  this  point  in  time  was  to  allow  

countries  to  rebuild  their  economy  during  the  post-­‐World  War  I  period  without  the  

fear   of   capital   flight.     Eichengreen   (2008)  mentions   that  during   the   three  decades  

after  World  War  II,  capital  controls  became  less  prevalent  and  international  capital  

flows   reached   record   highs.     Industrial   nations   led   the   way   in   liberalizing  

international  capital  flow  policies,  while  encouraging  developing  countries  to  do  the  

same.      

Post-­‐World   War   II   financial   crises   started   to   highlight   the   risks   of   freely  

moving   capital,   especially   in   developing   countries.     Economists   and   governments  

have   tried   to   better   their   understanding   of   capital   flow   behavior   and   how   capital  

controls   can   be   instituted   to   mitigate   the   risks   of   capital   volatility   during   crises.    

(Chamon   &   Garcia,   2014)   examine   the   ways   that   Brazil   used   capital   controls   to  

respond   to   the   2008   crisis.     Brazil   was   the   one   of   the  most   aggressive   emerging  

 

markets  in  terms  of  their  reactionary  capital  control  policies.    Beginning  in  2009,  the  

Brazilian   government   imposed   controls   such   as   portfolio   flow   taxes,   loan   flows  

taxes,   currency   exchange   taxes,   and   increased   reserve   requirements   for   domestic  

banks.    The  authors  discovered  that  capital  controls  increased  the  price  of  Brazilian  

assets   and,   to   a   certain   extent,   isolated   the   Brazilian   financial   market   from   the  

international  financial  market.    The  authors  also  concluded  that  the  capital  controls  

as   a   whole   successfully   contained   the   appreciation   of   the   real   (the   domestic  

Brazilian  currency).    The  Brazilian  government  began  relaxing  their  capital  controls  

in  2011.    The  authors   infer   that   the  controls  allowed  Brazil   to  avoid  a  bubble  and  

out-­‐of-­‐control  domestic  credit  levels.    The  downside  of  the  capital  controls  was  the  

reduced  access  to  foreign  financing,  possibly  contributing  to  the  low  investment  and  

growth  performance  during   the  post-­‐crisis  period.    Brazil   is   but  one   example  of   a  

country   that   has   had   success   with   capital   control   policies   during   a   crisis.     These  

success   stories   have   caused   many   economists   believe   that   capital   controls   are   a  

legitimate  way  to  shield  countries  from  some  of  the  effects  of  recessions.  

  There   are   a   wide   variety   of   capital   controls   that   can   be   instituted   by   a  

country.    Capital  controls  can  target  short-­‐term  investments,  long-­‐term  investments,  

or  both.    Wary  of  the  risks  that  come  with  the  volatility  of  short-­‐term  capital  flows,  

some   countries   impose   capital   controls   with   the   goal   of   attracting   investment  

projects   that   necessitate   long-­‐term   commitment   from   investors.     In   Vietnam,   the  

government   requires  as  a  precondition   that   foreign   investors  set  up  a  Vietnamese  

capital  bank  account,  which  enables  the  tracking  of  flows  in  and  out  of  the  country.    

Also,  the  Vietnamese  government  requires  that  foreign  investors  fulfill  all   financial  

obligations   to   the  State  of  Vietnam  before  distributing  any  profits   (KPMG).    Ostry,  

Ghosh,  Habermeier,  Chamon,  Qureshi  &  Reinhardt  (2010)  provide  another  example  

of  capital  controls  that  target  short-­‐term  flows.    From  2006-­‐2008,  Thailand  imposed  

an   unremunerated   reserve   requirement   on   any   foreign   currencies   sold   or  

exchanged  against  the  domestic  baht.    The  requirement  was  30%  and  was  effective  

in   reducing   the  volume  of  net   flows  as  well  as  altering   the  composition  of   inflows  

(there  was   a   greater   percentage   of   foreign   direct   investment   inflows   and   a   lower  

percentage  of  short-­‐term  flows).  

 

Some  capital  controls  that  target  long-­‐term  capital  flows  are  due  to  domestic  

aversion  to  foreign  ownership  of  domestic  assets.    In  Mexico,  for  example,  Article  27  

of   the   constitution   limits   foreign   investment   in   domestic   real   estate   and   natural  

resources.    Neely  (1999)  explains  that  this  is  a  protective  measure  Mexico  has  taken  

to   prevent   foreign   companies   from   exploiting   Mexican   resources   for   short-­‐term  

profits,  which  is  has  frequently  occurred  in  the  history  of  Mexico.    Another  reason  a  

country  might   impose   capital   controls   specific   to   long-­‐term   flows   is   because   of   a  

general  aversion  to  the  risks  of  taking  part  in  international  financial  markets.    South  

Korea,   for   example,   restricted   long-­‐term   foreign   investment   inflows   before   they  

radically  reformed  their  capital  account  starting   in   the   late  1990s.    Noland  (2007)  

attributes  South  Korea’s  restrictions  on  FDI   inflows  to   the  country’s  unwillingness  

to   have   the   foundation   of   their   economy   be   contingent   on   foreign   capital   and  

uncontrollable  macroeconomic   factors.     South   Korea   is   exemplary   of   an   economy  

that  rapidly  developed  without  relying  on  FDI   inflows.    The  country   instead  relied  

on  technology  licensing  and  international  loans  to  spur  growth.  

  Capital   controls   can   also   be   categorized   by   whether   or   not   they   restrict  

capital   account   transactions   via   price   mechanisms   or   quantity   controls.     Price  

controls   usually   manifest   themselves   in   the   form   of   taxes.     A   popular   price  

mechanism   is   the   “Tobin”   tax,   which   was   first   introduced   in   1972.     Tobin   taxes  

impose  a  small  percentage  tax  on  all  foreign  exchange  transactions.    Frankel  (1996)  

explains   that   the   purpose   of   the   Tobin   tax  was   to   reduce   the   incentive   to   switch  

investment  positions  in  the  short-­‐term  in  the  foreign  exchange  market,  which  would  

mitigate   market   volatility.     Another   price-­‐based   capital   control   is   the   mandatory  

reserve   requirement,   which   requires   foreign   investors   to   deposit   a   percentage   of  

their   investment  with   the   central   bank   (earning   no   interest).    Mandatory   reserve  

requirements   are   meant   to   build   the   foreign   reserves   of   the   central   bank.     Chile  

implemented   such   a   policy   from   1991   to   1998,   specifically   targeting   short-­‐term  

inflows.     In   the   context   of   Chile,   their  mandatory   reserve   requirement   essentially  

functioned  as  a  tax  on  short-­‐term  inflows.    Stiglitz  (2000)  praised  Chile’s  mandatory  

reserve  requirement  because  it  reduced  the  volatility  of  short-­‐term  inflows  without  

compromising  long-­‐term,  growth-­‐fostering  inflows  such  as  FDI.  

