Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

50
OCCASIONAL PAPER SERIES NO. 13 / APRIL 2004 FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING AND FINANCIAL STABILITY by a staff team led by Andrea Enria and including Lorenzo Cappiello, Frank Dierick, Sergio Grittini, Andrew Haralambous, Angela Maddaloni, Philippe Molitor, Fatima Pires and Paolo Poloni

Transcript of Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

Page 1: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

OCCAS IONAL PAPER S ER I E SNO. 13 / APR I L 2004

FAIR VALUE

ACCOUNTING AND

FINANCIAL STABILITY

by a staff team led by Andrea Enriaand including Lorenzo Cappiello,Frank Dierick, Sergio Grittini,Andrew Haralambous,Angela Maddaloni,Philippe Molitor,Fatima Pires and Paolo Poloni

Page 2: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

In 2004 all ECB publications will feature

a motif taken from the

€100 banknote.

OCCAS IONAL PAPER S ER I E SNO. 13 / APR I L 2004

FAIR VALUE

ACCOUNTING AND

FINANCIAL STABILITY

by a staff team led by Andrea Enriaand including

Lorenzo Cappiello,Frank Dierick, Sergio Grittini,

Andrew Haralambous,Angela Maddaloni,Philippe Molitor,Fatima Pires and

Paolo PoloniThis paper can be downloaded from

the ECB’s website (http://www.ecb.int).

Page 3: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

© European Central Bank, 2004

AddressKaiserstrasse 2960311 Frankfurt am MainGermany

Postal addressPostfach 16 03 1960066 Frankfurt am MainGermany

Telephone+49 69 1344 0

Websitehttp://www.ecb.int

Fax+49 69 1344 6000

Telex411 144 ecb d

All rights reserved. Reproduction foreducational and non-commercial purposesis permitted provided that the source isacknowledged.

The views expressed in this paper do notnecessarily reflect those of the EuropeanCentral Bank.

ISSN 1607-1484 (print)ISSN 1725-6534 (online)

Page 4: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

3ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

CONTENT S1 INTRODUCTION 4

2 THE DEBATE ON FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING 6

2.1 Accounting standards in theEuropean Union 6

2.2 Potential drawbacks and advantagesof a full fair value accountingframework 7

3 FULL FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING VS. THE CURRENTACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK: A SIMULATIONEXERCISE 14

3.1 Key assumptions and the valuationmodel 14

3.2 Deterioration in asset quality 17

3.2.1 One-off deterioration 17

3.2.2 Cumulative deterioration 20

3.3 Parallel shifts of the yield curve 21

3.4 Impact of an interest rate shockover time 21

3.5 Real estate crisis 22

3.6 Sharp adjustments in equity prices 23

4 DISCLOSURES OF FAIR VALUES IN THEFINANCIAL ACCOUNTS: COMPARATIVEANALYSIS OF MAJOR EU BANKS 27

5 FAIR VALUES AND VOLATILITY INSHARE PRICES 29

6 IAS 39: CONSISTENCY WITH MARKETPRACTICES, SUPERVISORY TOOLS ANDSTATISTICAL REQUIREMENTS 35

6.1 Concerns regarding hedgingactivities 35

6.2 Supervisory concerns 40

6.3 Statistical concerns 43

7 CONCLUSIONS 45

Page 5: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

4ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

1 I N TRODUCT I ONAccounting standards bodies are currentlyrefining their proposals for the introduction ofadditional elements of fair value accounting forfinancial instruments. The ECB has a keeninterest in this debate, as accounting reformsare likely to have a profound impact on thebanking and financial industry. Furthermore,harmonised and high-quality accountingstandards could make a significant contributionto the integration and efficiency of financialmarkets in the euro area. On a broader scale,they could also facilitate European firms’access to the large international financialmarkets, thereby promoting growth. Theinterest of the ECB also stems from theconcerns that a wider application of fairvaluations might have adverse effects onfinancial stability. The consistency between theaccounting framework and the reporting forsupervisory and statistical purposes is also anaspect deserving due attention.

This paper1 focuses mainly on the potentialfinancial stability implications of Full FairValue Accounting (FFVA)2. However, it alsoaddresses certain issues specifically relating toInternational Accounting Standard 39 –Financial Instruments: Recognition andMeasurement. The attention is centredexclusively on banking, even though it isacknowledged that similar concerns may arisefor the stability of other sectors of financialactivity, and insurance in particular3. In order tomake what is a very complex issue moremanageable, this paper uses a stylisedcomparison between FFVA and the presentaccounting rules, herein referred to as theCurrent Accounting Framework (CAF4). Theresults are preliminary and somewhatincomplete. They are based on some simplifyingassumptions that may need to be reviewed.Whereas the findings suggest the need forfurther analysis, some relevant conclusionsalready emerge.

Section 2 explains the setting for this work,describing the state of play of accountingstandards in the European Union (EU) andreviewing the main arguments supporting and

opposing FFVA versus the CAF. A simulationexercise trying to analyse the potential impactof the introduction of FFVA on an average EUbank’s balance sheet is presented in Section 3.This exercise assesses the different dynamics ofbalance-sheet items under FFVA and the CAFin the face of a number of shocks. Section 4presents a comparison of the impact of the useof fair value valuation criteria on a small sampleof EU banks in order to highlight the main itemsof the balance sheet on which FFVA is likely tohave a significant effect. Section 5 presents thepreliminary results of an empirical investigationaimed at gauging whether the shift from theCAF to FFVA for banks’ trading books hasaffected the price volatility of the banks’ ownlisted shares. Section 6 then enters into morespecific concerns relating to the consistencyof the current accounting reform (focusingmainly on aspects of IAS 39) with soundrisk management practices adopted by banks(especially in the treatment of hedging),supervisory tools and statistical requirements.Finally, Section 7 presents the conclusions ofthe analysis, stressing that the introduction of

1 By a staff team led by Andrea Enria and including LorenzoCappiello, Frank Dierick, Sergio Grittini, Andrew Haralambous,Angela Maddaloni, Philippe Molitor, Fatima Pires and PaoloPoloni. This paper has benefited from the suggestions andcontributions received by members of the Banking SupervisionCommittee (BSC) and by members of an ad-hoc task force of theBSC composed by Juergen Ardnt, Carlo Calandrini, Thomas De-Vecchi, Olivier Jaudoin, Maria Leal, Konstataijn Maes, KalliopiNonika, and Jacobo Varela. Christian Fehlker and Michael Olsenalso contributed to the project. Comments on earlier versions ofthe paper from Darren Pain, Panagiotis Strouzas and GarrySchinasi are also gratefully acknowledged.

2 Under FFVA, assets and liabilities are carried on the balancesheet at their market value, if known, or at fair value, which isdefined as the amount for which an asset could be exchanged, ora liability settled, between knowledgeable, willing parties in anarm’s-length transaction.

3 Häusler G., 2003, “The Insurance Industry, Fair ValueAccounting and Systemic Financial Stability”, InternationalMonetary Fund, International Capital Markets, Speech given atthe 30th General Assembly of the Geneva Association.

4 It is acknowledged that accounting practices may varyconsiderably across Europe. However, for the purpose of thisstudy a generalised framework was considered – the CurrentAccounting Framework (CAF). Under the CAF assets are carriedat the amount of cash or cash equivalents paid or the fair value ofthe consideration at the time of acquisition. Liabilities are carriedat the amount received in exchange for the obligation. In generalterms, CAF is the measurement basis most commonly used byenterprises in preparing their financial statements. However, it isalso usually combined with other measurement bases, such asmarket prices (namely for trading activities) and lower of cost ormarket prices (“LOCOM”).

Page 6: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

5ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

1

IntroductionFFVA could have a very significant effect.Volatility of income is likely to be affected andthe pro-cyclicality of lending might alsoincrease. However, the positive effect thatFFVA would have on the ability of stakeholdersto take corrective action and safeguard thesafety and soundness of financial institutions isalso recognised. It is argued that any steptowards the introduction of FFVA should begradual enough – and consistent acrosscountries and companies – to avoid magnifyingany systemic disturbances.

Page 7: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

6ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

2.1 ACCOUNTING STANDARDS IN THE EUROPEANUNION

The need for a reform of the accountingtreatment of financial instruments stems fromseveral market developments. Financialinnovation has blurred the distinction betweenfinancial instruments and has contributed to thedevelopment of markets for instruments thatwere traditionally considered as illiquid andnon-tradable. The rationale for the differentaccounting treatment of banking, securities andinsurance services has gradually disappeared asthey often serve the same economic function.Moreover, as financial institutions haveincreased the range of services they provide, somixed accounting systems have been developedthat do not seem sustainable in the long run.

As the trading and capital market-relatedactivities of banks has grown, the accountingframework has been modified to permit marketvaluations for all the instruments held for tradingpurposes. The coexistence in banks’ financialstatements of items valued at historical cost(which are mainly held in the so-called “bankingbook”) and others at market values (in the“trading book”, which is “marked-to-market”)would be viable only if banks were managing thetwo components of the bank portfolio in a totallysegregated manner. But this is not the case, astrading instruments are increasingly used tohedge the interest rate risk in the banking book.5

More importantly, the increased reliance offinancial institutions on derivatives contracts,which in most jurisdictions are recorded as off-balance-sheet items, has contributed to a growingmisalignment between the information containedin financial statements and the true risk profilesof reporting entities. Even supervisoryauthorities and central banks are often lackinginformation on the effective redistribution ofrisks resulting from the extensive use ofderivative instruments such as credit derivatives.Current disclosure requirements are not deemedto be adequate to cover this information gap. Animprovement in the quality, coherence andinformation content of financial statementstherefore seems necessary in order to reflect the

2 THE D EB AT E ON FA I R VA LU E A C COUNT I NGnew financial environment and thereby favour aproper monitoring of management’s behaviourby stakeholders.

Within the EU, the push for a reform alsooriginates in the need to overcome differencesin accounting standards between MemberStates. Harmonisation in this area is a crucialstep towards supporting the integration offinancial markets in the euro area and in the EU.

A fundamental building block of the long-termstrategy developed by the InternationalAccounting Standards Board (IASB), anindependent and privately-funded standard-setting body based in London, is to bringfinancial statements up to date with marketdevelopments. In December 2000 the JointWorking Group of Standard Setters (JWG),consisting of the IASB’s predecessor andnational accounting standard-setters, developeda proposal to use FFVA for all financialinstruments. In the presence of coherentmethodologies for the calculation of fair values,the proposal would in fact provide a simple andconsistent approach for the valuation offinancial instruments on the books of financialinstitutions and across entities with a differentmix of activities.

However, the JWG’s proposal was receivedwith scepticism by some banks and byregulators, as credit risk models and valuationmethods of illiquid or non-traded instrumentsare not yet suitably developed to extend FFVAto important components of the balance sheet offinancial institutions, in particular banks.Concerns were also voiced regarding the impacton financial stability that might derive from theincreased volatility of financial statements. TheECB also conveyed its concerns to the JWG inNovember 2001.6

5 Jackson, P. and Lodge, D., 2000, “Fair value accounting, capitalstandards, expected loss provisioning, and financial stability”,Financial Stability Review, Regulatory Policy Division, Bank ofEngland.

6 Fair value accounting in the banking sector: ECB comments on the“Draft standard and basis for conclusions – financial instrumentsand similar items” issued by the Financial Instruments JointWorking Group of Standard Setters, 8 November 2001.

Page 8: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

7ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

2

The debateon fair

value accounting

In 2002 the IASB proposed amendments toInternational Accounting Standard (IAS) 39 –the crucial standard for the valuation offinancial instruments. The proposal includedthe possibility that several components of thebanking book (in particular, loans) couldcontinue to be carried at amortised cost, whilstintroducing an irrevocable option allowingfinancial institutions to measure any financialasset or liability at fair value through profit andloss at inception, the “fair value option”.Further criticism regarding the treatment ofportfolio hedging prompted the IAS to issue aspecific Exposure Draft on this issue. Thedebate is still very contentious, namelyregarding the issues of macro-hedging and thefair value option.

The ECB has voiced its concerns regarding theapplication of the fair value option. Theseconcerns are also supported by the conclusionsof this report. The IASB has acknowledged theconcerns that the fair value option may be usedinappropriately and announced its intention tolimit the application of the option to specifiedcategories of financial instruments, to introducethe requirement that fair values be verifiableand to recognise the role of prudentialsupervisors. These proposals were published inthe Exposure Draft, issued in April 2004. Thefinal version of IAS 39 is expected to be issuedin October 2004.

The European Commission’s interest in theharmonisation of accounting standards in the EUis reflected in the strong political commitment toendorse the standards issued by the IASB. InMay 2003 the EU Council approved a Directive7

which removed any inconsistencies between theexisting Accounting Directives and the IAS, andcomplemented a Regulation of July 20028 thatrequires all listed EU companies (includingbanks) to prepare consolidated accounts inaccordance with IAS from 2005 onwards. In July2003 the Commission welcomed the endorsementof the IAS by the Accounting RegulatoryCommittee9 (ARC), and in September 2003adopted a Regulation10 endorsing the IAS, withthe exception of IAS 32 and IAS 39 pending the

finalisation of these standards by the IASB. TheCommission therefore has a strong interest thatthe main issues of concern raised with referenceto the wider use of fair values for financialinstruments be satisfactorily dealt with, in orderto move to full endorsement of the IAS.

2.2 POTENTIAL DRAWBACKS AND ADVANTAGESOF A FULL FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTINGFRAMEWORK

Given the relevance of accounting standardsand the lively policy debate, fundamental issuesare raised to highlight both the costs and thebenefits of the wider application of fair valueaccounting, which makes it difficult to arrive toa clear-cut overall evaluation.

Five main drawbacks have surfaced from thecurrent debate on whether more extensive useshould be made of fair valuations. The firstfocuses on the likely increase in the volatility ofincome. It can be argued that volatility providesrelevant information and should be dulyrecognised in the financial statements.However, an excessive reliance on fair values,including for assets that are not actively tradedon liquid secondary markets, runs the risk thatthe information disclosed will embody“artificial” volatility, driven by short-termfluctuations in financial market valuations,or caused by market imperfections or byinadequate development of valuationtechniques. Moreover, for assets and liabilitiesheld to maturity, the volatility reflected in thefinancial statements is artificial and can beultimately misleading, as any deviations from

7 Directive 2003/51/EC of the European Parliament and of theCouncil of 18 June 2003 amending Directives 78/660/EEC, 83/349/EEC, 86/635/EEC and 91/674/EEC on the annual andconsolidated accounts of certain types of companies, banks andother financial institutions and insurance undertakings, publishedin OJ L 178 of 17 July 2003.

8 Regulation (EC) No 1606/2002.9 Committee composed of representatives of the EU Member States

and headed by the European Commission. The committee has aregulatory function and provides opinions on Commissionproposals to adopt international accounting standards.

