External referencing and pharmaceutical price...

35
1 External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiation * Begoña Garcia Mariñoso a , Izabela Jelovac b , Pau Olivella c January, 2007 Abstract External referencing (ER) imposes a price cap for pharmaceuticals based on prices of identical products in other countries. Suppose country A negotiates prices with a pharmaceutical firm while country B can either negotiate independently or implement ER based on A’s price. We show that B always prefers ER if (i) B can condition ER on the drug being subsidized in A and (ii) copayments are higher in B than in A. B’s preference is reinforced when the difference between country copayments is large and/or B’s population is small. External referencing by B always harms A if (ii) holds, but less so if (i) holds. Keywords: Pharmaceuticals, external referencing, price negotiation. JEL codes: L65, I18. * The authors thank for their valuable comments Pedro Barros, Kurt Brekke, Albert Ma, Michael Manove, Xavier Martinez-Giralt, Tanguy van Ypersele, participants at the 5 th European Health Economics Workshop (York, 2004) and at 3 rd Journées L-A Gérard-Varet (Marseille, 2004), and seminar participants at the BU/Harvard/MIT Health Economics joint seminars, HEC Montreal, Seminario SESAM Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Université de Liège and University College Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly benefited from discussions with Kurt Brekke, Claudie Charbonneau, Guillem López Casanovas, Michael Mclellan, Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz, and Frank Windmejer. The authors acknowledge the financial support of the BBVA. The usual disclaimer applies. a School of Economic and Social Studies. City University of London, Northampton Square, London EC1V 0HB, United Kingdom. E-mail: [email protected] b Corresponding author. Université de Liège (Belgium) and GATE (CNRS UMR 5824), Centre Léon-Bérard, 28 rue Laennec, 69373 LYON Cedex 08 (France). E-mail. [email protected] c Department of Economics and CODE. Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Edifici B, 08193 Bellaterra, Barcelona, Spain. E-mail: [email protected]

Transcript of External referencing and pharmaceutical price...

Page 1: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

1

External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiation*

Begoña Garcia Mariñosoa, Izabela Jelovacb, Pau Olivellac

January, 2007

Abstract

External referencing (ER) imposes a price cap for pharmaceuticals based on prices of

identical products in other countries. Suppose country A negotiates prices with a

pharmaceutical firm while country B can either negotiate independently or implement

ER based on A’s price. We show that B always prefers ER if (i) B can condition ER

on the drug being subsidized in A and (ii) copayments are higher in B than in A. B’s

preference is reinforced when the difference between country copayments is large

and/or B’s population is small. External referencing by B always harms A if (ii) holds,

but less so if (i) holds.

Keywords: Pharmaceuticals, external referencing, price negotiation.

JEL codes: L65, I18.

* The authors thank for their valuable comments Pedro Barros, Kurt Brekke, Albert Ma, Michael Manove, Xavier Martinez-Giralt, Tanguy van Ypersele, participants at the 5th European Health Economics Workshop (York, 2004) and at 3rd Journées L-A Gérard-Varet (Marseille, 2004), and seminar participants at the BU/Harvard/MIT Health Economics joint seminars, HEC Montreal, Seminario SESAM Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Université de Liège and University College Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly benefited from discussions with Kurt Brekke, Claudie Charbonneau, Guillem López Casanovas, Michael Mclellan, Jorge Mestre-Ferrandiz, and Frank Windmejer. The authors acknowledge the financial support of the BBVA. The usual disclaimer applies. a School of Economic and Social Studies. City University of London, Northampton Square, London EC1V 0HB, United Kingdom. E-mail: [email protected] b Corresponding author. Université de Liège (Belgium) and GATE (CNRS UMR 5824), Centre Léon-Bérard, 28 rue Laennec, 69373 LYON Cedex 08 (France). E-mail. [email protected] c Department of Economics and CODE. Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Edifici B, 08193 Bellaterra, Barcelona, Spain. E-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

2

1. Introduction

This paper aims at analyzing the incentives for a country to engage in external

referencing for pharmaceuticals as opposed to directly negotiating the drug’s price

with the firm. External referencing (ER) consists of a price cap for pharmaceuticals,

based on prices of identical products in other countries.