 

  Quantity-­‐based  capital  controls  can  take  the  form  of  policies  that  set  a  ceiling  

for  borrowing   from   foreign   residents.    According   to  Athukoralge   (2001),  Malaysia  

set   such   ceilings   in   response   to   the   1998   Asian   crisis,   limiting   foreign   currency  

borrowings   by   residents   and   domestic   borrowing   by   non-­‐residents.     Malaysia  

implemented  another  quantity-­‐based  control  by  setting  a  ceiling  on  banks/  external  

liabilities   not   related   to   trade   or   investment.     Other   times,   countries  may   require  

that   governmental   approval   be   granted   before   transactions   are   made   on   certain  

types  of   assets.     The   case  of   South  Korea  prohibiting  nearly   all   long-­‐term   flows   is  

one  example  of  this  type  of  quantity-­‐based  control.    

 

2.  Data  

2.1   Quantifying  Capital  Account  Restrictiveness  Due   to   the   variety   and   complexity   of   capital   controls,   quantifying   capital   account  

openness   is   a   burdensome   task.     Different   countries   at   different   points   in   time  

decide  to   impose  different  mixes  of  capital  controls.    Given  the  variety  of  available  

capital   controls,   each  mix   tends   to   be  unique.     It   is   therefore   important   to   have   a  

standard  measure  of  capital  control  restrictiveness.      

Many   capital   account   openness   indices   have   been   constructed   using   the  

IMF’s   Annual   Report   on   Exchange   Arrangements   and   Exchange   Restrictions  

(AREAER).      The  AREAER  is  a  database  of  binary  variables  that  contains  information  

about  the  types  of  capital  controls  are  employed  by  the  187  IMF  member  countries.      

The  variables  in  the  AREAER   include  a  wide  variety  of  capital  controls,  such  

as  restrictions  on  international  payments  and  transfers,  arrangements  for  payments  

and   receipts,   regulations   on   residents’   and   nonresidents’   accounts,   exchange   rate  

systems,  financial  sector  policies,  and  foreign  exchange  market  operations.    A  binary  

variable  with   the   value   of   1   indicates   that   a   country   has   instituted   the   particular  

capital  control  and  0  otherwise.    

The  AREAR  is  effective  in  distinguishing  between  de  jure  and  de  facto  capital  

controls.    De   jure   capital   controls   are   legally   instituted   policies.     De   facto   capital  

controls   relate   to   how   robustly   the   controls   are   implemented,   and   how   effective  

they  are   in   serving   their  purpose.    De  facto  capital   controls  are  harder   to  quantify  

than  de  jure  capital  controls,  but   they  depict  reality  more  accurately,  which  makes  

them  more  valuable  for  practical  perspective.  

There  are  various  issues  that  arise  when  measuring  capital  account  openness  

with  the  binary  variables  contained  in  the  AREAER.    Binary  measurements  indicate  

whether   or   not   a   country   has   instituted   a   given   capital   control,   but   provide   no  

information  on  the  degree  to  which  it  has  been  implemented.    Therefore,  there  is  no  

way  to  measure  differences  in  intensity  of  a  given  capital  control  between  countries.    

Another   issue  with   the   variables   in   the  AREAER   is   that   they   are   broadly   defined,  

preventing   them   from   capturing   certain   details   and   distinguishing   features   of  

 

capital   controls.     Some   of   the   problems   associated   with   a   lack   of   capital   control  

specificity  were  addressed   in  1997,  when   the   IMF   revised   the   classification  of   the  

variables   in   the   AREAER.     The   new   variable   categorizations   now   account   for  

distinctions  between  restrictions  on  inflows  and  outflows  as  well  as  the  differences  

between   different   types   of   capital   transactions.     However,   it   is   doubtful   that   any  

categorization   of   the   variables   in   the   AREAR,   no   matter   how   specific,   could   ever  

perfectly  encapsulate  the  complexity  and  variety  of  capital  controls.  

Using   the   information   from   the   AREAER,   Chinn   and   Ito   (2008)   created   a  

capital  account  openness  index  called  KAOPEN.    The  authors  reversed  the  values  of  

the  binary  variables  in  the  AREAER  in  order  to  construct  KAOPEN  in  a  way  that  has  

higher   index   values   corresponding   to   less   restrictive   current   account   policies.    

Selected   binary   variables   in   the   AREAER   are   weighted   and   aggregated   into  

individual   index   values   for   each   IMF   member   country.     The   aggregated   index  

measurements   assume   values   between   0   to   1,   with   0   representing   complete  

restriction   and   1   representing   complete   openness.    KAOPEN  values   are  measured  

annually,  with  1970  being  the  earliest  year  that  data  is  available  for.    

KAOPEN  is  the  most  appropriate  capital  account  openness  index  to  use  in  this  

study   for   two   reasons.   KAOPEN   is   constructed   so   as   to   focus   on   de   jure   capital  

controls,  making   it   effective   in  measuring   the   extent   of   regulatory   restrictions   on  

capital   account   transactions.     Since   the   purpose   of   this   study   is   to   evaluate   the  

effectiveness   of   a   country’s   legally   imposed   capital   controls   in   mitigating   the  

negative   effects   of   a   financial   crisis,   KAOPEN’s   focus   on   de   jure   capital   controls  

makes  it  a  logical  choice  of  index.      

The   second   reason   KAOPEN   is   an   ideal   index   of   capital   account  

restrictiveness   is   that   it   is   a   holistic,   robust  measure   of   capital   account   openness.  

Countries  oftentimes   impose  capital  controls   in  a  variety  of  ways   to   increase   their  

collective  effectiveness.    As  Edwards  (1999)  points  out,  the  private  sector  frequently  

circumvents  capital  controls.    Countries  can  make  this  more  difficult  by  adopting  an  

all-­‐inclusive   approach   to   their   capital   control   policies.     A   country   with   a   closed  

capital   account   can   reinforce   these   policies   by   imposing   controls   on   the   current  

account   or   by   changing   the   requirements   for   surrendering   export   proceeds.    

 

Malaysia   adopted   this   strategy   in   response   to   the   Asian   Crisis   of   1998.    KAOPEN  

incorporates  variables   from  a  variety  of   categories   in   the  AREAR,   accounting   for  a  

wide   range  of   capital   controls.     Therefore,  KAOPEN  values   are   strong  measures  of  

the  entirety  of  countries’  approaches  to  capital  account  restrictiveness.    

Here,  I  first  examine  KAOPEN  values  from  1970  to  2012  across  the  entirety  of  

the   IMF  member  countries   to   investigate   if   there   is  a  global   trend   towards  capital  

openness   or   restrictiveness.     I   then   focus   on   the   regions   of   Latin   America   and  

Southeast  Asia,   to   investigate   if   there  are   region-­‐specific   capital   account  openness  

trends.     I  evaluate  KAOPEN  for   these  regions  across   the  entirety  of   the   time  series  

(1970   to   2012)   as  well   as   specifically   for   time   periods   leading   up   to,   during,   and  

after  a  crisis.    For  Latin  America,  my  analysis  focuses  on  the  five  years  preceding  and  

following   the   2002   South   American   recession.     For   Southeast   Asia,   my   analysis  

focuses  on  the  five  years  preceding  and  following  the  1998  Asian  financial  crisis.  