10 Regulation (EC) No 1725/2003.

Page 9: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

8ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

cost will be gradually compensated for duringthe life of the financial instrument, “pulling thevalue to par” at maturity.11

The cost could be a potential increase in theintrinsic pro-cyclicality of bank lending , asmore accentuated increases in bank profits andcapital during upturns would support theoverextension of credit, that would then createthe conditions for a deeper and more long-lasting downturn. This would then also beexacerbated by the effect that downwardadjustments in asset valuations would have onbank profits and capital, which would furtherrestrain their lending. Moreover, anotherpotential result would be to limit creditavailability to counterparties whose creditstatus is more volatile, e.g. small and medium-sized enterprises (SME). Given the importanceof SMEs in Europe this may have a detrimentaleffect on future economic developments.

The second drawback relates to the role ofbanks in maturity and liquidity transformation.The joint provision of deposits and loans putsbanks in a position to provide liquidity ondemand and support the needs of othercomponents of the financial sector and of theeconomy as a whole, also in times of distress.12

This role is fundamentally linked to the opaquenature of the value of bank assets resulting fromthe non-marketability of loan contracts.13 It isargued that the attempt to introduce fair valuesfor loans fails to recognise a permanent andpositive feature of banking, i.e. its contributionto the overcoming of informational asymmetriesbetween lenders and borrowers. In this line ofreasoning, FFVA might drive banks to foregotheir fundamental function. As the accountingframework would not reflect their “lend andhold” attitude towards credit extension, bankswould face an incentive to hedge, securitise, orshift the risk to customers (e.g., via floating-rate or shorter-term loans) in order to movetowards a matched composition of theirliabilities.14 The potential cost to the financialsystem would be that liquidity and maturitytransformation would be more limited in scope,

as interest rate changes would be directlyreflected in the profit and loss (P&L) accounts.In this perspective, FFVA could encouragebanks to unduly emphasise short-term results atthe expense of long-term customer relationshipsand investment needs.

The third drawback concerns the role of banksas institutions smoothing intertemporalshocks.15 In all likelihood, FFVA will producemore positive results during good times, whenasset prices are increasing. This would beparticularly the case if economic agents have anoverly optimistic assessment of risks duringupturns, reflected in a short-term bias in thecalculation of expected cash flows. The upwardrevaluations of assets would be reflected inbank profits and bank management could facepressure from shareholders to distributedividends, including unrealised gains on assetsremaining in the bank portfolio.16 Banks’ abilityto smooth intertemporal shocks would thereforebe adversely affected, with a resulting cost interms of both the efficiency and the stability ofthe financial intermediation function. The CAF,on the other hand, applies the principle ofprudence which does not recognise unrealisedgains that may not materialise. In addition, theCAF makes it possible to build up reservesduring good times, which can then be depletedduring bad times. This would translate intolower variability in bank income and wouldallow banks to insure themselves againstunforeseen circumstances. This intertemporal

11 See Section 3.4 for a more detailed explanation of this issue.12 Padoa-Schioppa, T., 1999, “Licensing Banks: Still Necessary?”,

Group of Thirty, William Taylor Memorial Lecture on BankingPolicy, Washington D.C., 24 September.

13 Diamond, D. W., 1984, “Financial Intermediation and DelegatedMonitoring”, The Review of Economic Studies, vol. 51. no 3, pp.393-414.

14 FFVA’s discounting model makes longer-term assets increasinglysensitive to changes in interest rates.

15 Allen, F. and Gale, D., 1997, “Financial Markets, Intermediaries,and Intertemporal Smoothing”, The Journal of Political Economy,Vol. 105, No 3, pp. 523-546.

16 Tax is an added complication given that in several EU countriesaccounting statements are used to determine the taxable basis.

Page 10: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

9ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

2

The debateon fair

value accounting

smoothing function of the financial systemwould therefore be better accomplished underthe CAF.17

The fourth drawback is the potential disruptionto market discipline caused by the reduction ofcomparability and reliability of financialstatements across financial institutions. UnderFFVA, when there is no observable marketvalue then valuation models are used. Fairvalues obtained by these models should bebased on inputs from liquid markets in order toreduce the scope for possible manipulation. Atpresent a variety of valuation models coexistwith varied inputs and assumptions, and thismay significantly reduce comparability if usedindiscriminately across banks and acrossbalance-sheet items. Furthermore, it should alsobe mentioned that the date and purpose of thevaluation is critical in establishing a fair marketvalue. A valuation is determined for a particularpoint in time, and generally should not be reliedupon for other dates. In the same vein, avaluation is usually performed for a particularpurpose and generally may not be appropriatefor another purpose. For example, shareholdersmay value intangibles while creditors would bemore interested in the net realisable value.Moreover, given the current state of the art,particularly with regard to credit risk models,reliability in financial statements could benegatively affected. Indeed, fair values do notalways convey precise information concerning abank’s risk profile, thus hindering marketdiscipline that requires reliable information inorder to be effective. Misjudgement can triggeroverreaction, which can have a negative impacton the financial situation of a firm.

Finally, the fifth drawback focuses on thelimited reliability of present bank estimates ofprobabilities of default (PDs) for accountingpurposes. In its comments on the work of theJWG, the Federal Reserve Board18 questionedthe reliability and objectivity of fair valuesestimated using market credit spreads andinternal models. Indeed, there are seriouslimitations on the use of credit marketinformation as there is a large dispersion in

observed credit spreads for rated debt withineach risk grade and for a given maturity forlower-rated debt categories. Even between bankloans and bond obligations with the sameobligor, differences in observed credit spreadsare large and varied. Meanwhile, internal creditrisk rating systems may produce valuableinformation reflecting banks’ risk managementneeds, but they are not suitable for managingloan portfolios on a market-value basis.

Moving to the advantages of FFVA, thekey issue is the improved scope formarket discipline and corrective action. It isincreasingly acknowledged in both the academicliterature and the supervisory debate that thediscipline exercised by informed and uninsuredinvestors is an essential complement ofsupervisory control. FFVA would in principlelead to better insight into the risk profile of thebanks than is presently the case, also in the lightof the requirement to move many relevant off-balance-sheet items onto the balance sheet.Financial stability could benefit if shareholders,uninsured depositors and other debtholders arein a position to readily identify a deteriorationin the safety and soundness of a bank. In fact,their reactions – either by directly interfering inmanagerial choices or by exiting from theinvestment – could put pressure on the bank’smanagement to take corrective action at an earlystage (see Box 1).

17 Freixas, X. and Tsomocos, D., 2003, “Book vs. Fair ValueAccounting in Banking, and Intertemporal Smoothing”,September.

18 O’Brien, J., 2001, “The Use of Bank Internal Ratings Systems forLoan Fair Valuation”, Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem, Division of Research and Statistics, December.

Page 11: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

10ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Box 1

COUNTRY EXPERIENCES1

There are several examples of crises that may have been exacerbated by a lack of market accessto information on embedded losses. For instance, the lack of information and weakened marketdiscipline may have played an important role in deepening the US Savings and Loans crisis andthe more recent Japanese financial crisis.

US Savings & Loans

Between 1980 and 1994, about 1,300 Savings & Loans institutions (S&Ls), with assets ofUSD 621 billion, closed down or received Federal Savings and Loans Insurance Corporation(FSLIC) assistance. They had been weakened by a sharp increase in their funding rates and poorinvestment decisions. However the accounting treatment may also have played an important role.

Indeed, under the existing accounting framework, the S&Ls appeared to be solvent despite adeficit on a market-value basis of USD 118 billion.

The S&Ls were exposed to substantial interest rate risk, as 80% of their lending was in long-term fixed rate mortgages, funded mainly by short-term deposits at market interest rates. Whenthe average cost of S&L funding rose from 7% to 11% it surpassed the average return on theirmortgage lending. However, the embedded interest rate losses (under the existing accountingframework) showed up only in earnings each year going forward, whereas under FFVA theoverall loss would have been immediately recognised on the balance sheet through the presentvalue calculations. Thus, although the S&Ls had already sustained a sharp fall in their expectedearnings income stream, this fact was concealed by the accounting rules and the S&Ls continuedto reflect positive net worth.

In this context, the FSLIC responded by deciding to exercise regulatory forbearance, whichincluded a loosening of the accounting standards. The S&Ls were allowed to amortise goodwillfrom other S&L acquisitions over 40 years, whilst at the same time immediately recognisingincome from the acquired assets. Moreover, a plunge in the real estate market also added loanlosses to the already embedded interest rate losses. And to make matters worse, the S&Ls wereallowed to defer losses on loans sold over the remaining contractual life of the asset, rather thanrecognising the loss immediately in the profit and loss account (P&L). As a result, S&Lfinancial accounts completely failed to reflect the already massive existent embedded losses andappropriate corrective action by stakeholders (or early liquidation) was delayed, thus increasingthe final cost of the crisis to the US taxpayer.

Provisioning practices in Japan

Japanese banks disclose their non-performing loans under standards set by the JapaneseBankers’ Association (Zenginkyo). The definition of non-performing loans used by Zenginkyoprior to 1995 was narrow, comprising only loans to borrowers in legal bankruptcy plus loans inarrears for six months or more. However, from 1995 onwards the definition was broadened on

1 “Fair Value Accounting, Capital Standards, Expected Loss Provisioning, and Financial Stability”, Financial Stability Review, Bank ofEngland, June 2000.

Page 12: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

11ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

2

The debateon fair

value accountingtwo occasions, and from 1998 the Japanese Financial Supervisory Agency (JFSA) finallyintroduced a comprehensive assessment of problem loans more in accordance with the existingaccounting standards.

Notably, with each redefinition of problem exposures, the amount of non-performing loans, asdisclosed by the banks, substantially increased, despite the fact that these non-performing loanswere net of write-offs, which were also increasing over the period.

It can be argued that the crisis was indeed prolonged by the delay in provisioning and write-offs. In 1995 the redefinition of non-performing loans led to their sharp increase in thedisclosed amount, and specific provisions and write-offs also increased substantially, from lessthan JPY 6 trillion to JPY 11 trillion.

Thus it seems that following the sharp decline in property and equity markets, provisioning tooka number of years to adequately reflect the extent of the latent damage to loan books. Proponentsof full fair value accounting (with full allowance for expected losses) state that under thisregime problems would tend to become evident earlier, allowing for timelier corrective action.

Indeed, more precise information on the valueof banks’ assets would support marketdiscipline and transparency, thus favouring the

Box 2

UNDER-PRICED AND OVER-PRICED LOANS

If a loan is correctly priced at origination, the fair value equals the face value. In the absence ofany change in external conditions and in the presence of a flat yield curve, valuations will notdiffer under FFVA and the CAF, even if the borrower has defaulted (or the asset has beenimpaired). If the yield curve is not flat then some differences can emerge, but in all likelihoodthey would remain very limited. However, if for any reason the loan is over-priced, the fairvalue will reflect this surplus at origination, and the value of the loan will be correcteddownwards in the following period to coincide with the nominal value at maturity – or atdefault, corrected for the loss given default (LGD). A symmetric result would apply in case ofan under-priced loan. This means that phenomena such as implicit subsidies and cross-subsidisation – in relation to other entities of the banking group or to customers – would bereflected in bank accounts, provided of course that mispriced loans were correctly fair valued.In particular, under-pricing would immediately cause a loss to be reported in the incomestatement. The likely result would be increased transparency, vis-à-vis the public at large andthe supervisors, which could represent a powerful incentive to abandon these pricing practices.

Another interesting aspect concerns the distribution of this effect over time. While thecumulated profits will be the same at the maturity of the loan, their distribution through time willdiffer substantially. Under the CAF the reported profits will be stable throughout the life of theloan, but FFVA will give rise to increased volatility, as it imposes reporting a gain or a loss atorigination that is then reabsorbed throughout the life of the loan.

working of private incentives in curtailingopaque practices of cross-subsidisation (seeBox 2).

Page 13: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

12ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

The second advantage can be seen as the otherside of the coin regarding the cost of banks’role in maturity and liquidity transformation, asmentioned above. Indeed, it may also be thecase that banks will take advantage of the toolsprovided by financial innovation and rely onmore sophisticated instruments to perform theirtraditional liquidity transformation function.For instance, banks may increasingly relyon securitisation and other risk-transfermechanisms to limit the adverse consequencesof FFVA on the P&L account, while ensuringliquidity provisions to support developments onsecondary markets for instruments that arecurrently non-tradable. If so, FFVA might endup supporting the increased marketability ofcurrently illiquid assets. By spreading the risksthrough the financial system, it might also havea positive benefit of possibly increasingsystemic resilience.

The third advantage stresses the potential ofFFVA to limit the scope for pro-cyclicality. Atleast for large borrowers, for whom secondarytrading prices or credit spreads can be used, fairvalues would reflect the market perception ofcredit quality. As a result, adjustments invaluations would be well understood by theusers of financial statements. Furthermore, asfair values are based on the notion of expectedcash flows, they are forward-looking in natureand should embody all the informationavailable. Hence, FFVA should allow for theearlier recognition of asset deterioration. If,however, losses are incurred and measured onthe basis of private information anddiscretionary and unquestioned decisions of themanagement, provisions and charge-offs maywell come as a surprise to the markets. Theycould also tend to be more backward-lookingand pro-cyclical. Provisioning may also come inbig chunks, making investors’ assessment onthe quality of bank assets subject to sharpadjustments. The perceived opaqueness of bankbehaviour may also lead investors to overshootin their reaction to such news. As all this islikely to occur during downturns, a latecorrection in valuations may possibly betransposed into a tighter credit squeeze that

would contribute to a further slowdown ineconomic activity. Furthermore, the potentialfor increased volatility would possibly increasethe risk of certain binding financial ratios beingexceeded (e.g. capital requirements or ratiosused in loan covenants that could trigger actionssuch as repayment). Financial institutions mayface an incentive to take proactive measures inorder to prevent this from occurring, forinstance by building up additional reserves andthereby increasing their resilience.

Finally, it may be argued that increasedvolatility in accounting magnitudes is notnecessarily a problem if investors correctlyinterpret the information disclosed. Inparticular, and already under the CAF, marketanalysts and institutional investors try toextrapolate fair valuations from a variety ofsources. If they were completely successful indoing so, the increased volatility in balance-sheet items would have no impact on investors’perceptions19. But even if this were not the caseand new elements were to be conveyed by thedisclosure of financial statements under FFVA,mature financial markets would be in a positionto appropriately interpret this increasedvolatility.

The divergent views regarding FFVA reveal adifferent perspective on banking. Under FFVA,a bank is seen as a bundle of assets andliabilities, not very different from an investmentfund: what matters is the net asset value, i.e.what the shareholders could earn by selling thebank at any particular moment. The emphasisis on the investors’ (in particular, theshareholders’) view, in the belief that the main

19 This argument presupposes the existence of markets that aresemi-strong form efficient, i.e. where all available publicinformation is correctly reflected in the market valuations byinvestors. Tests for market eff iciency are always joint tests ofmarket efficiency and the correctness of the underlying assetpricing model (that is used to compute normal prices and returns).Modern financial literature rejects this joint hypothesis andfinds that there is substantial predictability of asset returns.This rejection has driven the quest for more advancedasset-pricing models, aiming to link the reported predictabilitywith the expected excess returns that follow from theasset-pricing model.