With very few exceptions, most countries in the industrialized world have

implemented ER at some point of time.1 For instance, this policy came into force in

the Netherlands and in Switzerland in 1996, under the Pharmaceutical Prices Act and

the Health Insurance Law, respectively. In the Netherlands, the maximum price for a

drug is established as an average of the prices of the drug in Germany, France, UK,

and Belgium. Prior to 1996, the prices for pharmaceuticals in the Netherlands were

not subject to any regulation, and they were high compared to the prices in those

surrounding countries. As expected, the Pharmaceutical Prices Act resulted in

considerably lower prices in general for the Netherlands (see Windmeijer et al., 2006).

In Switzerland, the Health Insurance Law introduced a 'positive list' of reimbursed

pharmaceuticals. For a drug to be included in this positive list, its price should not

exceed the average of the prices in Germany, Denmark, the Netherlands and the UK.

Both the Dutch and the Swiss experiences raise the following questions: Why are

these countries interested in engaging in external referencing rather than in any other

type of cost-containment regulation? Namely, given that pharmaceutical prices are

directly negotiated upon in the UK and Germany, why does the Dutch health authority

rely on these foreign prices rather than on prices specifically negotiated for the

Netherlands? What is the influence of the ER policy on the reference countries?

To tackle these questions, we use a model where a pharmaceutical firm sells a drug in

two countries. To focus on the role of consumer copayments and also to gather

whether there are any size effects we assume that countries differ both in size (i.e., the

number of consumers) and in the level of copayments.

One of the countries (country A henceforth) negotiates the price with the firm. This

country is unable to threaten the firm with not authorizing the drug for sale in case of 1 See Section 2 for a detailed account of the European experience.

Page 3: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

3

negotiation failure. The only threat available to A is that of not listing the drug for

reimbursement, so that the firm can still sell the drug at its chosen price with no

subsidy. The other country (country B henceforth) can either negotiate the price of the

drug with the firm, or instead commit to imposing a price cap based upon the price in

the reference country. We study B’s decision under two scenarios: one where B, like

A, is unable to threaten with not authorizing the drug, and one where B is able to do

so. We say that the first scenario is one with “weak threats” and the other one with

“tough threats”. Our assumption is that whether tough threats are feasible or not is an

exogenous feature in our model. For each scenario, we analyze how the commitment

by country B to engage in ER affects negotiations in A and ultimately determines the

firm’s total profit.

We show that the effects of an ER policy crucially depend on its specific design. In

this respect, we distinguish between non-conditional and conditional ER policies. In a

non-conditional ER policy, the price in A is used as a price cap regardless of whether

it was the result of successful negotiations in country A or chosen by the firm once

negotiations had failed. In a conditional ER policy, the price in A is used as a price

cap only if it is the result of successful negotiations, i.e., only if the drug is included in

A’s list of subsidized drugs.

The main results of the paper are the following. First, an unconditional ER policy

harms both countries and should never be chosen. In this case, whether threats are

weak or tough is irrelevant, since no threats are ever made.

Let us now consider a conditional ER. Here it becomes crucial whether we are in the

weak-threats scenario or in the tough-threats scenario. In the former scenario, B’s ER

policy results in an increased negotiated price in country A. This harms A. We also

prove that, for any given population size of A, B prefers a conditional ER to an

independent price negotiation. However, it is true that B’s preference for ER over

independent negotiations diminishes as B’s population size grows, although it never

disappears.

Our results for the tough-threats scenario are somewhat different. First, the effect of

conditional ER on the bargained price in A is negative, which benefits A. Second, a

conditional ER should only be observed if the copayment in B is sufficiently larger

Page 4: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

4

than A’s and/or the negotiating power of the agency in country A is sufficiently

strong. This is in contrast to the weak threats scenario. The idea is that the feasibility

of tough threats improves B’s payoff not only under conditional ER but also under

independent negotiations. This explains why the results on the B’s preference for ER

are not so clear cut in the tough-threats scenario.