 

2.2   KAOPEN  Values  Figure   6   presents   the   average   of   annual   KAOPEN   values   for   the   187   IMF  

member   countries   as   a   group   from  1970   to   2012.     The   change   in   global  KAOPEN  

values  over  time   indicates   that,   in  general,  capital  account  openness  has   increased  

since  1970.    However,  Figure  6  shows  that  the  trend  toward  global  capital  account  

openness  slowed  and  even  reversed  in  the  late  1970’s  and  early  1980’s.    The  mean  

global   KAOPEN   value   did   not   begin   to   increase   again   until   the   late   1980’s.     The  

reduction  in  KAOPEN  values  during  the  late  1970’s  and  early  1980’s  is  attributable  

to   the  global   recession   that  occurred  during   the   same   time  period.    The   recession  

negatively   impacted   both   developed   economies   and   emerging  market   economies.    

The   trend   is   particularly   evident   in   the   Latin   American   debt   crisis   during   that  

period.    In  the  1960’s  and  1970’s,  Latin  American  countries  built  up  vast  quantities  

of   foreign   debt   by   borrowing   from   international   creditors   to   fund   economic  

development   projects.     Investors   were   initially   eager   to   finance   projects   in  

developing  Latin  America  because  GDP   in   the  region  was  rapidly  growing.    By   the  

late  1970’s,  however,  Latin  American  countries  were  struggling  to  repay  their  debts,  

 

partly  due  to  rising  oil  prices  and  increasing  interest  rates  in  the  United  States  and  

Europe.    Investors  became  wary  of  Latin  America’s  ability  to  repay  their  debts.    They  

withdrew   their   funds   from   the   region,   causing   a   large   outflow   of   capital   flight.    

According   to   Pastor   (1989),   capital   flight   in   Latin   America   totaled   $151   billion  

between  1973  and  1987.    This   equates   to  43%  of   their   total   external  debt  during  

that   time   period.     The   rapid   outflow   of   capital   from   Latin   America   deprived   the  

region  of   important   funding   that  was   expected   to  be  used   for  developing  projects  

and  servicing  their  foreign  debt.    Latin  American  countries  came  to  identify  capital  

flight  as  one  of  the  primary  causes  for  their  economic  woes.    As  a  result,  countries  in  

the   region   became  more   restrictive   on   capital   account   transactions   and   even   the  

IMF  made   stricter   capital   controls   a   precondition   for   Latin  American   countries   to  

receive  debt-­‐relief  assistance  packages.      

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  Figure  7  depicts  the  KAOPEN  value  for  Latin  American  countries   from  1970  

to  1990.    The   figure   shows  a   strong   trend   towards   capital   account   restrictiveness  

during   the   late   1970’s   and   early   1980’s   in   Latin   America.     The   figure   shows   that  

0.3  

0.35  

0.4  

0.45  

0.5  

0.55  

0.6  

1970  

1972  

1974  

1976  

1978  

1980  

1982  

1984  

1986  

1988  

1990  

1992  

1994  

1996  

1998  

2000  

2002  

2004  

2006  

2008  

2010  

2012  

KAO

PEN  

Year  

Figure  6:  Mean  KAOPEN  Value  for  all  IMF  Member  Countries,  1970-­‐2012  The  figure  presents  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  for  all  IMF  member  countries  from  1970-­‐2012.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  for  KAOPEN  values.  

 

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

0.6  

1970  

1971  

1972  

1973  

1974  

1975  

1976  

1977  

1978  

1979  

1980  

1981  

1982  

1983  

1984  

1985  

1986  

1987  

1988  

1989  

1990  

KAO

PEN  

Year  

Latin  American  countries  did  not  begin   liberalizing   their  capital  accounts  until   the  

late  1980’s.        

In   contrast,   this   trend   is   absent   for   developing   countries   during   the   same  

period.    Figure  8  shows  the  KAOPEN  value  for  a  selected  group  of  countries  that  had  

some  of  the  largest  economies  (in  terms  of  nominal  GDP)  in  the  world  in  1980.    The  

figure   makes   it   evident   that   the   overall   trend   towards   capital   account  

restrictiveness  was  not  present  in  developed  countries  with  prominent  economies.    

Thus,  the  overall  trend  towards  stricter  capital  controls  in  the  late  1970’s  and  early  

1980’s,   apparent   in   Figure   6,   did   not   apply   globally,   but   had   important   regional  

distinctions.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  5  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

                                                                                                               5  Figure  7  depicts  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  from  1970  to  1990  for  selected  Latin  American  countries:  Argentina,  Bolivia,  Chile,  Colombia,  Ecuador,  Guatemala,  Mexico,  Paraguay,  Peru,  Uruguay  &  Venezuela.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  KAOPEN  values.    

 Figure  7:  Mean  KAOPEN  Value  for  Latin  American  Countries,  1970-­‐19905  The  figure  presents  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  for  selected  Latin  American  countries  for  1970-­‐1990.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 6  

 

 

 

 

 

 

Excluding  the  reversal  in  the  late  1970’s  and  early  1980’s,  there  is  clearly  an  

overall  trend  towards  global  capital  account  openness.    This  has  made  international  

capital   reallocation   and   international   trade   easier,   prominent   features   of   the  

present-­‐day  integrated  global  economy.  

  Figures   9   graphs   the   KAOPEN  values   in   Latin   America   and   Southeast   Asia  

from  1970  to  2012,  illustrated  the  regional  differences  in  capital  account  openness.    

In  general,  Latin  American  countries  have  liberalized  their  capital  accounts  more  so  

than   Southeast   Asian   countries.     The   next   section   of   this   paper   relates   KAOPEN  

values  to  FDI   inflow  volume  on  a  regional  basis,  which  should  indicate  whether  or  

not  the  dichotomy  of  the  approaches  taken  by  Southeast  Asian  countries  and  Latin  

                                                                                                               6  Figure  8  depicts  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  from  1970  to  1990  for  a  selected  group  of  developed  countries  that  were  global  leaders  in  terms  of  GDP  in  1980:  Canada,  France,  Germany,  Italy,  Japan,  Spain,  the  United  Kingdom  &  the  United  States.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  KAOPEN  values.  

0.4  

0.45  

0.5  

0.55  

0.6  

0.65  

0.7  

0.75  

0.8  

0.85  

1970  

1971  

1972  

1973  

1974  

1975  

1976  

1977  

1978  

1979  

1980  

1981  

1982  

1983  

1984  

1985  

1986  

1987  

1988  

1989  

1990  

KAO

PEN  

Year  

Figure  8:  Mean  KAOPEN  Values  for  Developed  Countries,  1970-­‐19906  The  figure  shows  the  mean  KAOPEN  values  for  a  selected  group  of  developed  countries  from  1970-­‐1990.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.    