Page 14: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

13ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

2

The debateon fair

value accounting

function of financial statements is to provideaccurate information on which they can basetheir decisions. The traditional approach ismore geared towards perceiving a bank as agoing concern , thus emphasising the role ofbank-customer relationships that may escape anaccurate market pricing and the viability of thebank in the medium term. Within thisframework, the focus is more on the interest ofall stakeholders (in particular creditors, but alsoborrowers) that the bank steadily continues toperform its liquidity and maturitytransformation functions. The differentperspective emerges with greater clarity in thediscussion on the treatment of own credit riskand on the issue of provisioning practices,which will be discussed in more detail in thefollowing sections.

The above outline of the debate on FFVAshows that the issue is multifaceted anddifficult to address relying solely on hardevidence. In order to have a balancedassessment of the arguments discussed above, itwould be essential to understand how thischange in accounting paradigm would impactthe behaviour of banks and banks’stakeholders. This is not easily done, as nocountry has gone so far as to apply FFVA to allassets and liabilities. However, some elementsfor an assessment have been gathered andprovided in this report, which may contribute toweighing the pros and cons.

Page 15: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

14ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

As a first attempt to understand the likelyimpact of FFVA (as compared with the CAF)on financial stability, a simulation exercise wasperformed aimed at gauging how variousshocks would affect the balance sheet of a bank.The following scenarios were considered: (i) asignificant deterioration in asset quality; (ii) anunexpected change in interest rates; (iii) thedeflating of a real-estate bubble; and (iv)significant upward and downward adjustmentsin stock prices.

3.1 KEY ASSUMPTIONS AND THE VALUATIONMODEL

In order to make the exercise relevant for theassessment of the introduction of FFVA in theEU, the simulation uses a hypothetical bankresembling as much as possible the asset andliability composition of the average EU bank.Of course, this type of analysis is subject to a“Lucas critique”, given that the balance sheetstructure is taken as given and that thebehaviour of the bank is assumed not tochange when confronted with a reform ofthe accounting framework. However, thesimulation remains useful to provide thebackground for a discussion of possiblebehavioural reactions to the introduction ofFFVA for financial instruments. In fact, ifFFVA is ever adopted, banks will look at thelikely impact on their current balance sheetstructure and decide on changes that minimisethe undesirable effects. Furthermore, asimulation exercise is also helpful forunderstanding the overall effect: even thoughthe different scenarios are analysed under aceteris paribus assumption, it is possible tocombine some of them and have a preliminaryassessment of possible compensating effects.

In order to more accurately reflect the profile ofa “typical EU bank”, aggregate data for the EUbanking sector are considered. OECD statisticsprovided the main source of aggregateinformation, while additional breakdowns arecalculated using the ECB’s Money and BankingStatistics. When no other aggregate source was

3 FULL FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING VS THE CURRENTACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK: A SIMULATIONEXERCISE

available, the financial statements of somemajor EU banks are used as a proxy.

Unfortunately, reliable aggregated data on thesize of variable and fixed rate contracts and onthe relative weight of securities included in thebanking and trading books are not readilyavailable. Hence the simplistic assumption ismade that the assets are held in equal proportion(i.e. 50%-50%). Even though the situationseems to be highly diversified across MemberStates, this assumption was checked on asample of different banks and appeared to beplausible20. As the results can be very sensitiveto this assumption, additional national sourcescould be used in further refinements of thework, or different proportions could besimulated in order to estimate the sensitivity ofthe effects to the assumptions. A furthersimplifying assumption that might bereconsidered in future work concerns thematurity of the loan portfolio. In the absence ofinformation on residual maturity, an averagematurity of ten years was considered formortgage loans, while for corporate loans short,medium and long-term aggregates as reported inthe ECB statistics were respectively attributed amaturity of one, three and ten years. Moreover,partial checks performed in some MemberStates confirmed that on the basis of availableinformation this assumption is sufficientlyrobust. Finally, another important simplifyingassumption is that derivatives are notconsidered. This is certainly a clear constraintfor the analysis, but the lack of informationdoes not allow any other possibility.

20 Regarding the size of variable and fixed-rate contracts theassumption is representative of the situation in some MemberStates. Where the relative weight of securities in the banking andtrading books is concerned, the situation varies greatly betweenMember States from an equal split to approximately 80% ofsecurities in the banking book.

Page 16: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

15ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

Structure before the shockBalance sheet % of assets in €€€€€

Assets1. Corporate loans 31.0 3,100.0

1.a. Short-term – fixed rate 15.5 1,550.01.b. Medium-term 4.7 465.0

Fixed rate 2.3 232.5Variable rate 2.3 232.5

1.c. Long-term 10.9 1,085.0Fixed rate 5.4 542.5Variable rate 5.4 542.5

Specific provisions for corporate loans2. Mortgage loans – fixed rate 15.0 1,500.0

Specific provisions for mortgage loans3. Securities 23.0 2,300.0

3.a. Debt securities 18.4 1,840.0Trading book 9.2 920.0Banking book 9.2 920.0

3.b. Shares 4.6 460.0Trading book 2.3 230.0Banking book 2.3 230.0

Specific provisions for securities in banking book4. Other 31.0 3,100.0

Total assets 100.0 10,000.0

Liabilities1. Deposits & interbank borrowing 63.0 6,300.02. Bonds 12.5 1,250.03. Other 18.6 1,850.0Capital and reserves 5.9 600.0

Total liabilities & Capital and reserves 100.0 10,000.0

Table 1 Init ia l balance sheet

Our average EU bank (see balance sheet above),is assumed to be newly established, thus theCAF and FFVA should in principle21 deliverthe same picture at the start of the simulation.Attention should therefore be focused on thedifferential treatment in the presence ofdifferent shocks. The box below summarisesthe main assumptions to provide a quickoverview of the changes in the variousscenarios.

The approach used aims to estimate how a shockto an exogenous factor would affect the fairvalue of a financial instrument. The informationon probabilities of default (PDs) and lossesgiven default (LGDs) has been extrapolatedfrom the results of the third Quantitative ImpactSurvey (QIS3) performed by the BaselCommittee on Banking Supervision to assessthe effects of the proposed changes to the NewBasel Capital Accord. For the sake ofsimplicity, a flat yield curve was assumed22.

The fair value of fixed-income instruments (e.g.,loans, bonds, medium-term notes (MTNs), etc.)is calculated by discounting the expected cashflows at the discount rate. The expected cashflow at a given point in time is the sum of all thepossible cash flows on that date, multiplied bythe probability attached to a particular outcome.A distinction is made between collateralised andnon-collateralised instruments, as well asbetween bullet instruments – whose principal isrepaid in full at maturity – and annuities – whichenvisage a constant payment in each period –thus leading to four possible types of instrument(see Box 3).

21 As argued in Box 2, this may not be the case if the bank for anyreason under-prices or over-prices some loans.

22 A flat yield curve simplif ies the analysis considerably. Indeed,the forward rate curve will be identical to the yield curve in thiscase, and hence every change in the yield curve will represent anunexpected change by definition. This is important, since onlyunexpected changes in interest rates will affect the net worth ofbanks in theory. If the yield curve were upward sloping, anincrease in the interest rate that is in line with the forward rateleaves net worth unchanged.

Page 17: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

16ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Box 3

KEY ASSUMPTIONS

– Balance sheet composition reflects average EU banking sector structure– Variable and fixed rate contracts in equal proportions (50%-50%)– Maturities (average):

Short term: 1 yearMedium term: 3 yearsLong term: 10 years

– Flat yield curve– Mortgage loans: collateralised annuities– Corporate loans: uncollateralised bullet loans– Probability of default (PD) and loss given default (LGD) extrapolated from the Third

Quantitative Impact Survey (QIS3)Mortgage loans: PD = 0.5% and LGD = 10%Corporate loans: PD = 1% and LGD = 45%

– Scenario I: One-off deterioration in asset qualityMortgage loans: PD = 1%Corporate loans: PD = 2%

– Scenario II: Cumulative deterioration in asset qualityMortgage loans: PD = 7.48%Corporate loans: PD = 15.66%

– Scenario III: Interest rate changesParallel shift in yield curve: 100 basis points (upward and downward)

– Scenario IV: Real estate crisisCommercial real estate replaces mortgage portfolioLGD = 70%PD = 3%Interest rates = +300bp

– Scenario V: Volatility in equity pricesAnnual price increase: 30%Annual price decrease: 40%

The calculation is given by the followingformula:

��

n

tt

t

t

RFCFE

1 )1()(valueFair

where n indicates the contractual maturity ofthe financial instrument, CF the cash flows, RFthe risk-free zero coupon rate, and RP the riskpremium. In turn the expected cash flow at aparticular point in time (i.e., the numerator ofthe ratio) can be expressed as follows:

where m indicates the number of possible statesat time t and for each state i there is acorresponding possible cash flow CF(i)

with an

associated probability p(i). The formula is thenadjusted to take into consideration therepayment of part of the principal beforematurity for annuities, while for collateralisedloans the expected cash flow is adjusted in caseof borrower default to take into account thecollateral value. The changes in the probability

� �ipiCFCFE t

m

itt �

1)()(

(1 + RFt + RP

t) t

Page 18: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

17ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

of default (PD) are factored into the associatedprobability, whilst the changes in the loss givendefault (LGD) are incorporated in the CF.

3.2 DETERIORATION IN ASSET QUALITY

The first scenario considered is an unexpectedand generalised increase in credit risk. Thedeterioration in the creditworthiness of theborrowers will be reflected in the increase of theirprobability of default. The main assets that will beaffected by changes in the credit quality will be theloan portfolio (which comprises 46% of totalassets) and the debt securities held both in thetrading and the banking book (18% of totalassets). First, an analysis is conducted withreference to a one-off and rather milddeterioration in asset quality. This makes itpossible to focus on the different timing withwhich FFVA and the CAF reflect the increase incredit risk in the financial statements. Then aharsher scenario affecting all the instruments issimulated.

3.2.1 ONE-OFF DETERIORATION

In order to simulate a discrete increase in creditrisk, changes in the PDs of mortgage loans,corporate loans and debt securities wereconsidered, using the information availablefrom the QIS3.

Mortgage loans,23 which represent approximately15% of assets, are assumed to have a PD of 0.5%,which is larger than the floor set in Basel II forretail loans (0.3%) and reflects the approximateaverage for retail lending in the QIS3. In addition,the initial LGD is assumed equal to the floor set inBasel II (10%). The deterioration in credit qualitytakes the form of a one-off increase in the PDfrom 0.5% to 1.0%, which can be historicallyconsidered rather mild. The overall impact of thisincrease in credit risk is therefore minor. As soonas the increase in PDs materialises into theimpairment of loans or outright defaults, theoverall effect can be quantified as a loss of 0.04%of total assets and 0.6% of capital and reserves.The final effect would be the same under both

FFVA and the CAF: under FFVA, the value ofthe assets would be revised downwards in orderto reflect the decrease in expected cash flows,while under the CAF a provision for the sameamount would be created as soon as the asset isrecognised as impaired, with exactly the sameeffect on the P&L. The timing of this adjustmentcould, however, differ substantially under the twoaccounting regimes.

Corporate loans, which represent approximately31% of assets, are assumed to start with a PDequal to 1%24 and an LGD of 45%25. For the sakeof simplicity, these are assumed to beuncollateralised bullet loans. The one-offdeterioration in credit quality takes the form of anincrease in the PD to 2%, which can be considereda relatively mild and realistic scenario, consistentwith the results of the QIS3. In this case, the finalimpact would be more substantial and the negativeeffect on the P&L could be estimated at almost3% of capital and reserves. Once debt securities,which account for 18% of the total assets ofour average bank, are also considered, theadditional adverse effect could be quantified at1.3% of capital and reserves. The overall effect ofa decline in credit quality of the magnitude justdescribed would therefore make for a final increasein losses equal to 4.8% of capital and reserves.

Thus far, we have addressed the end period,assuming that the deterioration in asset qualitywould fully materialise. In this case, byconstruction FFVA and the CAF deliver exactlythe same outcome. But the interesting aspect is thedifferent time profile with which the change isrecorded in the bank’s balance sheet. FFVArecognises the deterioration in asset quality assoon as the PDs are revised upwards, even thoughimpairment or default have not yet materialised:the value of the loans is immediately reviseddownwards, as the value of the expected future

23 Mortgage loans are assumed to have an average maturity of tenyears and take the form of annuities. As a reminder, the averagematurity was used, as information on residual maturity was notavailable.

24 The current 8% capital charge approximately equates with a 1%PD when the exposure is uncollateralised.

25 According to QIS 3 results, an LGD of 45% corresponds more orless to the LGD of a senior uncollateralised loan.

Page 19: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

18ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Impact of a one-off mild deteriorationStructure in credit quality

Asset item (% of total assets) on assets on capital & reserves

Mortgage loans 15 -0.0% -0.6%Corporate loans 31 -0.2% -2.9%Debt securities 18 -0.1% -1.3%

Total 64 -0.3% -4.8%

Table 2 Deterioration in credit qual ity under FFVA vs the CAF with default

cash flows decreases, and the decrease is directlytranslated in the P&L accounts. Under the CAF,however, the deterioration becomes visible onlywhen the loans are considered impaired andspecific provisions are created.

Here the crucial point concerns the provisioningbehaviour of the bank under the CAF. If thebank’s provisioning decisions were taken in aperfectly forward-looking manner, i.e. reflectingany change in the expected cash flows, the effectsunder the CAF would be exactly equivalent tothose under FFVA, ceteris paribus (namely ifinterest rates remain constant). If, on the contrary,the bank provisions were mainly backward-looking, there would be a relevant difference withFFVA (see Box 4). It has to be noted, though, thata relevant obstacle to forward-lookingprovisioning comes from present accounting and

tax regulations. In order to limit the possibility formanagement to manipulate financial results,regulations in most countries tend to give a strictinterpretation of the notion of impairment:provisioning is allowed only when the losses havealready materialised or when there is hardevidence that they will materialise soon.

Therefore, FFVA would allow a timelierrecognition of any deterioration in assetquality, which might facilitate the exertion ofpressure by stakeholders and supervisors totake corrective action. From a financialstability perspective, the timelier recognitionunder FFVA is welcome and consistent withprudent accounting recognition principles. Thesooner the problems are detected, the sooner theinstitutions and the regulators can become fullyaware of them and take the necessary actions.

Box 4

CREDIT RISK PROVISIONING AND FAIR VALUE

Under the current accounting framework, credit losses are recognised when it is probable as of thebalance sheet date that some or all contractual payments will not be received. The term “probable”loss is not precisely defined, but is mostly used to mean that the possibility that losses willmaterialise exceeds a certain threshold, generally 50%. Assessments of the probability that somecontractual payments will not be received usually rely upon one or more of the following:(i) information, circumstances or events, regarding the credit quality of an individual loan;(ii) statistical analyses, based on historical experience, concerning credit losses associated with aportfolio of loans; or (iii) the judgement of a bank’s management regarding an individual loan or aportfolio of loans, notably with respect to the evolution of the economic environment.

This concept of loss is attached to the view that a financial statement should reflect events thathave occurred within the reporting period and should not reflect events that have not yetoccurred. This concept is usually designated under the terms of “incurred loss”. The provisionsmade against this risk are thus backward-looking.