Let us offer some intuition for our results. For almost all situations, we find that the

ER policy worsens the bargaining power of country A vis à vis the firm and increases

the price in A. The mechanism is as follows. The firm’s threat point in the bargaining

with A improves when an ER policy is chosen. By how much it improves depends on

the way B designs its ER policy. As an illustration, consider the extreme case where

the ER is non-conditional. In other words, suppose that B promises to set the price in

A as a price cap, even if this price is not the result of a successful negotiation in A. If

demand is quite inelastic, B’s promise can be exploited by the firm, who may not

negotiate in A and set a very high price in order to maximize the profits in B. Our

point is that under an unconditional ER the firm is able to extract higher rents from B.

This “linked demand” effect is also present (although in a smaller scale) in the weak-

threats scenario and under a conditional ER. Indeed, the only situation where the

linked demand effect does not exist is in the tough-threats scenario. The reason is that

in this scenario, a negotiation failure in A implies that the firm looses B’s market. In

order to draw comparisons, we study as a benchmark the case where the firm

negotiates with each country independently.

Our results with independent negotiations are a direct corollary of Jelovac (2003),

where she shows that with independent negotiations, prices are lower where subsidies

are higher.2 Since a more generous subsidy results in a smaller negotiated price, there

is scope for a country to engage in ER if its copayments are sufficiently larger than

the other’s. Hence, our contribution is the characterization of the effect of ER in this

setting.

Another contribution of our paper is that it enlightens the difference between external

referencing and parallel imports. The closest paper to ours in this respect is Pecorino

2 This may seem counterintuitive, since in markets that use the price mechanism as an allocation device high subsidies are associated with demand inelasticity and high prices. However, with bargaining, high subsidies increase the gains from negotiation to firms, who are then willing to go with lower prices.

Page 5: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

5

(2002), who studies the effects of parallel imports from country A to country B on A’s

price negotiation. He obtains that, surprisingly, the presence of parallel imports in this

context results in higher profits for the firm. It turns out that our model with

unconditional ER yields the same results, as it constitutes a different version of

Pecorino’s one, namely one with subsidies (which he assumes away). Hence the

statement made by Danzon et al. (1997) that external referencing is tantamount to a

100% parallel import is confirmed for the case of an unconditional ER policy. In

contrast, if ER is conditional, Pecorino’s result is reversed: the profits of the firm

decrease due to a conditional ER policy.

Unfortunately, a limitation to our study is that there is very scarce information about

the details of existing ER policies. For example, we do not know whether these

policies are conditional or unconditional, or whether their details are far more

sophisticated than the ones we have described before. After all, an ER policy is an ex-

ante commitment and it could be made to depend on the complex flux of events it

precedes. However, we believe that by focusing on the three examples that we have

picked (unconditional ER, conditional ER with weak threats, and conditional ER with

tough threats) we can gather the direction of the effects and demonstrate how

important the design of the policy is.

The three examples studied are somewhat more general than at first glance. For

instance, it is interesting to note that if the firm is able to make transfers to the agency

in the benchmark country in exchange for higher prices, and these transfers are

unobservable to the referencing country, then the situation is equivalent to one of

unconditional ER: the firm is able to induce a large price in both countries. The only

difference with the unconditional ER situations is that the benchmark country is not

forced now to delist the pharmaceutical drug. In contrast, if transfers are observable

(and the referencing country has large incentives to monitor) the referencing country

can delist the drug upon observation of such transfers. This would be consistent with

what we assume to happen under the weak conditional ER when a break-up of

negotiations is observed.