 

American   countries   towards   capital   account   restrictiveness   has   yielded   different  

outcomes  for  the  countries  in  those  regions.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 7  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2.3   KAOPEN  &  FDI  Inflows;  Time-­‐Series  Data  Selection  I  examine  the  relationship  between  KAOPEN  values  and  net  FDI   inflow  volume  for  

my   focus   countries   over   an   eleven-­‐year   period   centered   around   the   year   of   the  

financial  crisis:  1998  for  Southeast  Asia  and  2002  for  Latin  America.    Figures  10  and  

11  show  the  %  GDP  change  for  my  countries  of  focus  in  each  region  over  an  11-­‐year  

period.     In  Latin  America,   the  crisis  was  deepest   in  2002  as  evidenced  by   the  GDP  

                                                                                                               7  Figure  9  depicts  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  from  1970  to  1990  for  a  selected  group  of  Latin  American  and  Southeast  Asian  countries.    The  Latin  American  countries  included  are  Argentina,  Bolivia,  Chile,  Colombia,  Ecuador,  Guatemala,  Mexico,  Paraguay,  Peru,  Uruguay  &  Venezuela.    The  Southeast  Asian  countries  included  are  Cambodia,  Indonesia,  South  Korea,  Lao  PDR,  Malaysia,  Myanmar,  Philippines,  Singapore,  Thailand  &  Vietnam.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  KAOPEN  values.  

Figure  9:  Mean  KAOPEN  Values  for  Latin  American  and  Southeast  Asian  Countries,  1970-­‐20127  This  figure  shows  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  for  Latin  American  and  Southeast  Asian  Countries  between  1970  and  2012.  

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

0.6  

0.7  

0.8  

1970  

1972  

1974  

1976  

1978  

1980  

1982  

1984  

1986  

1988  

1990  

1992  

1994  

1996  

1998  

2000  

2002  

2004  

2006  

2008  

2010  

2012  

KAO

PEN  

Year  LA  KAOPEN  values   SE  Asia  KAOPEN  Values  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

contraction  seen  in  figure  10.     In  Southeast  Asia,   the  crisis  was  deepest   in  1998  as  

evidenced  by  the  GDP  contraction  seen  in  Figure  11.    Thus,  I  recognize  2002  as  the  

start   of   the   financial   crisis   in   Latin  America   and  1998  as   the   start   of   the   financial  

crisis  in  Southeast  Asia.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 8  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 9  

                                                                                                               8  Figure  10  shows  the  mean  annual  %  GDP  change  from  1997  to  2007  for  my  focus  countries  in  Latin  America:  Argentina,  Chile  &  Venezuela.  There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  GDP  change  values.  

Figure  11:  Mean  Annual  %  GDP  Change  for  Southeast  Asian  Countries,  1993-­‐20039  This  figure  shows  the  annual  %  GDP  Change  for  my  focus  Southeast  Asian  Countries  from  1993-­‐2003.      

-­‐8  -­‐6  -­‐4  -­‐2  0  2  4  6  8  10  12  

1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007  %  GDP  Change  

Year  %  GDP  

Figure  10:  Mean  Annual  %  GDP  Change  for  Latin  American  Countries,  1997-­‐20078  This  figure  shows  the  annual  %  GDP  Change  for  my  focus  Southeast  Asian  Countries  from  1991-­‐2001.      

-­‐6  

-­‐4  

-­‐2  

0  

2  

4  

6  

8  

10  

1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003  %  GDP  Change  

Year  %  GDP  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

The   KAOPEN   values   for   the   five   years   preceding   the   crisis   indicate   the  

intensity  of  a  given  country’s  capital  controls  before  the  beginning  of  the  recession.    

The  KAOPEN  values  in  the  years  after  the  start  of  the  crisis  reveal  if  a  given  country  

responds  by  opening  or  closing   their  capital  account  and   to  what  extent.    The  FDI  

inflow   levels   during   the   five   years   after   the   start   of   the   crisis   are   of   particular  

interest,   because   they   show   how   effective   a   given   country’s   reactionary   capital  

control  alterations  relate  to  actual  capital   flow  volume.     I   find  that  FDI   inflows  are  

sensitive  to  capital  controls  imposed  in  response  to  a  crisis.  

Figures  12  and  13  show  how  the  mean  KAOPEN  value  in  Latin  America  and  

Southeast   Asia   changed   during   the   11-­‐year   periods   centered   around   the   year   in  

which   their   respective   crises   began.     Figure   12   indicates   that   in   general,   Latin  

American   countries   responded   to   the   2002   crisis   by   loosening   capital   controls.    

Figure  13  shows  that  countries  in  Southeast  Asia  also  opened  their  capital  accounts,  

but   less   drastically   than   Latin   American   countries.     In   2001,   one   year   before   the  

start   of   2002   crisis,   the   average   KAOPEN   value   in   Latin   America   was   .655.     The  

average  KAOPEN  value   in  Southeast  Asia   in  1997,  one  year  before   the   start  of   the  

1998  crisis,  was   .371.    Before  the  start  of   the  crisis,  Southeast  Asian  countries  had  

much  less  open  capital  accounts  than  countries  in  Latin  America.    This  is  consistent  

with   the   broader   trend   of   Southeast  Asian   countries   being  more   averse   to   capital  

account  liberalization  than  Latin  American  countries,  which  is  shown  in  Figure  9.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                         9  Figure  11  shows  the  mean  annual  %  GDP  change  from  1992  to  2002  for  my  focus  countries  in  Southeast  Asia:  Vietnam,  Singapore,  Indonesia  &  Malaysia.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  GDP  change  values.  

 

 

 

 

   

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

         10  11  

 

 

2.4   KAOPEN  &  FDI  Inflows;  Latin  America  The  Latin  American  crisis  of  2002  was  sparked  by  the  devaluation  of  the  Brazilian  

real.    After  the  devaluation  of  the  real,  Argentine  export  competitive  was  damaged  

because   the   Argentine   peso  was   pegged   to   the   US   dollar,   preventing   the   country  

from  devaluing  in  order  to  restore  their  export  competitiveness.    What  started  out  

as   a   currency   crisis   in   Argentina   turned   into   a   sovereign   debt   crisis   when   the  

country’s   economy   started   contracting   because   decreased   tax   receipts   could   no  

longer  finance  the  country’s  outstanding  interest  payments.    Despite  assistance  from  

the  IMF,  the  market’s  confidence  in  Argentina  and  the  peso  continued  to  deteriorate.    

                                                                                                               10  Figure  12  shows  the  mean  annual  KAOPEN  value  from  1997  to  2007  for  selected  countries  in  Latin  America:  Argentina,  Bolivia,  Chile,  Colombia,  Ecuador,  Guatemala,  Mexico,  Paraguay,  Peru,  Uruguay  &  Venezuela.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  KAOPEN  values.  11  Figure  13  shows  the  mean  annual  KAOPEN  value  from  1993  to  2003  for  selected  countries  in  Southeast  Asia:  Cambodia,  Indonesia,  South  Korea,  Lao  PDR,  Malaysia,  Myanmar,  Philippines,  Singapore,  Thailand  &  Vietnam.    There  are  no  country-­‐specific  weightings  applied  to  KAOPEN  values.    