Page 20: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

19ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

One drawback of this approach is that it often leads to provisions for loan losses being createdonly after the credit quality of a borrower has already deteriorated substantially and the loan hasbeen assigned a very low internal credit grade, if not classified as defaulted. This can lead toloans being overvalued and profits overstated during periods when loan quality is alreadydeclining, but default rates have not yet started to increase. It also implies that the aggregatelevel of provisions will typically increase only after economic downturns are well under way.

This situation is aggravated if only specific provisions are created. Indeed, the drawback ofbackward-looking provisioning could be alleviated if the individual assessment is supplementedby a group assessment, and general provisions are established when the risk cannot be insulatedand linked to a specified item.

By contrast, the notion of forward-looking provisioning refers to the likelihood of defaultembodied in any loan. Provisions should reflect any change in the probability of default aftertaking into account recovery rates. This approach is very close to the Basel Committee’s viewon expected losses related to the banking book, to the extent that unexpected losses (UL) shouldin principle be compensated for by capital and expected losses (EL) by provisions after theyhave been assessed through the internal ratings-based methods.

The notion of dynamic provisioning can be considered a specific extension of forward-lookingprovisioning, in the sense that it deals with credit risk over the whole life of the loan (in BaselII, the calculation of EL is limited to one year). A provision is created at inception based on thehistorical probability of default until maturity of comparable loans.

Full fair value accounting is forward-looking by nature since it requires the revaluation of an itemwhen there is a change in its market price or, in the absence of a market, in the present value of thestream of revenues generated by the item. Indeed it takes expected loss into account, since achange in risk at any point in the holding period is reflected in a change in the current fair value.

However, the following elements regarding FFVA should be considered when comparing it toforward-looking provisioning:

– FFVA does not take the principle of prudence into consideration since it treats unrealisedprofits and losses similarly. With forward-looking provisioning unrealised gains are notaccounted for, except on liquid instruments recognised in the trading portfolio;

– FFVA does not distinguish between credit risk and other risks (interest rate, currency, etc.)that are not linked to the counterparty;

– Credit risk measurements derived from financial markets, i.e. spreads, are imprecise and canbe influenced by factors other than those directly linked to the counterparty’s credit risk (amore general market risk aversion).

Therefore, as a tentative conclusion, even though FFVA is forward looking, it differssignificantly from forward-looking provisioning with regard to prudence, volatility ofaccounts, accuracy and reliability.

Page 21: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

20ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

On the other hand, if the increase in credit riskis subsequently reversed before the impairmentand defaults take place, then no or limitedimpact would be visible under the CAF, whilethe full downward and upward adjustmentswould be recorded under FFVA.

3.2.2 CUMULATIVE DETERIORATION

In order to assess the impact of a severedecrease in asset quality, a scenario wasdesigned in which credit risk steadily increasedfor five years. The cumulative default rateswere drawn from the long-term averagespublished by Moody’s for the period 1983-1999, assuming a constant value of collateral.The five-year cumulative default rates forcorporate loans was then set at 15.66%,consistent with a credit rating B1 from Moody’s(BB for S&P and Fitch) with an adverseeconomic environment. Following a similarapproach, the cumulative rate for retailmortgage loans was set at 7.48%.

The mechanics of the adjustment is analogous toprevious scenarios, but owing to the severity ofthe deterioration in a five-year time frame, theimpact on capital and reserves is verysignificant. The cumulative loss would reachalmost 50% of capital. Under the balance sheetstructure of our average bank, a yearly return onequity of approximately 10% throughout theperiod would be needed to compensate thiseffect without depleting capital and reserves.

Again, in order to assess the differential impacton bank accounts, it is essential to focus theattention on the time frame for balance sheetadjustments under FFVA and the CAF. Theoverall impact on capital of credit losses, at

Impact of a 5-year cumulative deteriorationStructure in the credit quality of the loan portfolio

Asset item (% of total assets) on assets on capital & reserves

Mortgage loans 15 -0.4% -7.3%Corporate loans 31 -2.5% -40.9%

Total 46 -2.9% -48.1%

Table 3 Severe decrease in the credit qual ity of loan portfol io under FFVA or the CAF withdefault

least, would be the same under both – it is thetiming of the recognition of those changes in theaccounts that differs, and this may have positiveor negative effects. Under FFVA theunexpected downward revision in credit qualitywould be immediately translated into the P&Lsover the entire five-year period. The valueadjustment would in all likelihood be moreforward looking than the present provisioningbehaviour of EU banks. The positiveimplication would be that corrective actioncould be taken earlier, thus preventingmanagement from adopting a passive attitudeand waiting until the storm blew over. Theeffect on volatility may also turn out to be lowerthan under the CAF, if the extreme assumptionis made that provisioning only occurs ex-post,when the losses have already materialised.

On the other hand, two main points can be raised,which question the appropriateness of FFVA inpresence of shocks like the one simulated here.First, it is current practice for rating systems ofbanks to use PDs that are estimated in a point-in-time fashion, taking into consideration at most aone-year horizon. This approach may make sensefrom a risk management perspective, as it allowsinternal ratings to reflect promptly changes incredit risk. However, such estimates, would befed into the valuation of expected cash flows andcould be revised quite frequently. A largeadjustment of the magnitude described abovecould well drive a bank to insolvency, whereastaking a longer-term perspective and consideringthat long-term loans would be kept in theportfolio beyond the crisis period, may cause amore positive picture to emerge. Second, theCAF need not be coupled with backward-lookingprovisioning. If the CAF were to be combinedwith forward-looking provisioning, which takes

Page 22: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

21ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

a through-the-cycle view on PDs based on long-term statistical evidence, buffers would becreated that would shelter the balance sheet froma deterioration in asset quality

All in all, it can be concluded that in presence ofshocks on credit quality FFVA would allow amore timely recognition of the change in therisk environment. FFVA would be moreforward looking than the CAF coupled withbackward provisioning. However, if PDs areestimated at a short-term horizon, FFVA couldalso cause some artificial volatility in bankcapital and the adjustments would remain pro-cyclical. The CAF combined with dynamicprovisioning would, on the contrary, providefor a smoothing of such shocks, via the use ofbuffers accumulated in good times.

3.3 PARALLEL SHIFTS OF THE YIELD CURVE

A parallel shift of 100 basis points, bothupwards and downwards, is considered. Theresults of the simulation here depend cruciallyon the following assumptions: maturity ofassets and liabilities, proportion of variable andfixed rate contracts, and the relative weight ofthe trading and investment books. Assumptionson maturity, in particular, may attributeexcessive relevance to long-term, fixed rateassets, whose value is more sensitive tochanges in interest rates. This could undulymagnify the impact of the shock under FFVA.Another important caveat has to be made: giventhe lack of available data, it was not possible totake into account the use of off-balance-sheetinstruments aimed at hedging interest rate risk,which may play a relevant role in offsetting thechanges reported under FFVA.

The simulated upward shift of the yield curvewould generate losses of a comparablemagnitude under FFVA and the CAF. Thedifference would stem only from the loan book,as under the CAF debt securities in the bankingbook are valued at the lower of cost or marketvalue (LOCOM principle). The valueadjustments, to be reported in the P&L, wouldamount to about 22% of capital and reservesunder both the CAF and FFVA (see tablebelow). This conclusion is dependent on theassumption that the bank is newly established,so that the carrying amount equals the marketvalue immediately prior to the shock. If themarket price before the shock were above thecarrying amount, the CAF would allow theabsorption of part of the adjustment withoutshowing it in the P&L accounts. This leads tothe other conclusion, which shows a muchgreater difference when the yield curve shiftsdownward by 100 basis points. In this case, theprofits generated under FFVA would be twiceas large as those under the CAF (24% of capitaland reserves, compared with 12%).

3.4 IMPACT OF AN INTEREST RATE SHOCK OVERTIME

The results presented in the previous section(and which, as mentioned above, should betreated with caution) show that the volatility ofbank income could significantly increase as aresult of the adoption of FFVA. This is also anexample where the contrast between the netasset value perspective, embodied in FFVA andthe going concern perspective underlying theCAF can be best portrayed. Again, we have totake into account the time dimension of theshock on the bank’s P&L. Assuming that theassets and liabilities affected by the shock are

Impact on assets (%) Impact on capital and reserves (%)Adjustments to yield curve CAF FFVA CAF FFVA

100 bp upward adjustment -1.3 -1.3 -21.8 -22.2100 bp downward adjustment -0.7 -1.4 -12.0 -24.0

Table 4 Paral le l shi fts of the yie ld curve

Page 23: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

22ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

neither sold before maturity nor renewed aftermaturity, FFVA and the CAF will have todeliver exactly the same cumulative impact onthe P&L. The reason is that bonds and loansshow a “pull-to-par” movement, as at maturity(unless the debtor has defaulted earlier) theirmarket value and fair value will have to equalpar value, irrespective of any value changes thatmay have been recorded over their lifetime. Ofcourse, such a convergence effect does notwork for shares held by the bank as they do nothave a maturity and there is no obligation forthe issuers to repay a nominal amount.

The convergence effect implies that, ceterisparibus, any immediate change in the fair value ofsuch bonds and loans as a result of the interestrate shock will be gradually recovered throughoffsetting value adjustments over the remaininglife of the instruments. The following graphmaps the difference through time between profitsand losses under FFVA and the CAF in case of a100 basis point decrease in interest rates. Itshows that the search for a measurementmethodology that refers at any point in time to thenet asset value of the portfolio substantiallyincreases the volatility of income for instrumentsthat are held to maturity, in particular in theperiod immediately after the interest rate shock.It should also be noted that the increase in theportfolio value as a result of the interest ratedecline would immediately show up underFFVA, but not under the CAF, thus leading tothe build-up of unrealised gains in the latter case.

A similar analysis can be performed for ascenario of interest rate increases. Thisbasically leads to a mirror image of the graph,with a large negative difference between the fairvalue and historical value immediately after theinterest rate increase (although the differencebetween FFVA and CFA should be smaller foran interest rate increase given that the value ofthe securities in the banking book will berevised downwards in both FFVA and CFA/LOCOM). The value difference is thenrecovered over the remaining life of theinstruments.

Chart 1 Difference between FFVA and theCAF in the P&L account from a downwardshift in the yield curve of 100 bp(as a % of capital & reserves)

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Years

FFVA-CAF

The earlier scenario of an interest rate decline canbe combined with asset quality deterioration,with interesting results. For instance, if thedeterioration in asset quality coincides with arecession and an alleviation of inflationarypressures, a decrease in interest rates (eventhough this would not occur as the kind ofparallel shift simulated here) might alleviatethe impact of the value adjustments underFFVA. In this case, the CAF with perfectlyforward-looking – but not cyclically adjusted –provisioning might imply a wider correction ofvaluations than under FFVA, as offsetting theinterest rate effect would not be taken intoconsideration.

3.5 REAL ESTATE CRISIS

For the purpose of this exercise, thecomposition of the balance of the average EUbank was modified, and the mortgage portfoliowas replaced by a commercial real estateportfolio. The assumption that commercial realestate represents approximately 15% of totalassets is not as extreme as it might seem, giventhe resemblance with situations prevailing insome EU countries like Ireland and Sweden. Astress scenario similar to those experienced inmajor collapses of real estate markets followedby banking crises (as in the Nordic bankingcrisis) was tentatively designed (focusing

Page 24: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

23ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

solely on the loan book). The reduction incollateral values of the commercial real estateportfolio was factored in through a 50%increase in the LGDs over average valuesreported in the QIS3, and the PDs wereincreased to about 3%. These shocks wereconsidered to occur together with an increase ininterest rates of 300 basis points, which isextreme but still falls short of the increasesexperienced in some countries during actual realestate crises.

The impact of such a shock on the average EUbank would be very substantial and thevaluation effect would play a prominent role, asFFVA would immediately capture the effect of achange in interest rates as well as the downwardadjustment in collateral values. This means thatfrom the very moment at which the shockmaterialises, the bank would experience valueadjustments of such a magnitude as to absorbmore than half of its capital and reserves (54%).Under the CAF, disregarding provisioningbehaviour, no impact would materialise untilactual impairment or default; but also whendefault occurs the effect would be much morelimited (less than half of the FFVA impact, infact), because the interest rate effect would bemissing (see summary table below). This meansthat in a typical real estate crisis scenario, inwhich an increase in interest rates is coupledwith an increased fragility of the borrowersand a decrease in collateral values, FFVA couldactually contribute to accelerating and possiblydeepening the effect of the crisis. In fact, ifinterest rates decrease or collateral valuesrecover somewhat, the valuation effect underFFVA would be reversed only after havinggenerated a capital squeeze that, if it does notdrive the bank out of the market, would in anycase substantially affect its willingness to lend.

However, FFVA’s immediate capturing of theshock and forward-looking nature may allowfor a swifter correction. Under the CAF, eventhe final effect would be more limited, as theinterest rate effect would not be captured.However, under the CAF the subsequentcorrection of banks’ lending behaviour wouldtend to be slower than under FFVA.

3.6 SHARP ADJUSTMENTS IN EQUITY PRICES

Finally, the simulation exercise focused onadjustments in equity prices. The simulationwas based on recent swings, which were largeenough to represent a “stress scenario”: in theperiod between 1999 and 2001 an averageannual increase of 30% and fall of 40% of shareprices took place. Although the equity portfolioonly represents approximately 5% of assets, theimpact that surfaced from the shocks turned outto be substantial, given the magnitude of theprice adjustments.

Under the LOCOM principle that is used in theCAF, the treatment of equity in the bankingbook is asymmetric. Changes bringing the pricebelow cost call for a specific value adjustmentof the instruments and the change directlyaffects the P&L; increases in their marketvalues do not affect the accounting treatment ofthe instruments and do not result in any profits.This means that a major difference betweenFFVA and the CAF will emerge in the case of asharp upward adjustment in stock prices. Infact, the simulation shows that a 30% increasein stock prices would result in profits of about12% of capital and reserves under the CAF,reflecting the adjustment in the trading book,while under FFVA profits would be twice aslarge (24%). Of course, different assumptions

CAFImpact of real estate crisis FFVA Initial moment After default/impairment

On assets 0-3.2 0.0 0-1.6On capital and reserves -53.8 0.0 -26.1

Table 5 Real estate cr i s i s

(%)

Page 25: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

24ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

on the relative weight of the trading andbanking book would deliver different results,but the effect remains striking.

This raises a twofold concern from a financialstability perspective. First, as unrealised gainswill feed into the P&L under FFVA, they may bedistributed and any subsequent downwardcorrection in equity markets could directlyimpact on capital.26 Second, in the oppositecase where profits are not distributed, theincrease in regulatory capital might fuel anincrease in lending and entail a pro-cyclicaleffect.

When considering a significant fall in stockprices, the assumption that the average EU bankconsidered in the analysis is newly establishedmeans that any downward adjustment isconsidered as below cost, and so the treatmentwould be equal under FFVA and the CAF. The

40% downward adjustment would determinelosses of up to 30% of capital and reserves.