Again, we do not have information on how referencing countries do respond in reality

to transfers of this kind. We do however observe them. For instance, Pfizer offered

Page 6: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

6

disease management services to state residents in the state of Florida in order to avoid

a low price (namely, a lower rebate) that would be a benchmark for other states.3

It is important to emphasize that our analysis is positive in nature, rather than

normative. We do not analyze how and why copayments are chosen or why threats

may be tough or weak –we only observe that in practice copayments and threats

differ.4 Similarly, we do not seek to offer a complete explanation of why some

countries are reference countries and others are referencing countries. The basis of our

analysis is the fact that in the real world there are countries of either type. However, it

is clear that if a country’s objective is to reduce the costs of drugs, she will have an

incentive to engage in ER if by doing this it can induce lower prices than by

negotiating directly.

The paper is organized as follows. A description of the European experience with ER

is provided in Section 2. A two-country model with fixed-charge copayments is

described in Section 3. Section 4 provides the solution to the benchmark case in which

each country negotiates the price with the pharmaceutical firm, independently of the

other country. Section 5 introduces the possibility for one country to adopt a weak-

threat ER policy, and analyzes its effects. Section 6 extends the analysis adding the

possibility of transfers from the firm to the benchmark country to influence the

benchmark price. Section 7 extends the analysis to the tough-threat case. Section 8

graphically summarizes our findings. Section 9 concludes. All the proofs are in the

appendix.

3 Florida-Pfizer deal charts new territory in overall cost control, but can it work? Formulary September 1, 2001.

4 For example, one observes that in the Netherlands, failure of abiding by the price cap results in no sales authorization, whilst in Switzerland drugs are always allowed for sale, but they may not be subsidized.

Page 7: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

7

2. The European Experience

Let us now overview the many instances of ER that one can find in Europe. We

concentrate in this area because it is the most documented one.5 We concentrate on

the issues that are most relevant to appraise the relevance of our model.

Countries using ER and benchmark countries

Many countries in Europe have implemented ER policies. However, not only the

details differ from country to country, but are also changed often. For instance, in

Denmark, foreign prices were used to determine the reimbursement price for groups

of drugs (drugs with same ATC-code), but this policy has been discontinued recently,

and has been replaced by non-price controls. In Sweden, external referencing was

discontinued in 2002. Hence, the situation is, to say the least, volatile. Hence, the

examples given below should be taken with caution, as they are only valid as of the

time of writing this section.

The ER formula

As for inter-country differences, some administrations use the prices of other

countries to construct an average reference price, whereas others take the minimum

price. Among the first ones, some use a large list of referenced countries. Austria uses

prices from Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, the Netherlands,

Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the UK. Finland ads to the previous long list prices from

Austria, Belgium, Ireland, and Norway. Also among countries using average prices,

others use prices from just a handful of countries. This is what happens in the two

examples presented in the beginning of the introduction: the Netherlands uses the

prices observed in Belgium, France, Germany, and the UK while Switzerland uses the

prices from Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK. There are many other

countries that take averages (from different lists): Austria, Belgium, Italy, Lithuania

(average minus 5%), and Norway (average of the lowest 3).

5There are countries outside Europe that also have implemented ER: Brazil (lowest price); Canada (median price); Japan, Korea, and Taiwan (average price).

Page 8: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

8

As mentioned earlier, some countries take the minimum instead of the average price.

France uses the lowest price among Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany,

Greece, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the UK. Other countries

using the same method (again with different reference countries) are: Bulgaria,

Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Latvia, Poland, Portugal,

Romania, ex-Serbia-Montenegro, Slovakia, and Slovenia.

In summary, out of all European Countries, only UK, Sweden, Germany, and

Denmark do not currently have an ER policy.

Formal versus informal ER

Very importantly for our model, the ER policy may be implemented more or less

formally. We assume that the referencing country commits to its policy at the outset.

This is precisely why the ER impacts the negotiations carried out in the reference

countries. In this respect, Spain uses ER only informally, and therefore it is less

appropriate to apply our analysis to this particular case.

Weak versus tough threats

Also importantly for our model, there are reasons to believe that most of European

experiences correspond to the weak threats scenario. The reason is simple. In Europe,

authorization and price negotiation are separate processes carried out by separated

agencies, based on different criteria, and with different time horizons. As Heuer et al.