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

0.6  

0.7  

0.8  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

KAO

PEN  

Year  

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

0.6  

0.7  

0.8  

1993  

1994  

1995  

1996  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

KAO

PEN  

Year  

Figure  12:  Mean  Annual  KAOPEN  value  for  Latin  American  Countries,  1997-­‐200710  This  figure  shows  the  average  annual  KAOPEN  value  in  Latin  America  from  1997-­‐2007.  

Figure  13:  Mean  Annual  KAOPEN  value  for  Southeast  Asian  Countries,  1993-­‐200311  This  figure  shows  the  average  annual  KAOPEN  value  in  Latin  America  from  1993-­‐2003.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.   Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

Argentina  gradually  phased  out  the  peso’s  peg  to  the  dollar,  but  action  did  not  come  

swiftly  enough.    The  crisis  reached  an  apex  near  the  end  of  2001,  when  confidence  in  

the   peso   was   so   compromised   that   Argentina   experienced   a   bank   run.     Arellano  

(2008)   notes   that  Argentina   eventually   decided   to   default   on   over   $100  billion   of  

their   debt   in   December   of   2001.     This   should   have   worsened   the   situation   in  

Argentina   because   a   default   would   theoretically   block   Argentina’s   access   to  

international  capital  markets.    Towards  the  end  of  2002,  however,  World  Bank  data  

shows   that   the   global   price   of   soy,  which   is   one  of   the  most  prominent  Argentine  

exports,  soared  to  their  highest  level  since  mid-­‐2000.    Argentina  enjoyed  an  export-­‐

driven  recovery;  GDP  contracted  by  10.89%  in  2002  then  grew  by  8.84%  in  2003.      

Argentina’s   economy  began   to   slow  down   in  1998  when   the  Brazilian  Real  

was  devalued.    The  recession  was  by  no  means  mild;  World  Bank  data  indicates  that,  

from   1998   to   2002,   the   Argentine   economy   shrank   by   over   25%.     Figure   14  

indicates   that   Argentina   responded   to   the   crisis   by   increasing   capital   account  

restrictiveness.     Net   FDI   inflow   volume   in   Argentina   follows   a   trend   similar   to  

KAOPEN  values  in  Argentina.    Similar  year-­‐to-­‐year  relative  changes  in  KAOPEN  and  

FDI   inflows   indicate   that   the   extent   of   Argentina’s   capital   controls   have   a  

relationship   with   capital   flow   volume.     Although   Argentina’s   economy   began   to  

recover  in  2003,  net  FDI  inflows  did  not  begin  to  increase  until  2004,  one  year  after  

Argentina  began  to  reopen  their  capital  account.    This  indicates  that  FDI  inflows  are  

more  responsive  to  capital  controls  than  macroeconomic  trends.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure  14:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Argentina,  1997-­‐2007  This  figure  shows  the  KAOPEN  values  and  FDI  net  inflow  volumes  for  Argentina  from  1997  to  2007.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.  

Figure  15:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Chile,  1997-­‐2007  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Chile  from  1997-­‐2007.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.    

0  

0.2  

0.4  

0.6  

0.8  

1  

1.2  

$0.00  

$2,000.00  

$4,000.00  

$6,000.00  

$8,000.00  

$10,000.00  

$12,000.00  

$14,000.00  

1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  MIllions  

Year  FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

0  0.1  0.2  0.3  0.4  0.5  0.6  0.7  0.8  0.9  1  

$0.00  

$5,000.00  

$10,000.00  

$15,000.00  

$20,000.00  

$25,000.00  

$30,000.00  

1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  Millions  

Year  FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

 

 

The  2002  crisis  did  not  affect  Chile  as  much  as  it  did  Argentina.    According  to  

the  World  Bank,  Chile  only  had  GDP  contraction  in  1999,  while  Argentina’s  economy  

shrank  for  four  consecutive  years.    Calvo  (2005)  attributes  Chile’s  relatively  strong  

performance  during  the  recession  to  the  fact  that  Chile  did  not  have  as  severe  of  a  

pre-­‐crisis   currency-­‐denomination   mismatch.     Figure   15   indicates   that   Chile  

responded   to   the   crisis   by   opening   their   capital   account,  which   is   the   opposite   of  

what  Argentina  did.    Chile  experienced  a  drop  in  FDI  inflows  from  1999  to  2002,  but  

had  a  strong  resurgence  afterwards.    Again  the  relationship  between  capital  account  

restrictiveness  and  net  FDI   inflows  appears   to  be  significant,  even   in   the  case  of  a  

country   that  was  not  affected  by   the   crisis   to   the   same  degree  as  Argentina.    This  

enforces   the   argument   that   net   FDI   inflows   are  more   sensitive   to   towards   short-­‐

term  variations  in  capital  controls  than  macroeconomic  trends.  

Venezuela   also   experienced   adverse   effects   from   the   crisis   of   2002;   their  

economy  shrank  by  9%   in  2002  and  by  8%   in  2003  according   to   the  World  Bank.    

Adding  to  the  economic  problems  the  country  was  facing,  political  instability  led  to  a  

strike  in  December  2002.    The  strike  caused  a  crisis  in  the  Venezuelan  oil  industry,  

greatly  reducing  the  country’s  crude  oil  output  for  much  of  2003.    Venezuela  started  

experiencing  capital  flight  as  confidence  in  their  economy  deteriorated.    In  order  to  

curb  the  capital  flight  and  prevent  further  depletion  of  foreign  reserves,  Venezuela  

increased  the  intensity  of  their  capital  controls  as  indicated  in  Figure  16.    FDI  inflow  

volume  rose  during  2000  and   then  steeply  declined,   coinciding  with   the   time   that  

Venezuela’s   KAOPEN   value   decreased.     Even   in   the   case   of   a   country   that  

experienced  a  crisis  due  to  internal  rather  than  exogenous  factors,  there  appears  to  

be  a  significant  relationship  between  capital  account  restrictiveness  and  capital  flow  

volume.     It   is  difficult  to  ascertain  causality;  some  of  the  FDI   inflow  reductions  are  

likely  due  to  a  general  lack  of  investor  confidence  in  the  region.    It  seems  probable,  

however,   that   the  heightened  capital  account  restrictions  also  played  a  part   in   the  

reduction  of  FDI  inflow  volume  during  and  after  the  crisis.      

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2.5   KAOPEN  &  FDI  Inflows;  Southeast  Asia  The  1998  Asian  financial  crisis  began  in  Thailand,  when  the  country  was  forced  to  

float  the  Thai  baht  after   large-­‐scale  currency  speculation  attacks  and  a  shortage  of  

foreign   reserves   led   to   the   failure  of   their   fixed   exchange   rate   system.    Thailand’s  

outstanding   debt   payments,   which   they   had   already   struggled   to   honor,   became  

even  more  difficult  to  pay  back  after  the  decision  to  float  the  baht  led  to  devaluation.    