However, if we consider a well-establishedbank, the historical upward trend in stock priceswould imply that the equities in the bankingbook were accounted for on the balance sheet ata value substantially lower than current marketvaluations. In other words, the bank would havea substantial amount of unrealised gains (alsoreferred to as “hidden reserves”), which wouldbe larger the longer the average holding period.The evolution of the European stock marketindex (Eurostoxx) could provide an idea of thepotential magnitude of unrealised gains.

Hence, if a bank has unrealised gains, even adownward adjustment of the magnitude

26 Although this concern may be alleviated by the fact that somecountries (e.g. UK) have specific rules on what can and cannot beconsidered as “distributable” profits.

Impact on assets (%) Impact on capital and reserves (%)Price swings CAF FFVA CAF FFVA

30% appreciation in equity prices -0.7 -1.4 -11.7 -23.540% depreciation in equity prices -1.8 -1.4 -29.6 -29.6

Table 6 Adjustments in equity prices

Holding period

Years 15 years 10 years 5 years 3 years

1987 100.001988 72.261989 94.261990 121.081991 92.281992 101.44 100.001993 101.39 99.951994 141.14 139.141995 128.74 126.911996 140.36 138.371997 170.17 167.75 100.001998 233.17 229.86 137.031999 303.36 299.05 178.27 100.002000 418.41 412.47 245.88 137.932001 397.44 391.80 233.56 131.022002 319.05 314.52 187.49 105.17

Table 7 European stock market returns by holding period

Sources: Datastream, Eurostoxx index.

Page 26: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

25ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

3

Full fairvalue accounting

vs the currentaccounting framework:

a simulationexercise on an

average EU bank

described here could have a very differentimpact under FFVA and the CAF. Again,depending on the assumptions on the magnitudeof these unrealised gains and on the relativeweight of the investment and trading book, thelosses under the CAF could be half as large asthose under FFVA. If we consider acompounded shock, with the decrease in stockprices occurring together with an upward shiftin the yield curve affecting fixed income assetsand liabilities, the differential impact of FFVAwith respect to the CAF could even be greater.

The argument concerning unrealised gainspoints to a more general issue. Some EU banks– in particular in countries where the investmentcomponent of the equity portfolio istraditionally large – may have significanthidden reserves, which could be realisedwhenever a shock generates large losses andmarket participants grow worried about thebank’s solvency. In 2001 it was often arguedthat some large German banks were disposingof long-term shareholdings in order to limitlosses caused by deterioration in their loanportfolio and low returns from investments incapital market-related activities. To someextent, this helped regain the confidence ofinvestors and responded to market rumourshinting at more substantial liquidity and evensolvency problems. In the presence of FFVAthis would not have been possible as the profitsresulting from the appreciation of the equityportfolio would have been reported muchearlier. These unrealised gains might havealready been distributed as, in good times,shareholder pressure for higher dividends maybe difficult to resist. This example captures thepoint on intertemporal smoothing discussed inSection 2.2. At the same time, it should also bestressed that unrealised gains do not support aproper functioning of market mechanisms andcould provide bank management with excessivemargins of discretion which may not be usedsolely for the benefit of financial stability. Inorder for market discipline to be effectivelyexercised, investors need to be adequatelyinformed, financial statements transparent andbanks required to hold explicit capital to cover

risks rather than use hidden reserves. To thisend, the disclosure of unrealised gains would beuseful information, which could be provided bybanks in the Annexes to their financialstatements.

* * *

To conclude this section we note that:

– the differential impact of a credit risk shockunder FFVA and the CAF depends on theassumptions on the provisioning behaviourthat would be followed under the CAF. Astatic comparison with the present behaviourof EU banks, which seems to be biased infavour of backward-looking and pro-cyclicalprovisioning, would suggest that a moveto FFVA might actually represent animprovement, as it could be analogous toforward-looking provisioning. However,the CAF coupled with forward-lookingprovisioning would actually deliver betterresults from a financial stability perspective,as it would make it possible to recognisecredit losses in a timely fashion withoutentailing the changes in valuations that underFFVA would be generated by interest ratemovements;

– for other shocks embodying a significantprice component, a major difference betweenFFVA and the CAF would surface. In allcases, concerns emerged that the prematurerecognition of unrealised value changesmight aggravate somewhat the effects of theshock and cause a pro-cyclical impact, eventhough the positive effect via better marketdiscipline and transparency is to beacknowledged;

– the findings on the relevant impact of shiftsin the yield curve, with all the caveats neededto interpret the results, raise importantquestions as to the incentives banks wouldface if confronted with the introduction ofFFVA. In particular, it is likely that theywould take the initiative to reduce theexposure to interest rate risk, and it cannot

Page 27: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

26ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

be ruled out that such initiatives might alsolead to a shortening in the maturity ofloans and/or to a more extensive recourse tovariable rate contracts. As a result, banksmay be pushed to shy away from theirtraditional role, and increasing portions ofliquidity risk and interest rate risk wouldbe transferred to bank customers, i.e.households and corporates, which may beless skilled at managing them;

– FFVA would probably see increasingrecourse to securitisation and other hedgingmechanisms to limit the adverseconsequences on the P&L account. If thiswere the case, FFVA might end up favouringthe increased marketability of presentlyilliquid assets, spreading the risks throughthe financial system and possibly increasingsystemic resilience.

Finally, it should be noted that the simulationexercise does not capture changes in behavioursubsequent to the introduction of FFVA, asbanks would readjust their portfolios in order tominimise the negative affects and betterposition themselves to reap the potentialbenefits. In that respect, it is interesting toanalyse the case of Denmark, which is the EUcountry that has gone furthest in the use of fairvalues – although not extended to the loan book– in order to check whether this has indeedresulted in increased volatility or instability ofthe financial system. The available empiricalevidence shows that Danish accountingprinciples have not resulted in significantincome volatility for banks. Furthermore, recentdata point to what can be considered as lowexposure to interest rate risk of the Danishbanking sector. These results raise the questionof whether banks would increase their hedgingactivity as a consequence of the introduction offair values in order to shelter their balancesheets from undesired volatility, which wouldbe positive from a financial stability point ofview.

Page 28: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

27ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

4

Disclosuresof fair values in

the financial accounts:comparative analysisof major EU banks

According to requirements defined by the USFinancial Accounting Standards Board(Statement of Financial Accounting Standard107, “Disclosures about Fair Value of FinancialInstruments”), companies listed on US marketsshould disclose the estimated fair values of on-and off-balance-sheet financial instrumentswhen it is possible to do so. Compliance withthis requirement therefore furnishes fair-valuedata for a number of EU banks listed in the USon the basis of their financial statements for2000, 2001 and 2002 in which they report fairvalues for all financial instruments. The smallsample of banks considered includes ABNAmro, Barclays Bank, Deutsche Bank, RoyalBank of Scotland, ING, Fortis, and BankAustria Creditanstalt.27

The analysis encompassing a small sample ofbanks was carried out at the individual banklevel, without any data aggregation, in order toavoid smoothing the variability that could stemfrom a different portfolio composition.Attention is focused on the difference in thevaluation of balance sheet items under FFVAand the CAF, in relation to capital and reserves,and on the different changes in fair values andbook values between two years, again showingthe difference between the two in relation tocapital and to total assets. The results show thatFFVA has an important impact on somecomponents of the banks’ portfolios. They alsoshow that such impacts could also varysignificantly across banks.

On the assets side, the impact of FFVA oninterbank lending would be rather modest, eventhough for some banks the use of fair valuesproduces a revaluation, attributable to theembedded interest rate gains on this activity(approximately 4% of capital and reserves). Asexpected, FFVA determines quite a change inthe loan book. Both the absolute magnitude ofthe changes and the variability across banks areextremely relevant. For instance, in 2001 theloan book of Fortis was revalued by more than40% of capital and reserves, followed by animportant downward revision (-15%) in 2002.For some banks fair values are not changing at a

4 DISCLOSURES OF FAIR VALUES IN THEFINANCIAL ACCOUNTS: COMPARATIVE ANALYSISOF MAJOR EU BANKS

pace significantly different from that of bookvalues, nor are they moving in a differentdirection. If all the banks in the sample hadmoved to FFVA in 2002, the profits generatedby loan revaluation would have ranged from 1%to 33% of capital and reserves. This evidencesignals that valuation methods could still differsignificantly. It also confirms that incomevolatility would in all likelihood risesignificantly unless banks changed theirbehaviour when having to measure at fair valuesas opposed to simply disclosing values. Thepicture is varied when looking at securitiesholdings, where the impact is rather significantfor three banks, in particular in the last periodconsidered, but only moderate for the other fourbanks. If one bank (ING) had adopted an FFVAapproach in 2002, the revaluation of thesecurities portfolio would have generatedprofits of up to 49% of capital and reserves.Where derivatives are concerned, however,under the CAF they are recorded as off-balance-sheet items unless held for trading. Hence thechange induced by FFVA is significant.Different accounting treatments of derivativeshamper a proper assessment, but again arelevant impact can be detected for at least twobanks in the sample. If those banks (Barclaysand ING) had adopted FFVA in 2002, therevaluation of their derivatives position wouldhave generated profits of around 18% of capitaland reserves.

On the liabilities side, some interesting effectsare also worth mentioning. For instance, theeffect on deposits and interbank lending wouldbe heterogeneous across banks, with someextreme movement. For instance, Fortis reportsa significant fall in the fair value of depositsbelow book value, stemming from the valuationmethod used for fixed rate deposits. Thisdifference between fair value and book valueamounts to 33% of capital and reserves.

27 The analysis comprises seven banks, five of which are the largestbanks in their home country (as measured by assets). ABN andING are the 1st and 2nd-largest banks in the Netherlands.Barclays is the largest in the UK, Deutsche Bank the largest inGermany, and Fortis and Bank Austria Creditanstalt the largestin Belgium and Austria, respectively.

Page 29: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

28ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Significant changes occur also in the valuationof debt securities and derivatives.

All in all, this simple comparison shows that, ifbanks do not change their behaviour, theintroduction of FFVA could render EU banks’balance sheets more volatile. The effect is notparticularly noticeable when measured vis-à-vistotal assets, but it is definitely not negligiblewhen measured against banks’ shareholders’equity (SHE). In some cases, substantialunrealised gains emerge. This raises thequestion of the use of such value adjustments,as dividend distribution would hamper theability to shelter future downward movements.

FV revaluation2)

as a % of SHE as a % of assetsNet financial assets1) 2002 2001 2000 2002 2001 2000

ABN Amro 32 38 20 1 1 1Barclays 4 8 7 0 0 0Deutsche 5 5 -20 0 0 -1RBS -1 -10 -6 0 -1 0ING 44 28 12 1 1 1Fortis 74 68 -22 2 2 -1Bank Austria Creditanstalt 16 10 9 1 0 0

1) Net financial assets = financial assets - financial liabilities.2) FV revaluation = FV - BV.

Table 8 Fair values versus book values

Page 30: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

29ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

5

Fair valuesand volatility

in share prices

The evidence that FFVA would introducehigher volatility in banks’ balance sheets is not,in itself, a sufficient reason for rejecting thevalidity of the approach. In particular, it may beargued that financial markets could already basetheir valuation on fair values, so that the reformwould only have the benefit of aligning thebalance sheet treatment with the marketvaluations that already guide investmentdecisions. Furthermore, even if the introductionof FFVA were to induce increased volatilityin share prices, investors may well be ableto interpret the relevant developments,disentangling the different sources of volatility.Of course, this hypothesis cannot be properlytested, as FFVA has not been introduced in anycountry. However, some indication, also for EUcountries, can be inferred from the changes inthe valuation methods for the trading books ofbanks.

At the beginning of the 1990s the CapitalAdequacy Directive28 was transposed into thenational legislation of EU countries,introducing the principle that banks’ tradingbooks should be marked-to-market. Anempirical analysis has been conducted with theaim of gauging the impact that a shift fromhistorical cost accounting to FFVA for thetrading book would have on the volatility ofbank share prices (P) in some EU countries. Thesame kind of empirical analysis could inprinciple be carried out to check for changes inthe volatility of earnings. However, banksusually release earnings data on a semi-annualor quarterly basis. Higher-frequency data

5 F A I R VA LU E S AND VO L AT I L I T Y I N S H AR EPR I C E S

(monthly or weekly) are made available bymajor data providers.29 However, these seriesseem to display relevant changes only at timeswhen banks release the data: the intermediatemissing points are filled in using aninterpolation technique, but they seem to lackeconomic content. Any exercise aimed atcomputing the volatility of banks’ earnings pershare with monthly or weekly frequency willthus not be possible. Moreover, the sample size(especially for the period before the adoption ofthe FVA) is not sufficiently large to carry outthe analysis on low-frequency data.

The analysis is based on weekly bank equityindices30 for five EU countries: France,Germany, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom.For each country both individual bank data anda sector index are considered, except for Francewhere the lack of data means that only the sectorindex can be used. The sample period variesfrom each country, according to dataavailability. Whenever possible, the analysis iscarried out from January 1973 to January 2004.Subject to data availability, the banks with thehighest market capitalisation included innational bank equity indices have been chosen.For each country the date of when the EUCapital Adequacy Directive was transposed intonational legislation was identified (see Box 5).

28 Council Directive 93/6/EEC, enacted on 15 March 1993.Nevertheless, changes in accounting regulations concerning thetreatment of so-called held-for-trading securities had alreadybeen implemented in some of Member States.

29 Thomson Financial Datastream, for example.30 As provided by Datastream.

Box 5

WHEN DID BANKS START TO MARK-TO-MARKET THEIR TRADING BOOKS?

The empirical analysis of banks’ share volatility depends critically on the date at which thechange in accounting regulation was carried out in each country. In principle, a distinction couldbe made between the de jure and de facto change in accounting standards, i.e. distinguishingbetween when a new regulation was introduced in the country’s legal framework and when thebanks actually started to adopt the new standards. For the purpose of this study it was generallyaccepted that major banks (such as the ones included in the indices) would adopt the new

Page 31: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

30ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

regulations as soon as possible, i.e. starting the next fiscal year. The dates were chosen asfollows.

In France, the accounting trading book was created by regulation at the beginning of 1990, andthus a dummy variable was introduced starting in January 1991. In Germany, accountingregulations demand valuation at historical costs of banks’ assets and liabilities. However,Paragraph 252 (2) of the German Commercial Code, which was introduced in 1991, allowsexceptions to this general principle and thus prompted the development of fair valuemeasurement for banks’ trading books. A dummy variable was introduced in January 1992. InSpain, the held-for-trading category of securities, which could be valued using market values,was introduced in accounting regulations in September 1989; thus the dummy variable has avalue of 1 starting in January 1990. In Italy the same definition was introduced in 1992 and thedummy variable takes the value of 1 starting from January 1993. In the United Kingdom, theBritish Bankers Association Statements of Recommended Practice (BBA SORP) was the firstformal guidance recommending that trading book securities be marked-to-market. It was issuedin 1990, with banks encouraged to adopt its recommendations as soon as practicable or in thefirst accounting period beginning on or after January 1993 at the latest. However, it was alreadycommon practice for banks with major securities trading operations (since the Stock Exchange“Big Bang” of 1986) to use market valuations. Thus, the empirical study has been carried outusing two different dummy variables, the first one starting in January 1987 and the second onestarting in January 1991.