Similar   to   how   Brazil’s   devaluation   impacted   Argentina’s   export   competitiveness,  

Thailand’s  devaluation  reduced  the  export  competitiveness  of  other  Southeast  Asian  

countries.    Trade  links  were  the  channel  for  financial  contagion  and  caused  the  Thai  

crisis  spread  to  most  other  countries  in  Southeast  Asia.  

Figure  16:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Venezuela,  1997-­‐2007  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Venezuela  from  1997-­‐2007.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.      

0  

0.2  

0.4  

0.6  

0.8  

1  

1.2  

$0.00  

$1,000.00  

$2,000.00  

$3,000.00  

$4,000.00  

$5,000.00  

$6,000.00  

$7,000.00  

1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  Millions  

Year  

FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

Vietnam   has   historically   taken   a   conservative   approach   towards   capital   flows   by  

implementing   a   wide   variety   of   capital   controls.   Vietnam   was   not   as   adversely  

affected  by  the  1998  Asian  financial  crisis  as  other  countries  in  the  region.    Table  1  

shows  the  average  annual  %  change  in  GDP  for  selected  Southeast  Asian  countries  

between   1998   and   2002,   as   well   as   the   standard   deviation   for   the   yearly  

fluctuations   in  %   GDP   change.     Vietnam   averaged   the   highest   annual   GDP   in   the  

region   over   the   five-­‐year   period.     Vietnam’s   propensity   to   shield   itself   from   the  

international   financial   system   reduced   the   country’s   interconnectedness   with   the  

rest  of  the  market,  which  is  likely  one  explanatory  factor  for  their  relatively  strong  

performance   during   the   crisis   of   1998.     Vietnam   also   had   the   smallest   standard  

deviation  of  their  annual  %  GDP  changes,   indicating  that  Vietnam  has  less  year-­‐to-­‐

year   variability   in   their   economic   performance.     This   is   also   likely   attributable   to  

severity  of  their  capital  control  policies.  

Vietnam’s   FDI   inflow   volume   between   1992   and   2002   follows   closely  with  

the  country’s  KAOPEN  values  over  the  same  time  period,  as  seen  in  Figure  17.    The  

figure   indicates   that   Vietnam’s   capital   controls   were   gradually   loosened   between  

1992  and  1996,  which   facilitated  higher  FDI   inflow  volume.    After  1996,  however,  

Vietnam  stopped  liberalizing  their  capital  account  and  even  tightened  restrictions  a  

bit  in  2001.    This  coincides  with  a  reduction  in  FDI  inflow  volume.    Although  there  

appears   to  be   some   relationship  between  KAOPEN  and  FDI   inflows,   it   is   likely   the  

small  variation  in  FDI  inflow  volume  during  the  crisis  period  is  due  to  a  general  lack  

of  confidence  in  the  outlook  of  the  regional  economy.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Country   Average  Annual  %  GDP  Change  

Standard   Deviation   of  Annual  %  GDP  Changes  

Vietnam   5.97%   0.76  Philippines   2.69%   1.92  Malaysia   2.71%   6.38  South  Korea   5.16%   6.49  Thailand   1.23%   6.67  

Table  1:  Average  Annual  %  GDP  Change  &  Standard  Deviation  in  Selected  Southeast  Asian  Countries,  1998-­‐2002  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  Malaysia  and  Indonesia  had  similar  pre-­‐crisis  KAOPEN  values,  as  indicated  in  

Figures   18   and   19.     Both   countries   reduced   their   capital   account   openness   in  

response   to   the   crisis,   with   Malaysia   implementing   capital   controls   a   bit   more  

severely   than   Indonesia.     Overall,   FDI   inflow   volume   decreased   in   both   countries  

over   the   ten-­‐year   period,   as   depicted   by   the   trend   lines   in   the   figures.     Although  

there  is  an  overall  downward  trend  in  FDI  inflow  volume,  there  are  drastic  year-­‐to-­‐

year  FDI  variations.    One  reason  for  this  could  be  that  Malaysia  and  Indonesia  had  

liberalized   capital   accounts   prior   to   the   recession   (both   countries   have   the  

maximum  KAOPEN  values  in  the  early  1990’s).    Year-­‐to-­‐year  variations  in  FDI  inflow  

volumes  to  Malaysia  and  Indonesia’s  are  much  greater  than  those  of  Vietnam.    Less  

variation   in   Vietnam   is   likely   due   to   the   country’s   capital   account   restrictiveness.    

Liberalized  pre-­‐crisis  capital  accounts   in  Malaysia  and   Indonesia  and   the  resulting  

Figure  17:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Vietnam,  1992-­‐2002  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Vietnam  from  1992-­‐2002.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.      

0  

0.05  

0.1  

0.15  

0.2  

0.25  

$0.00  

$500.00  

$1,000.00  

$1,500.00  

$2,000.00  

$2,500.00  

$3,000.00  

1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  Millions  

Year  

FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

interconnectedness  with   the   international   financial   system   could   have  made   their  

economies  more   susceptible   to  market   trends.     The   economies’   responsiveness   to  

market  dynamics  could  be  a  primary  cause  in  the  year-­‐to-­‐year  FDI  inflow  variations  

seen  in  Figures  18  and  19.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure  18:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Malaysia,  1992-­‐2002  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Malaysia  from  1993-­‐2003.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.    

Figure  19:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Indonesia,  1992-­‐2002  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Indonesia  from  1992-­‐2002.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.      

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

0.6  

0.7  

0.8  

$0.00  

$1,000.00  

$2,000.00  

$3,000.00  

$4,000.00  

$5,000.00  

$6,000.00  

1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  Millions  

FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

0  

0.2  

0.4  

0.6  

0.8  

1  

1.2  

-­‐$6,000.00  

-­‐$4,000.00  

-­‐$2,000.00  

$0.00  

$2,000.00  

$4,000.00  

$6,000.00  

$8,000.00  

1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  Net  InHlows,  $US  Millions  

Year  FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

 

 

  Singapore  is  a  unique  case  in  Southeast  Asia  due  to  its  interconnectivity  with  

the  global  economy  as  well  as  the  sophistication  of  their  domestic  economy.    Figure  

20   compares   annual   GDP   per   capita   from   1994   to   1997   in   my   Southeast   Asian  

countries   of   focus.   Singapore’s   GDP   per   capita   in   every   year   dwarfs   those   of   its  

regional   counterparts.     Strong  GDP  per  capita   in  Singapore   is  a  byproduct  of   their  

industrialized   economy   and   a   stable   political   environment   that   actively   promotes  

domestic  business.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Before  the  1998  Asian  financial  crisis,  Singapore  had  the  maximum  possible  

KAOPEN  value,  as  seen  in  Figure  21.    Singapore  was  not  immune  to  contagion  effects  

from  neighboring  countries;  according  to  the  World  Bank,  Singapore  experienced  a  

$0.00  

$5,000.00  

$10,000.00  

$15,000.00  

$20,000.00  

$25,000.00  

1994   1995   1996   1997  

GDP  per  Capita  (Constant  2005  $US)  

Year  Singapore   Vietnam   Indonesia   Malaysia  

Figure  20:  Annual  GDP  per  Capita  in  Southeast  Asian  Countries  of  Focus,  1994-­‐1997  (Constant  2005  $US)  This  figure  shows  how  annual  GDP  per  Capita  changed  between  1994-­‐1997  in  Singapore,  Vietnam,  Indonesia  &  Malaysia.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

GDP  contraction  of  over  2%  in  1998.    Singapore  responded  quickly  and  decisively,  

allowing   their   currency   to   depreciate   against   the   US   dollar,   which   reduced   the  

potential  gains  of  would-­‐be  currency  speculators.    

Singapore’s  strategy  of  slightly  increasing  capital  control  restrictiveness  can  

be  observed  in  Figure  21.    FDI  inflows  to  Singapore  increased  at  a  steady  rate  prior  

to   the  1998  crisis,  but  similar   to   the  other  countries   in   the  region,  decreased  after  

1996.    Figure  21  shows  that  Singapore’s  FDI  inflow  volume  recovered  very  quickly  

after  the  crisis,  reaching  an  all-­‐time  high  in  1999.    This  type  of  FDI  inflow  resurgence  

did  not  occur  in  Malaysia,  Indonesia,  or  Vietnam.    It   is   likely  that  Singapore’s  post-­‐

crisis  FDI  inflow  increases  are  partly  due  to  the  timeliness  and  effectiveness  of  the  

mild  capital  controls  they  imposed  after  1996.      

Another   probable   cause   of   Singapore’s   post-­‐crisis   FDI   inflow   resurgence   is  

the   sophistication   and   liberalization   of   their   pre-­‐crisis   economy.     Singapore   was  

already   an   industrialized,   trade-­‐centric   nation   that   had   proved   itself   as   a   viable  

investment  opportunity.    Past  performance  was   likely   the  primary  reason   that   the  

market’s  confidence   in  Singapore,  and  FDI   inflow  volume,  was  restored  so  quickly  

after  the  crisis.    The  case  of  Singapore  seems  to  indicate  that  a  country  with  an  open  

capital  account  and  a  strong  presence  in  international  financial  markets  can  respond  

to  crises  by  implementing  mild  capital  controls.    After  initially  experiencing  a  drop  

in   capital   flows,   a   country   with   an   open   capital   account   will   likely   enjoy   a   swift  

capital  inflow  recovery.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2.6  Formalizing  the  Relationship  Between  KAOPEN  &  FDI  Inflows  In  order  to  ascertain  the  strength  of  the  relationship  between  KAOPEN  and  net  FDI  

inflow  volume   for  my   focus   countries,   I  measure   the   correlation  between   the   two  

variables.     The   correlation   is  measured   during   an   eleven-­‐year   period   centered   on  

the  year  that  the  respective  crises  began.    It  inevitably  takes  some  time  for  changes  

in  capital  account  restrictiveness  to  reflect  in  capital  flow  volume.    I  lagged  the  FDI  

variable  by  one  year  to  account  for  this  time  delay.    If  KAOPEN  is  a  robust  measure  

of   capital   account   openness   and   an   effective   determinant   of   flow   volume,   there  

should   be   a   positive   correlation   between   the   index   value   and   FDI   inflow   volume.    

The  correlations  are  displayed  in  Table  2.  

 

 

Figure  21:  FDI  Net  Inflows  &  KAOPEN  Values  in  Singapore,  1992-­‐2002  This  figure  shows  annual  FDI  Net  Inflows  and  KAOPEN  Values  in  Venezuela  from  1997-­‐2007.    FDI  Net  Inflows  are  measured  in  $US  Millions.      

0  

0.2  

0.4  

0.6  

0.8  

1  

1.2  

$0.00  

$2,000.00  

$4,000.00  

$6,000.00  

$8,000.00  

$10,000.00  

$12,000.00  

$14,000.00  

$16,000.00  

$18,000.00  

1993   1994   1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003  

KAO

PEN  

FDI  InHlow  Volum

e  ($US  Millions)  

Year  FDI  Net  Inglows   KAOPEN  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  The   correlation   values   indicate   a   strong   positive   relationship   between  

KAOPEN  values  and  net  FDI  inflow  volume  in  each  of  my  focus  countries  except  for  

Vietnam  and  Singapore.    Vietnam  and  Singapore  are  unique  cases  because  over  the  

11-­‐year   crisis   period   centered   around   1998,   both   countries   made   smaller  

alterations   in   their   capital   controls   than   the   five  countries.     It   is  difficult   to  derive  

meaningful  correlation  values  for  Vietnam  and  Singapore  given  the  limited  number  

of   years   in   the   sample   and   the   minimal   changes   made   to   each   country’s   capital  

account   during   that   time  period.     The   correlation   values   are   encouraging  because  

they   strengthen   the   argument   that   there   is   an   association   between   the   two  

variables.     It   is   crucial,   however,   to   acknowledge   that   the   correlation  values   in  no  

way  imply  causation.  

 

   

Country   Correlation  

Argentina   0.526  Chile   0.420  

Venezuela   0.476  

Vietnam   -­‐0.257  

Malaysia   0.556  

Indonesia   0.745  Singapore   0.069  

Table  2:  Correlations  Between  KAOPEN  Values  &  FDI  Inflow  Volume  for  Focus  Countries,  11-­‐

Year  Period  Centered  on  Start  of  Crisis  

Source:  Author’s  calculations  based  on  World  Bank  data.  

 

3.  Conclusion  This  paper  evaluates  the  impact  of  capital  controls  on  capital  flow  volume  during  a  

financial  crisis.    In  general,  I  find  that  capital  account  restrictiveness  has  a  negative  

relationship  with  capital  flow  volume,  specifically  net  FDI  inflows.    This  relationship  

was   present   for   both   Latin   American   and   East   Asian   countries.     This   relationship  

held   whether   or   not   a   country   increased   or   decreased   their   capital   account  

restrictiveness.     The   relationship   also   held   regardless   of   a   country’s   pre-­‐crisis  

economic   vulnerability.     I   observed   that   countries   with   open   pre-­‐crisis   capital  

accounts   can   effectively   respond   to   a   regional   crisis   by   imposing   mild   capital  

controls,  and  then  eliminating  them  after  the  worst  phase  of  the  crisis  passes.  

  My   findings   suggest   that   capital   account   restrictiveness   is   a   more   robust  

predictor  of  FDI  inflow  volume  than  macroeconomic  variables  such  as  GDP  growth.    

Lessening   capital   controls   during   a   crisis   is   more   effective   at   increasing   capital  

inflow   volume   than   domestic   macroeconomic   recovery.     I   find   that   changes   in  

capital  account  restrictiveness  do  not  immediately  impact  net  FDI  inflow  volume.    It  

generally   takes   about   one   year   to   observe   measureable   effects   of   imposing   or  

eliminating  capital  controls  on  FDI  net  inflow  volume.    