After computing returns as the log differencesof two consecutive price index observations, aGeneralised Autoregressive ConditionalHeteroskedasticity (GARCH) model is fitted oneach series32. This makes it possible to estimatetheir time-varying volatilities. Within thiseconometric framework a dummy variable isused to test whether there was a significant

increase in volatility following the adoption offair values for the trading book. In addition, acontrol variable for the total market volatility isintroduced, also modelled using a GARCHprocess (see Box 6).

Box 6

EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY

This box describes the methodology used to test whether the change in the accounting standardsconcerning the reporting of financial instruments has had an impact on the volatility of banks’share prices.

The empirical analysis is carried out on logarithmic differences of banks’ price indices, (Pi,t),including dividends, where i = l,...,n represents the ith asset under consideration. Logdifferences in P’s makes it possible to compute (compounded) total returns, ri,t.

First, a test is run to determine whether the returns process can be explained by autoregressiveand moving average components. If the coefficients associated with these terms aresignificantly different from zero, they are included among the explanatory variables, otherwisethey are discarded from the mean equation.

32 Since equity price indices are non-stationary time series,empirical analysis is carried out on returns since these arestationary series.

Page 32: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

31ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

5

Fair valuesand volatility

in share pricesThe mean equation for returns can be written as follows:

(1) t,iqt,iq,it,i,ipt,ip,it,i,i,it,i bbraraar ���������������

�� 11110 .

Error terms �i,t’s are assumed to have zero mean and a time-varying variance, hi,t. The adoptedvariance process, (which turns out to be the variance of returns), is conditional on a time-varying information set and, as such, is updated as long as new information becomes available.Therefore it takes into account the events that affect equity markets. The linear GeneralisedAutoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (GARCH) model originally proposed by Engle(1982) and Bollerslev (1986) is used:

(2) 12

1 ��

������� t,iit,iiit,i hh .

This form of the GARCH model, however, is not able to capture the so-called asymmetricvolatility phenomenon. Typically volatility tends to increase more after negative return shocksthan after positive return shocks of the same magnitude. Two different models, the leverageeffect hypothesis (Black, 1976, and Christie, 1982) and the volatility feedback effect (Campbelland Hentschell, 1992) can help to explain this phenomenon. The leverage effect states that afteran unexpected decrease in the equity value the debt-to-equity ratio of a firm tends to increase.This, in turn, will induce an increase in the riskiness (volatility) of equities which will surge aswell. An alternative explanation is that after a negative shock and the consequent increase inequities variance, the expected return must become sufficiently high to compensate the investorfor the increased volatility. This movement in prices will thus in itself create more volatility(volatility feedback). These two explanations for asymmetries in volatility are not mutuallyexclusive, and can be at work at the same time (see also Bekaert and Wu, 2000).

In order to take into account the asymmetry effect, equation (2) is therefore enriched with anadditional term (see Glosten, Jagannathan and Runkle, 1993, and Zakoian, 1994) as shown inequation (3):

(3) � � 12

112

1 0����

������������ t,iit,it,iit,iiit,i hIh .

The indicator function I(�i,t < 0) is equal to one if �i,t is negative, and equal to zero otherwise.Assume that � i turns out to be positive (negative). When � i,t is negative, I(� i,t < 0) is equal toone and volatility actually goes up (down). Conditional volatility, instead, does not change forpositive innovations, since I(� i,t < 0) will be equal to zero.

Now assume that at a certain point in time, �, with � < t, the accounting requirements for thedisclosing of financial assets changes. This change may be reflected in the variance hi,t. Thishypothesis can be tested by checking whether the intercept of the GARCH model changes withparallel shifts. Therefore the conditional variance represented in equation (3) is further modifiedas follows:

(4) � � 12

112

121 0����

�������������� t,iit,it,iit,iit,ii,i,t,i hIdh ,

where di,t represents a dummy variable which takes on value zero for � < t, i.e. before the changein the accounting standards, and value one otherwise, i.e. for the whole period after the change

Page 33: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

32ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

has occurred. If �2,i is significantly different from zero, then this will indicate that the processgoverning volatility has changed.

To check for possible changes in the intercept attributable to changes in the volatility of thewhole market, the GARCH process (4) is modified as follows:

(5) � � t,mit,iit,it,iit,iit,ii,i,t,i hhIdh ������������������� 1

211

2121 0 ,

where hm,t is the time varying variance associated with the whole market m. Equation (5) isjointly tested with the mean equation (1) to asses the impact of a change in accounting standardson banks’ return volatility.

The variance for the whole market, hm,t, is calculated using a procedure similar to that used forhi,t. First, the returns on the whole market index are computed, and are then modelled in linewith equation (1). Second, error terms are assumed to follow a GARCH process similar to thatof equation (3). Finally, hm,t is recovered and plugged into equation (4).

For each country the empirical analysis iscarried out on an aggregate bank index and/orindividual bank indices. For each time series,two different equations are estimated: onecontains as a control variable the whole marketvariance while the other does not. The fourthcolumn in the following table showscoefficients of the dummy variables whichindicate whether there has been a switch involatility after the adoption of the FFVAstandards. P-values are reported in parentheses.T-statistics are shown in the last column.

In general, several different components areused for the valuation of equity prices. Apartfrom the well-known relationship betweencurrent stock prices and a combination ofexpected future dividends and stock returns,the valuation of a stock price index for banksmay also depend on the accounting standards.With historical cost accounting, asset valuationshave to rely on inferences regarding some itemsin the banks’ balance sheets. This willinevitably increase the uncertainty associatedwith those items. On the other hand, underFFVA this type of uncertainty does not play anyrole in asset valuation. At the same time,however, fair value may result in the increasedvolatility of future cash flows. Therefore, when

accounting standards change from the CAF toFFVA, the overall effect on the volatility ofbanks’ equity returns is uncertain. Moreover, asargued at the beginning of this section, sinceinvestors may base their valuations on fairvalues independently of the accountingstandards, it would not be surprising to observenegligible changes in volatility when movingfrom one accounting regime to another.

Empirical evidence shows that the change involatility of returns is almost never significantexcept for IKB in Germany, Banco Santander inSpain and Standard Chartered in the UnitedKingdom. Where bank indices are concerned,only the UK index is sensitive to the change inaccounting standards. Controlling for themarket returns does not improve significance.

These results need to be interpreted withcaution for at least three different reasons.First, the choice of the cut-off dates at whichbanks changed from one accounting standard tothe other is far from clear-cut. Banks in thesame country may have started to implement fairvaluations of financial assets at different timesand for a different set of instruments. Second,towards the end of the 1980s and at thebeginning of the 1990s the relative weight of

Page 34: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

33ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

5

Fair valuesand volatility

in share pricesControl for the Coefficients of dummy

Countries market variables t-stats

Germany Deutsche Bank yes 0.20 1.62(0.11)

no 0.12 1.66(0.10)

HypoVereinsbank yes 1.14 1.38(0.17)

no 1.13 1.35

(0.18)

Commerzbank yes 0.13 0.54(0.59)

no 0.17 1.25(0.21)

IKB yes -3.29 -3.66(0.0)

no 0.43 -2.00(0.05)

Bankgesellschaft Berlin yes 0.07 0.18(0.86)

no 0.07 0.19(0.85)

Bank Index yes 0.10 0.87(0.38)

no 0.07 1.47(0.14)

Spain Banco Santander yes 1.00 2.40(0.02)

no 1.04 2.81(0.0)

Bankinter yes -1.24 -1.22(0.22)

no -1.36 -0.85(0.39)

BBV Argentaria yes 0.43 0.87(0.38)

no 0.45 0.92(0.36)

Bank Index yes 0.18 1.03(0.30)

no 0.15 0.66(0.50)

United Kingdom Bank of Scotland yes (since 1987) -0.73 -1.10(0.27)

yes (since 1991) -0.38 -0.83(0.41)

no (since 1987) 0.73 -1.48(0.14)

no (since 1991) -0.52 -1.47(0.14)

Barclays Bank yes (since 1987) 0.50 1.00(0.32)

yes (since 1991) 0.79 1.52(0.13)

no (since 1987) -0.05 0.26(0.79)

no (since 1991) -0.13 -0.71(0.48)

Table 9 Results of the FVA analysis using GARCH models for the volat i l ity of returns

Page 35: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

34ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

the trading book – to which the FFVA standardapplied – vis-à-vis the overall stream of incomewas relatively modest. Finally, even thoughvolatility had increased significantly andpermanently after the adoption of the FFVA, itwould be important to analyse to what extentinvestors priced in this incremental volatility inthe context of an asset pricing model. Thiswould make it possible to check whether thehigher variability embodies, from the investors’point of view, information about additionalrisk. The lack of a significant change in the risk

premium would indicate that investors interpretthe additional variation as being in line with thenew reporting requirements. Therefore, theadditional volatility would not lead to a re-allocation of capital away from the bank’sequity. Further investigation is thus needed toaddress the aforementioned points.

Table 9 Results of the FVA analysis using GARCH models for the volati l ity of returns (cont’)

Control for the Coefficients of dummyCountries market variables t-stats

United Kingdom STD Chartered yes (since 1987) 15.60 4.56(0.00)

yes (since 1991) 0.88 1.85(0.06)

no (since 1987) 0.84 1.12(0.26)

no (since 1991) 0.30 0.77(0.44)

Abbey Bank yes (since 1991) 0.47 1.46(0.14)

no (since 1991) -0.08 -0.50(0.62)

Bank Index yes (since 1987) 2.01 1.91(0.05)

yes (since 1991) 2.34 2.14(0.03)

no (since 1987) 0.11 0.66(0.50)

no (since 1991) 0.02 0.14(0.88)

Italy Banca Intesa yes -1.00 -0.82(0.41)

no -0.88 -0.77(0.44)

Unicredito Italiano yes 0.31 0.82(0.41)

no 0.32 0.93(0.35)

Capitalia yes 2.47 1.79(0.07)

no 0.35 0.57(0.57)

Bank Index yes -0.25 -1.50(0.13)

no -0.27 -1.54(0.12)

France Bank Index yes 0.10 0.46(0.64)

no 0.08 0.41(0.68)

Page 36: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

35ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

6

IAS 39:consistency with

market practices,supervisory tools

and statisticalrequirements

6.1 CONCERNS REGARDING HEDGING ACTIVITIES

Until now, the analysis of the effects of FFVAon financial stability has been conducted bycomparing the full fair value for all financialinstruments to the present setting, checkingwhether the potential move to FFVA couldcreate adverse effects on financial stability. Inthis section the focus will be shifted to theimpact of IAS 39, which can be understood as apartial application of fair value accounting.Indeed, IAS 39 includes a proposal which givesinstitutions the possibility to irrevocably applyfair valuations to any financial instrument atinception – the so-called “fair value option”.32

An important improvement of IAS 39 relates tothe issue of the comprehensiveness of financialaccounts, since these should provide a completepicture of the reporting company. One of the keyareas in which the proposals of the IASB providea significant improvement over the CAF regimeis the recognition on the balance sheet ofbusiness that is now recorded onlyoff-balance sheet, in particular derivativestransactions. There is an increasing awarenessthat the risk exposures of financial intermediariescannot be appropriately assessed in the absenceof reliable and comparable information onderivatives business. It is now well known thatderivative contracts can be used not only to hedgerisks but also to increase leverage, and theresulting increase in risk needs to beappropriately recognised on the balance sheet(see Box 7). Furthermore, the increased recourseto credit risk transfers has raised questions as tothe effective redistribution of risks throughoutthe financial system.

A mixed accounting framework introducesartificial volatility in reported earnings that onlyincompletely reflects the economic hedgingstrategies of the reporting company and thuswould not mirror the overall reduction in therisk exposure. Under FFVA, hedging activitieswould not represent a particular problem, asboth the hedged and the hedging instrumentswould be fair valued. Changes in oppositedirections would be automatically offset and

6 IAS 39: CONSISTENCY WITH MARKET PRACTICES,SUPERVISORY TOOLS AND STATISTICALREQUIREMENTS

only the net change in value would be reflectedin the P&L. However, under the present mixedsystem a problem arises, as derivativeinstruments are commonly used to hedge risksstemming from assets and liabilities that arevalued at their historical values. Hence, in theabsence of specific treatment, changes in therelevant risk factor would only be reflected inthe value of the derivative, which would be fairvalued, and not in the hedged instrument. Thiswould introduce artificial volatility in bankprofits. In addition, it would not reflect the riskmanagement tools that are applied by banks andwould fail to provide a clear and consistentpicture of the risks involved.

Hence, a specific accounting treatment – “hedgeaccounting” – was devised in order to addressthis issue. Hedge accounting either defers orbrings forward the recognition of gains andlosses in the profit and loss account so that thegain or loss from the hedged instrument isrecognised at the same time as the offsettinggain or loss from the hedging instrument.

In this context, IAS 39 defines two types ofhedges, the fair value hedge, which protectsagainst fluctuations in the value of balance sheetitems, and the cash flow hedge, which protectsfuture revenues or transactions. Changes in valueof fair value hedges must be recognised in theincome statement for both the hedged item andthe hedging instrument, while changes in valueof cash flow hedges, concerning the hedginginstrument only, are taken to equity.

Initially, the IASB envisaged the application offair value hedge accounting only at the microlevel (i.e. instrument by instrument). Inresponse to concerns of the banking industry,however, amendments were proposed in August2003 to allow for fair value hedge accountingfor portfolio hedges of interest rate risk (so-

32 It should be noted, however, that the IASB is currently revisingthis standard in order to introduce a confined application of thefair value option to a specific set of financial instruments. On21 April 2004, the IASB issued an “Exposure Draft of proposedamendments to IAS 39 Financial Instruments: Recognition andmeasurement the fair value option”, with a 90 day current period.

Page 37: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

36ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Box 7

THE POTENTIAL IMPACT OF OFF-BALANCE-SHEET ITEMS ON INTEREST RATE RISK EXPOSURES: ANEXAMPLE FROM BELGIUM

The figure below represents the report in which the assets and liabilities of all Belgian bankshave been assigned to ten different time bands according to their remaining time-to-repricing(December 2003, source: Belgian Prudential Regulatory Scheme A, Banking and FinanceCommission).

When restricting our attention to on-balance-sheet assets and liabilities only, we observe thatnet assets are typically negative at the short end and positive at the long end, implying thatBelgian banks act as maturity and liquidity transformers.

When we take the net off-balance-sheet positions into account (e.g., options, forward rateagreements, interest rate swaps), we conclude that the total net exposure of banks across time-to-repricing time bands is affected. The effect over different time bands varies greatly. Inparticular, net off-balance-sheet positions seem to partially reduce all time band imbalances thatexist at the long end of the time-to-repricing curve. While the impact is not extremely large, itshould be noted that these are total mismatches over all Belgian banks, and the effects might bemore significant were we to focus on an individual bank. At the short end, the impact is lessconsistent, although off-balance-sheet net positions can clearly be seen to increase theimbalance in time band “1 to 3 months”.