   

 

   

 

References    

Adams-­‐Kane,  Jonathon,  and  Yueqing  Jia.  "Mapping  Global  Gross  Capital  Flows  

Through  2030."  (n.d.):  n.  pag.  World  Bank,  May  2013.  Web.  

 

Ananchotikul,  Nasha,  and  Ms  Longmei  Zhang.  Portfolio  Flows,  Global  Risk  Aversion  

and  Asset  Prices  in  Emerging  Markets.  No.  14-­‐156.  International  Monetary  Fund,  

2014.  

 

"AREAER  Online."  IMF  ELibrary.  IMF,  n.d.  Web.  

 

Arellano,  Cristina.  "Default  risk  and  income  fluctuations  in  emerging  

economies."  The  American  Economic  Review  (2008):  690-­‐712.  

 

Athukoralge,  Prema-­‐chandra.  Crisis  and  recovery  in  Malaysia:  the  role  of  capital  

controls.  Edward  Elgar  Publishing,  2001.  

 

Bailliu,  Jeannine  N.  Private  capital  flows,  financial  development,  and  economic  growth  

in  developing  countries.  Ottawa:  Bank  of  Canada,  2000.  

 

Bernanke,  Ben,  and  Mark  Gertler.  Monetary  policy  and  asset  price  volatility.  No.  

w7559.  National  bureau  of  economic  research,  2000.  

 

Borensztein,  Eduardo,  Jose  De  Gregorio,  and  Jong-­‐Wha  Lee.  "How  does  foreign  direct  

investment  affect  economic  growth?."  Journal  of  international  Economics  45.1  

(1998):  115-­‐135.  

 

Chamon,  Marcos,  and  Marcio  Garcia.  "Capital  controls  in  Brazil:  

effective?."International  Monetary  Fund,  manuscript  (2013).  

 

 

Chinn,  Menzie  D.,  and  Hiro  Ito.  "A  new  measure  of  financial  openness."  Journal  of  

comparative  policy  analysis  10.3  (2008):  309-­‐322.  

 

"Data  |  The  World  Bank."  Data  |  The  World  Bank.  The  World  Bank,  n.d.  Web.  

 

Diamond,  Douglas  W.,  and  Raghuram  G.  Rajan.  Liquidity  risk,  liquidity  creation  and  

financial  fragility:  A  theory  of  banking.  No.  w7430.  National  bureau  of  economic  

research,  1999.  

 

Edwards,  Sebastian.  How  effective  are  capital  controls?.  No.  w7413.  National  bureau  

of  economic  research,  1999.  

Eichengreen,  Barry  J.  Globalizing  capital:  a  history  of  the  international  monetary  

system.  Princeton  University  Press,  1998.  

 

Fischer,  Stanley,  and  Fonds  monétaire  international.  "Capital  Account  Liberalization  

and  the  Role  of  the  IMF."  (1997).  

Fontevecchia,  Agustino.  "Bernanke's  QE  Dance:  Fed  Could  Taper  In  Next  Two  

Meetings,  Tightening  Would  Collapse  The  Market."  Forbes.  Forbes  Magazine,  22  May  

2013.  Web.  

 

Frankel,  Jeffrey  A.  How  well  do  foreign  exchange  markets  function:  might  a  Tobin  tax  

help?.  No.  w5422.  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  1996.  

 

"Global  FDI  in  Decline  Due  to  the  Financial  Crisis,  and  a  Further  Drop  Expected."  

UNCTAD  Investment  Brief  (2009):  n.  pag.  UNCTAD,  2009.  Web.  

 

Hwang,  Soosung,  and  Mark  Salmon.  "Market  stress  and  herding."  Journal  of  

Empirical  Finance  11.4  (2004):  585-­‐616.  

 

"Just  in  Case."  The  Economist.  The  Economist  Newspaper,  12  Oct.  2013.  Web.  

 

 

Kaminsky,  Graciela  L.,  Carmen  M.  Reinhart,  and  Carlos  A.  Végh.  "When  it  rains,  it  

pours:  procyclical  capital  flows  and  macroeconomic  policies."  NBER  

Macroeconomics  Annual  2004,  Volume  19.  MIT  Press,  2005.  11-­‐82.  

 

Levy,  Haim,  and  Marshall  Sarnat.  "International  diversification  of  investment  

portfolios."  The  American  Economic  Review  (1970):  668-­‐675.  

 

Mihaljek,  Dubravko.  "The  financial  stability  implications  of  increased  capital  flows  

for  emerging  market  economies."  BIS  papers  44  (2008):  11-­‐44.  

 

Neely,  Christopher  J.  "An  introduction  to  capital  controls."  Federal  Reserve  Bank  of  

St.  Louis  Review  81.November/December  1999  (1999).  

 

Noland,  Marcus.  "South  Korea's  experience  with  international  capital  flows."Capital  

Controls  and  Capital  Flows  in  Emerging  Economies:  Policies,  Practices  and  

Consequences.  University  of  Chicago  Press,  2007.  481-­‐528.  

 

Organisation  for  Economic  Co-­‐operation  and  Development.  Foreign  direct  

investment  for  development:  Maximising  benefits,  minimising  costs.  OECD  Publishing,  

2002.  

 

Ostry,  Jonathan  D.,  et  al.  "Capital  inflows:  The  role  of  controls."  Revista  de  Economia  

Institucional  12.23  (2010):  135-­‐164.  

 

Portes,  Richard,  and  Helene  Rey.  "The  determinants  of  cross-­‐border  equity  

flows."  Journal  of  international  Economics  65.2  (2005):  269-­‐296.  

 

Reinhart,  Carmen,  and  Guillermo  Calvo.  "Capital  flow  reversals,  the  exchange  rate  

debate,  and  dollarization."  (1999):  13-­‐15.  

 

 

Resilience,  Towards  Human.  "Sustaining  MDG  Progress  in  an  Age  of  Economic  

Uncertainty."  (2011).  

 

Stiglitz,  Joseph  E.  "Capital  market  liberalization,  economic  growth,  and  

instability."  World  development  28.6  (2000):  1075-­‐1086.  

 

Stulz,  René  M.  "Globalization,  corporate  finance,  and  the  cost  of  capital.  "Journal  of  

applied  corporate  finance  12.3  (1999):  8-­‐25.  

 

Suchanek,  Lena,  and  Garima  Vasishtha.  "The  evolution  of  capital  flows  to  emerging-­‐

market  economies."  Bank  of  Canada  Review  2009.Winter  (2010):  19-­‐31.  

 

"Trade  Profiles."  Trade  Profiles-­‐  China.  World  Trade  Organization,  n.d.  Web.  

 

"Vietnam  -­‐  Foreign  Exchange  Control  Rules  for  Foreign  Direct  Investments  ."  KPMG,  

n.d.  Web.