Of course, the figure below only yields a first-order approximation of the impact of off-balance-sheet instruments on the interest rate risk exposure. More specifically, the exercise might besensitive to underlying assumptions and data limitations. First, the time band data does not

On- and off-balance sheet posit ions according to the residual term to the next interest ratereview date

(EUR billions)

-300

-250

-200

-150

-100

-50

0

50

100

150

200

-300

-250

-200

-150

-100

-50

0

50

100

150

200

indeterminate < 8D >8D, < 1M

>1M, < 3M

> 3M, < 6M

> 6M, < 1Y

> 1Y, < 2Y

> 2Y, < 5Y

> 5Y, < 10Y

> 10Y

assets December 2003off-balance-sheet net position December 2003on-balance-sheet net position December 2003liabilities December 2003overall net position December 2003

Page 38: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

37ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

6

IAS 39:consistency with

market practices,supervisory tools

and statisticalrequirements

make it possible to distinguish between trading and banking book positions. Second,imbalances within a given time band do not surface. Third, the positions are reported on a solobasis, meaning that the consolidated balance sheet might look different. Fourth, optionpositions are included at their delta value. Fifth, savings deposits may be assigned to certaintime bands according to their effective or behavioural maturity, instead of being classified intothe indeterminate time band. Sixth, all positions in foreign currencies were converted into euroand added up (without allowing for compensations). Seventh, options risks in savings depositsand prepayment risks in loans are not taken into account.

called “macro-hedges”), which would movecloser to banks’ prevailing risk managementpractices. Indeed, in most European countriesthis management technique is used as a basis forthe hedging accounting treatment, allowing thebank to recognise the effect of this technique inthe accounts.

IAS 39 also stipulates that derivativeinstruments may be used as hedginginstruments, and requires all derivativefinancial instruments to be measured at fairvalue. The application of these measurementrules leads to differences in treatmentdepending on the nature of the financialinstrument as opposed to management intent. Inaddition, the choice between using a fair valuehedge and a cash flow hedge in economicallyequivalent situations would render verydifferent impacts on net income or equity.

The accounting treatment of banks’management of interest rate risk that involves

macro-hedges needs further consideration. Ineconomic terms, it does not matter whether aderivative instrument is considered a fair valuehedge or a cash flow hedge, while IAS 39imposes different requirements for therecognition under the two types of hedgeaccounting. Concerns have been raised thatportfolio hedging strategies, which form part ofbanks’ risk management strategies, wouldeither be not at all recognised in hedgeaccounting, thus giving rise to volatile P&Lstatements, or would only qualify for cash flowhedge accounting. Cash flow portfolio hedgeaccounting requires banks to measure thehedging instrument (the financial derivative) atfair value, with resulting changes in its valuedebited or credited in equity. Through time thisequity item will be gradually recycled in P&L.Hence, this accounting treatment results inincreasingly volatile equity positions. Somebanks expressed their concern that cash flowhedging would generate “artificial volatility” inequity (see Box 8).

Box 8

CASH FLOW HEDGE VERSUS FAIR VALUE HEDGE: IMPACT ON THE BALANCE SHEET

The following example provides a comparison of the potentially differing impacts of applyingcash flow hedge accounting treatment or fair value hedge accounting treatment. The exampleuses a simplified balance sheet. The following additional assumptions were made:

– concerning the contractual maturities and repricing dates schedule. Period 2 is three years(duration 2.5) and Period 3 is five years (duration 4.5);

– all deposits are demand deposits, reimbursed on demand or in a brief period of time and havethe following expected (behavioural) maturities: 800 for period 1; 1,100 for period 2 and5,600 for period 3;

Page 39: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

38ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

– demand deposits bear a 0% interest rate;

– hedging instruments are financial derivatives which constitute a perfect hedge;

– the entity successively invests the amounts of demand deposits at a short-term horizon withshort-term interest rates.

It should be noted that the IASB has established that demand deposits cannot qualify for fairvalue hedge accounting beyond the shortest period in which the counterparty can demandpayment. Demand deposits constitute a significant part of banks’ liabilities, usually bearing anull or a very low interest rate, which can be considered as a fixed rate.

Many banks manage interest rate risk by referring to behavioural maturities. In the followingtable the assets and liabilities are set in the timing schedule according to their expectedmaturities, which is relevant for risk management purposes. In this example, the timing of thedeposits has been modified. Indeed, while individual demand deposits are seemingly veryvolatile, taken aggregately they have historically proved to be fairly stable.

Contractual maturitiesBalance sheet Period 1 Period 2 Period 3

Loans to customersShort-term 3,500 3,500Medium & long-term - variable rate 1,750 300 300 1,150Medium & long-term - fixed rate 1,750 500 300 950

Mortgage loans 3,000 300 300 2,40010,000 5,550 900 3,550

Deposits 7,500 7,500Interbank lending 1,500 1,500Equity (capital+ reserves) 1,000 1,000

10,000 9,000 0 1,000

Note: Figures in euro.

Table A Balance sheet with contractual maturit ies

Note: Figures in euro.

Expected maturitiesBalance sheet Period 1 Period 2 Period 3

Loans to customersShort-term 3,500 3,500Medium & long-term – variable rate 1,750 300 300 1,150Medium & long-term – fixed rate 1,750 500 300 950

Mortgage loans – fixed 3,000 300 300 2,40010,000 4,600 900 4,500

Deposits 7,500 800 1,100 5,600Interbank lending 1,500 1,500Equity (capital + reserves) 1,000 1,000

10,000 2,500 1,100 6,600

Table B Balance sheet with expected maturit ies

Page 40: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

39ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

6

IAS 39:consistency with

market practices,supervisory tools

and statisticalrequirements

Cash-flow hedgeBalance sheet (CFH)

Loans to customersShort-term 3,500.0Medium & long-term – variable rate 1,750.0Medium & long-term – fixed rate 1,750.0

3,000.0Total assets 10,000.0

Deposits 7,500.0Interbank lending 1,500.0Swap – Period 2 27.5Swap – Period 3 252.0

Equity (capital + reserves) 1,000.0 720.5of which:

Initial equity 1,000.0Other comprehensive income – Swap – Period 2 -27.5Other comprehensive income – Swap – Period 3 -252.0

P&L (Net income) 0.0Total liabilities & equity 10,000.0

Impact on equity -28.0%Impact on P&L 0.0%

Table C Impact on the balance sheet from the casch f low hedge

Demand deposits create risk for the interest rate margin. The interest rate margin wouldfluctuate between the short rate market rates and a fixed rate, thus resulting in exposure tointerest rate risk. In order to hedge this risk, banks enter into swaps paying the short-termfloating rate and receiving the fixed rate.

As can be seen in the preceding table, the bank is liability-sensitive in Periods 2 and 3. According tothe IAS 39 framework, hedging of net risk positions is not allowed. To hedge the interest ratemargin risk resulting from demand deposits it is assumed that the bank will enter into two swaps of1,100 and 5,600. The swaps are only recorded off-balance sheet at inception and have nil value.

If, subsequently, interest rates increase by 100 basis points, the fair value of the swaps wouldchange as follows:Period 2 swap: 27.5 (1,100*0.01*2.5)Period 3 swap: 252.0 (5,600*0.01*4.5)

Recognition under cash flow hedge accounting:

The hedging instrument is measured at fair value, and changes are recognised in equity. Hence,with the changes in interest rates the change in fair value of the swap is recognised along withthe consequent accounting loss recognised in equity. The balance sheet would be as follows:

In this situation, the increase in interest rates of 100 basis points would reduce equity by almost30%.

Page 41: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

40ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

Any accounting rules that result in volatileequity positions in banks should be carefullyconsidered. Market price volatility may feedinto volatile equity positions, which may triggersupervisory action if minimum requirements arenot met. In case of temporary price movements,such consequences of accounting rules forbanking supervision might have a pro-cyclicaleffect in that market volatility and supervisoryaction would be linked in an automatic way.This would clearly be undesirable.

The main concern about the new proposals onmacro-hedge accounting relates to the treatmentof demand deposits.33 Indeed the proposed newaccounting rules on macro-hedging do not allowdemand deposits to qualify for fair value hedgeaccounting. Clearly, for depositors the value ofdemand deposits is the nominal value.However, the behavioural maturity of coredeposits differs from their contractual maturityand banks tend to take this into consideration intheir risk management practices. Even thoughsight deposits are redeemable on demand, theyare typically stable liabilities under a “goingconcern” scenario. The liquidity transformationrole of banks stems from their ability to collectfunds from a very disparate set of savers. Thisminimises the likelihood of a sudden andcontemporaneous withdrawal of funds, whichwould only arise in the event of panic orsystemic crises. The latter are normallyaddressed by other tools (including depositinsurance and emergency liquidity assistance),which make it possible to “lock in” the funds inilliquid investments. In the management ofinterest rate risk, therefore, banks tend to usebehavioural maturities for deposits, in order tohedge only the residual risk. Of course thisdoes not mean that banks should be left withabsolute discretion in their decisions on thematurity allocation of deposits. Some criteria,consistent across credit institutions, wouldneed to be developed. In this respect,convergence would best be achieved betweenthe supervisory principles for the managementof interest rate risk and the criteria defined byaccounting standard-setters. Cooperationbetween the IASB and the Basel Committee on

Banking Supervision could appropriately leadin this direction.

It is frequently argued that the introduction inthe US of accounting principles akin to thoseembedded in IAS 39 has not created majorproblems. However, the greater relevance ofdemand deposits in the EU vis-à-vis the US (seeBox 9) suggests that the effect on EU banks’practices merits further consideration.

The draft of IAS 39 also introduced an optionenabling any financial instrument to bedesignated at origination for measurement atfair value. The introduction of the fair valueoption does not seem justified purely ontransparency grounds. First, no mechanism isforeseen in the draft exposure to ensure that fairvalues are reliably measured. The total freedomleft to financial intermediaries to choose whichinstruments to fair value, coupled with the lackof oversight on the valuation models adopted,would adversely affect the information contentof financial statements. Second, because of theunreliability of fair values as well as the veryfact that not all institutions would use fairvaluations – for a limited and heterogeneous setof instruments – the comparability of balance-sheet information across financial institutionscould be severely jeopardised. Moreover, froma broader perspective, comparability at theinternational level could also be compromised,as there is no such option available under USGAAP. From the financial stability viewpoint,the implications of the fair value option dependon the extent to which the option would be used.The absence of any control over the processmust be of concern, as some banks may bepressed by institutional investors, ratingagencies and market analysts to graduallyextend the area of instruments to be fair valued,and this could lead other banks to follow suit.The move towards FFVA could thereforeproceed unchecked, driven by agents that arenot best placed to fully appreciate the

33 Deposits can only qualify for fair value hedge accounting beyondthe shortest period in which the counterparty can demandpayment.

Page 42: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

41ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

6

IAS 39:consistency with

market practices,supervisory tools

and statisticalrequirements

Box 9

STRUCTURAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN THE US AND EU BANKING SECTORS1

Underlying structural differences between the US and European banking sectors haveinfluenced the current debate regarding the new accounting rules set forth in IAS 39, namelypertaining to the wider application of fair values and the treatment of demand deposits.

First, the US financial system can be characterised as market-based, while the EU is more bank-based. Indeed, the total lending business of deposit-taking banks ascends to about 130% ofGDP in Europe, while it represents merely 20% of US GDP. Thus, lending is more importantfor European banks and one of the major limitations of applying fair value accounting is the lackof reliability of loan valuations. Moreover, while in the euro area the total size of the equity andbond market is roughly comparable to the amount of deposits, it is eight times larger in theUnited States. Considerable core demand deposits exist and are a fundamental characteristic ofthe European banking sector. These deposits remain on the balance sheet for longer periods,even when they are legally available to the depositors on demand or at very short notice. Theyare in this sense equivalent to long-term savings and are treated as such by banks, in accordancewith sound interest rate risk management techniques as explained in the consultative documentof the Basel Committee Principles for the Management and Supervision of Interest Rate Risk.

Second, the rate of savings is relatively low in the United States, not exceeding 3%, while itfluctuates around 12% in Europe. The savings market is also more disintermediated in theUnited States than in Europe. Indeed, Americans invest their savings in stocks and mutual fundswhile Europeans visit their banks to invest in fixed-income products (savings accounts andlong-term certificates of deposits). This explains why European banks have extra resources.This surplus, which is much larger than for American banks, is mostly reinvested in bonds.Therefore, European banks are more vulnerable than American banks to the use of market valuesto assess their investment portfolios. The securities/equity ratio is around 200% for the fivemajor US deposit banks, while it fluctuates between 600% and 1,200% for several Europeanbanks.

Fourth, other differences between the EU and US banking sectors include the average durationof the loan book, assets books and the degree of securitisation. In this respect, European banks’balance sheets are more interest rate-sensitive than those of their American counterparts.

1 Bikker, J.A. and Wesseling, A.A.T., “Intermediatie, integratie en internationalisering: een overzicht van het Europese bankwezen”(Intermediation, integration, and internationalisation: an overview of the European banking system), De Nederlandsche Bank, MonthlyEconomic Bulletin, 67, 2003.

Page 43: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

42ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

potentially adverse implications from afinancial stability perspective.

6.2 SUPERVISORY CONCERNS

Several supervisory concerns have beenexpressed with reference to the introduction ofFFVA for banks. Many of the points raisedrelate to the concerns that the volatility of bankincome might increase substantially, a point thathas also been discussed in previous sections.Furthermore, the following additional concernsof supervisors should be mentioned.

The first refers to the compatibility of FFVAwith dynamic provisioning. Some supervisoryauthorities have recently introduced or areconsidering introducing regulations ondynamic (or statistical) provisioning, whichwould be determined in accordance withstatistically expected losses as opposed to theincurred loss model. The objective is to reducethe cyclicality of loan loss provisions by way oftimelier provisioning when credit qualitydeteriorates. This approach graduallyrecognises the increase in risk and spreads thecost over a longer period, thus cushioning theimpact from loan impairment losses that arerecognised in a single accounting period.

The compatibility of such a supervisoryapproach with FFVA – which in principlewould eliminate any need for specificprovisions as it already embodies expectedlosses in the definition of expected cash flows –is not clear. However, more forward-lookingprovisioning seems to be compatible with thecurrent text of IAS 39.34

The second concern directly relates to the issueof compatibility between the accountingtreatment and the supervisory requirements oncapital adequacy being defined in the New BaselAccord. This issue is, of course, essential asrisk management systems in place for reportingpurposes should be deemed appropriate from asupervisor’s point of view. Furthermore,misalignments between the two approaches

would determine the need for banks to runparallel reporting systems, unduly increasingcompliance costs. The Basel Committee onBanking Supervision has started a dialoguewith the IASB on this topic.

Moreover, this compatibility issue with theNew Basel Accord raises an additional concernfrom a financial stability perspective. Thealmost contemporaneous implementation of thenew capital requirements and of FFVA, at leastfor some items, might lead to a cumulative pro-cyclical effect . Several commentators on theNew Basel Accord, including the ECB, havestressed that the increased risk-sensitivity ofthe new framework may cause capitalrequirements to become binding duringdownturns, with an adverse effect on the banks’willingness to lend that may contribute tofurther postponing economic recovery. If theincrease in credit risk is also coupled with adownward correction in asset prices, banks thatare requested to apply FFVA more extensivelymay be subject to a double squeeze, as thecapital requirement would increase while theprofits would be pushed downwards on accountof the valuation effect. This interaction shouldbe studied in greater depth before thefinalisation of the two reforms, in order toidentify possible solutions.

Last but not least, a point that ranks high amongsupervisory concerns is the treatment of owncredit risk. Under FFVA a decline in thecreditworthiness of a bank would translate intoa requirement for higher risk spreads by theinvestor. If the bank is asked to discount itsliabilities using its current funding rate, whichseems to be the preferred solution of accountingstandard-setters, a higher risk margindetermines a lower present (or fair) value. Sincethis lower value is on the liabilities side of thebalance sheet, this translates in the P&L accountinto a profit that, if not distributed, is added toequity reserves (assuming assets constant).Supervisors find it counter-intuitive that a

34 Matherat, S., 2003, “International accounting standardisation andf inancial stability”, Financial Stability Review, Banque deFrance, June, pp. 132-153.

Page 44: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

43ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

6

IAS 39:consistency with

market practices,supervisory tools

and statisticalrequirements

decline in the creditworthiness of the bankwould translate into a profit and add up tocapital, thus allowing for a further expansion oflending. The approach of standard-setters iscorrect as long as things are viewed from theshareholders’ perspective or in the event of abankruptcy or failure. Indeed, under limitedliability an increase in the default risk increasesthe value of the shareholders’ put option.However, it takes no account of the creditors,who would be negatively affected by such adevelopment. Again, we find here a clearexample of the net asset value approachfollowed by proponents of FFVA. In this case,however, the final outcome is particularlystriking, as banks are by their very natureinstitutions operating with a high leverage, andan accounting approach that disregardscreditors’ concerns would be particularlydifficult to accept. It would certainly clash withthe supervisory assessment of banks, assupervisors would never recognise asregulatory capital the reserves created by arevaluation of liabilities arising out ofdiminished creditworthiness. On the otherhand, the application of FFVA to own creditrisk would discourage sound risk managementgiven that an upgrade in a credit rating wouldresult in the recognition of a loss. Anadditional, more technical observation relates tothe composition of own funds, as changes inown credit risk could translate into a swapbetween tier 1 and tier 2 capital.35 Moreover, thebank might be under increasing pressure todistribute profits whereas the loss would haveto be booked directly to equity reserves, hencereducing with full effect tier 1.

6.3 STATISTICAL CONCERNS

The statistical experts of the Eurosystemassessed the possible implications of IAS onthe statistical requirements of the ECB,including the statistical requirements related tofinancial stability.

In terms of the recognition and measurement offinancial instruments, there appears to be a

35 For example, a reduction in the value of subordinated debtincluded in tier 2 would be transferred as a “revaluation gain” totier 1.

reasonably close correspondence between IASand the requirements for Money and BankingStatistics (MBS) with regard to securities andderivatives. However, the possible extension ofthe application of FFVA to non-negotiablefinancial instruments in the form of loans anddeposits would be contrary to the currentlyapplicable principle that these instruments berecorded at nominal value in the statisticalbalance sheet.

Users of the MBS seek to maintain loans/deposits at nominal value. Nevertheless, theyhave also expressed an interest in receiving dataon a fair value basis for banking analysis,whilst acknowledging the subordinate status ofthe requirement and the potential costs ofproviding data on a dual valuation basis.

As a response to IAS 39, there is the intentionto change the ECB reporting requirements byeither imposing the reporting of nominal valuesfor stocks of loans and deposits or by extendingthe requirement for flow adjustments to alsocover the revaluation of loans and deposits.

For the purposes of external statistics, euro areafinancial accounts and government financestatistics, it is expected that the IAS willimprove the overall data quality. However, thewider use of FFVA could create inconsistenciesamong statistics. Whereas the European Systemof Accounts (ESA 95) currently requiresnominal values for deposits and loans,corporations complying with the IAS willreport data on loans and deposits on a fair-valuebasis and this could create some consistencyproblems in the future, e.g. in the reconciliationbetween MBS and Balance of Paymentsstatistics and for the presentation of financialaccounts statistics.

Of particular concern is the possibility that inthe EU listed companies could be permitted orrequired to apply the IAS in their individualaccounts while non-listed companies could be

Page 45: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

44ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

permitted or required to maintain the CAF.Differences in the approaches taken by MemberStates and the diversity in timing ofimplementation at national level may have adisruptive impact on the quality of euro areastatistics. Moreover, FFVA raises the moregeneral concerns of comparability of statisticsbased on valuation criteria that are subject todiscretionary variables.

Finally, it should be stressed that to the extentthat financial reporting requirements divergefrom supervisory and statistical reportingrequirements, FFVA runs counter to the ECBobjective, and that of the EuropeanCommission, to streamline the overall reportingrequirements of European companies.

Page 46: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

45ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

7

ConclusionsThe analysis conducted in this paper should beseen as a first step in a very complex issue thatrequires significant additional research andcareful consideration of the policy options.Although this analysis must be developedfurther, some tentative conclusions cannevertheless be drawn.

The analysis confirms the concerns that thepotential wider application of fair values couldunduly increase the volatility of banks’ balancesheets, possibly reducing their ability to react toadverse shocks. Indeed, for assets andliabilities held to maturity, the resultingvolatility from the introduction of increased fairvalues is purely artificial and ultimatelymisleading given that, irrespective of theinterim fluctuations, the values will converge tothe same result as under the CAF.

Furthermore, the pro-cyclicality of banklending could be enhanced, especially if theextension of fair values occurs withapproximately the same timing as the New BaselAccord. In fact, in the presence of shocksembodying a significant price component, suchas an interest rate shock, a real estate crisis or astock market crash, the immediate recognitionof unrealised value changes under fair valueaccounting might aggravate the effects of theshock. Banks may be encouraged to react bypanic selling and tightening lending standards,thus contributing to a further deepening of thecrisis.

Increased use of fair values may also embodyincentives for banks to modify their portfoliomix in a direction that may move them awayfrom their traditional liquidity transformationrole, thus reducing their contribution tointertemporal smoothing. Notwithstanding thatthe use of fair values may support increasedrecourse to securitisation (and other risk-transfer instruments), thus distributing risksmore evenly throughout the economy, theshock-absorbing features of the financialsystem might be lost. Indeed, once a systemicdisturbance unfolds, its macroeconomic effectsare likely to be more direct and severe.

7 CONCLU S I ON SRelevant supervisory concerns are such thatfurther work and adjustments are called for inthe current proposals of accounting standard-setters (although the issue is not a movetowards FFVA, but encompasses a widerapplication of fair values). The elaboration ofaccounting standards should aim at achievingconsistency with internationally agreedprudential standards, by recognising sound riskmanagement techniques. In this context, majorareas of divergence remain, namely with regardto the treatment of own credit risk. From asupervisory perspective it does not seemreasonable to accept an accounting treatment ofbank’s liabilities that would generate profitsand possibly an increase of regulatory capitaldue to a deterioration of the bank’screditworthiness. Moreover, the aim ofachieving consistency is also important from anefficiency standpoint. If accounting andprudential requirements diverge, and possiblyalso move away from sound internal riskmanagement practices adopted by banks, thecompliance burden for credit institutions wouldbe unduly inflated. Consistency with statisticalrequirements for monetary policy purposesshould also be considered more thoroughly.Indeed, there is the risk that the very sametransaction would have to be recorded usingthree or four different valuation criteria, therebyincreasing the reporting burden of banks.

The debate on macro-hedging mirrors thedifficulty of achieving a common understandingbetween accounting standard-setters and theindustry. Although the new draft of IAS 39recognises portfolio hedging of interest raterisk and is considered an improvement withrespect to previous versions of the standard, itstill falls short of properly acknowledgingsound risk management practices followed bybanks and supported by supervisors. One of themain concerns put forward relates to thetreatment of demand deposits. In particular, thebehavioural maturity of core demand depositsdiffers from the contractual one, and banks takethis into account in their asset and liabilitymanagement practices. This seems sensible, asbanks collect savings from disparate depositors

Page 47: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

46ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

and a sudden and contemporaneous withdrawalof funds is highly unlikely, which allows banksto engage in their typical liquidity and maturitytransformation function. While it is advisablethat accounting standards be aligned with bestpractices in risk management, it isunderstandable that some limits need to beplaced on bank discretion in the allocation ofdeposits in maturity bands. In this context,supervisory principles thus far developed couldprovide relevant guidance, once again stressingthe benefits of closer coordination betweenaccounting standard-setters and supervisors.

The empirical results of the investigationconducted on share prices seem to indicate that,by and large, the introduction of FFVAstandards had no significant impact onvolatility. The results, however, need to beinterpreted with caution for several reasons andcall for further research. First, the choice of thecut-off dates on which banks changed from oneaccounting standard to the other is far fromclear-cut. Second, towards the end of the 1980sand in the early 1990s, the relative weight of thetrading book – to which the FFVA standardapplied – vis-à-vis the overall stream of incomewas relatively modest.

Conversely, however, market discipline may besignificantly hampered by reliability and datacomparability issues. Indeed, the reliability offair values for several financial instruments ishighly questionable. In particular, market creditspreads or internal models still seem to deliverlarge and varied outcomes for instruments withcomparable risk features. The informationcontent of balance-sheet data could be adverselyaffected. Furthermore, given the proliferationof different internal valuation models, thecomparability of balance-sheet data acrossfinancial institutions could be severelyjeopardised. Therefore, for the market to be in aposition to reap the benefits resulting from theintroduction of fair values, the existence ofdeep and liquid markets and the use of generallyaccepted models are considered an importantprerequisite.

Another important feature that the analysisundertaken has revealed is the added valuegained from using FFVA for the treatment ofcredit risk when compared to the CAF andbackward-looking provisioning. In fact,provisioning tends to be backward-looking inthe EU, since in several Member Statesaccounting rules compel banks to put asideloan-loss provisions only when the losses havealready materialised. As a result, provisioningpractices tend to have a pro-cyclical impact, asprudent provisioning does not constrain lendingbehaviour in the upper part of the cycle and amajor correction usually occurs when theeconomy enters into recession, with the resultthat lending standards are further tightened.In this context, the concern of accountingstandard-setters to limit the ability of managersto manipulate the P&L by means of opaqueprovisioning practices is understandable.

However, the analysis provided somereassuring elements, not least from a financialstability perspective. FFVA would introduceforward-looking elements in the valuation ofcredit risk and would allow for a timelierrecognition of the deterioration in asset quality.This indication is conditional on the quality ofbanks’ internal ratings systems and credit riskmodels, which is not yet satisfactory.Nevertheless, it is acknowledged that credit riskmodels will develop, driven also by changesunder way in the supervisory approach to creditrisk, and they will be increasingly used for thepricing of loans. Supervisors will validate thesevaluations and there seems to be no strongargument against reflecting such information inthe financial statements in order to provide bankstakeholders with a more precise picture of theirbank’s quality, thus supporting marketdiscipline.

It should be emphasised that the analysis hasshown that the benefits of the forward-lookingelements of FFVA can also be achieved bycomplementing the CAF with a forward-looking provisioning system, which would becurrently more favourable from a financialstability point of view.

Page 48: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

47ECB

Occa s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

7

Conclusions

36 Goldstein, M. and Turner, P., “Banking Crisis in EmergingEconomies: Origins and Policy Options”, BIS Economic PapersNo 46, pp. 17-18, Bank for International Settlements, October1996.

An increasing reliance on fair values would alsopave the way for financial statements properlyaccounting for derivatives transactions, thusamending a major element of opaqueness in thefinancial system that is presently hindering aproper understanding of the real distribution ofrisks to both market participants and publicauthorities. This is an element that should bestrongly supported by the central banking andsupervisory community.

In any case, the outcome of the analysisundertaken and the results presented in thisreport clearly identify grounds for concern froma financial stability point of view regarding thetransition from the CAF to a wider applicationof fair values, in particular by means of ageneral option for financial institutions tomeasure at fair value any financial instrument.As the changes may have a significant impact onincome volatility and pro-cyclicality, it cannotbe ruled out that a systemic disturbance hittingthe banking sector during the transition couldbe unduly amplified. As a matter of fact,systemic crises in the past were frequentlyassociated with significant reforms, liberalisingmarkets and a change in the environment inwhich banks operated.36 The transition to thenew regime might be accompanied bysignificant structural changes in bank behaviourthat are very difficult to foresee, and hencesome of the effects presented in this analysismay not materialise. Nevertheless, the issuesraised are too important to be neglected andshould be addressed in a pre-emptive manner.

Page 49: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank

48ECBOcca s i ona l Pape r No . 13Apr i l 2004

EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANKOCCASIONAL PAPER SERIES

1 “The impact of the euro on money and bond markets” by J. Santillán, M. Bayle andC. Thygesen, July 2000.

2 “The effective exchange rates of the euro” by L. Buldorini, S. Makrydakis and C. Thimann,February 2002.

3 “Estimating the trend of M3 income velocity underlying the reference value for monetarygrowth” by C. Brand, D. Gerdesmeier and B. Roffia, May 2002.

4 “Labour force developments in the euro area since the 1980s” by V. Genre andR. Gómez-Salvador, July 2002.

5 “The evolution of clearing and central counterparty services for exchange-tradedderivatives in the United States and Europe: a comparison” by D. Russo,T. L. Hart and A. Schönenberger, September 2002.

6 “Banking integration in the euro area” by I. Cabral, F. Dierick and J. Vesala,December 2002.

7 “Economic relations with regions neighbouring the euro area in the ‘Euro Time Zone’” byF. Mazzaferro, A. Mehl, M. Sturm, C. Thimann and A. Winkler, December 2002.

8 “An introduction to the ECB’s survey of professional forecasters” by J. A. Garcia,September 2003.

9 “Fiscal adjustment in 1991-2002: stylised facts and policy implications” by M. G. Briotti,February 2004.

10 “The acceding countries’ strategies towards ERM II and the adoption of the euro:an analytical review” by a staff team led by P. Backé and C. Thimann and includingO. Arratibel, O. Calvo-Gonzalez, A. Mehl and C. Nerlich, February 2004.

11 “Official dollarisation/euroisation: motives, features and policy implications of current cases”by A. Winkler, F. Mazzaferro, C. Nerlich and C. Thimann, February 2004.

12 “Understanding the impact of the external dimension on the euro area: trade, capital flows andother international macroeconomic linkages“ by R. Anderton, F. di Mauro and F. Moneta,March 2004.

13 “Fair value accounting and financial stability” by a staff team led by Andrea Enria andincluding Lorenzo Cappiello, Frank Dierick, Sergio Grittini, Andrew Haralambous, AngelaMaddaloni, Philippe Molitor, Fatima Pires and Paolo Poloni, April 2004.

Page 50: Fair value accounting and financial stability - European Central Bank