(2007) point out, “[W]ith the introduction of the European Medicines Evaluation

Agency (EMEA) in 1995, the EU Member States wanted to harmonize access to the

pharmaceutical market” so that “[...] companies benefit from a larger market after

authorization.” (p. 2). As for Switzerland, a non-EU state, Paris and Docteur (2007)

report that “to be launched on the Swiss market, pharmaceutical products have to be

approved by the Swissmedic [...] The institute grants a marketing authorization if the

product meets the requirements of quality, safety and effectiveness. The clinical

assessment is based on data provided by the pharmaceutical company. This

authorization is valid for 5 years.” In contrast, “The Federal Office of Public Health

(OFSP) regulates both inclusion in the positive list and pricing of reimbursed

pharmaceuticals.”

Page 9: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

9

Empirical measures of the effects of ER

Apart form the work by Windmeijer (2006) already mentioned in the introduction,

there are several other empirical studies that analyze the impact of price regulation.

Unfortunately, more than exploring the effects of ER in isolation, most empirical

studies aim to determining the effect of price controls in general.6 An exception is

Heuer et al (2007), who explore whether countries engaging in ER suffer from delays

in the launch of pharmaceutical products. Although we do not address this

phenomenon, we think that it is a good proxy for the importance of ER.

These authors explicitly distinguish ER from other direct price controls (which

include the consideration of the therapeutic value of the drug, its cost-effectiveness, or

its pharmaceutical contribution to the economy). The authors also consider the effect

of reference pricing (that is, having the subsidy depend on the prices of similar drugs),

which constitutes an indirect form of price control. It is suggestive that the only

coefficient that is significant at the 5% level is that of the dummy variable for the

presence of ER.7 In contrast, the coefficients for the presence of other direct controls

and for reference pricing are not significant.

Relative market sizes

Our most important result for the European experience is that under conditional ER

and under weak threats, the referencing country’s preference for ER over independent

negotiations diminishes as the benchmark country’s population size grows, although it

never disappears. In Table 2 we report total pharmaceutical sales in millions of US

dollars in the year 2001. Recall that the Netherlands uses an average of the prices of

the drug in Belgium, France, Germany, and UK. If we divide sales in the Netherlands

by each of these countries’, we obtain, respectively, 1.20, 0.18, 0.16, and 0.25. If we

take the unweighted average of these numbers we obtain 0.45. If we performed the

same calculation assuming that Germany was to use the same list of countries as

benchmarks (adding the Netherlands and taking away Germany), we would obtain

6 On the effects of regulation on price see Danzon and Chao (2000a, 2000b) and Cabrales and Jimenez (2007). On the effects of regulation and price differentials on launch delays see Danzon, Wang and Wang (2005) and Kyle (forthcoming). 7 More specifically, they show that, all else equal, if a country abolished the use of ER then the chance of launch within eight months would rise by 50.9%.

Page 10: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

10

4.09. The fact that Germany does not engage in ER while the Netherlands does is not

incompatible with our results. In Table 1 we repeat the same analysis using Gross

Domestic Product at current prices, in Millions of Euro for the EU-15 (2nd quarter of

2006, the most recent quarter for which we have a complete set of data). We obtain

0.63 (instead of 0.45) and 3.58 (instead of 4.09).

Table 1: GDP (Year 2006, 2nd quarter)

Country GDP Germany 578.800,00 UK 467.969,40 France 447.496,80 Italy 368.254,50 Spain 243.136,00 The Netherlands 132.936,00 Belgium 78.041,00 Norway 68.450,60 Poland 66.028,30 Austria 64.059,80 Denmark 55.300,50 Greece 47.581,00 Ireland 42.518,60 Finland 41.356,00 Portugal 38.627,60 Czeck Republic 27.990,30 Hungary 22.063,20 Slovakia 10.721,00 Luxembourg 8.383,00 Slovenia 7.414,90 Lithuania 5.835,90 Latvia 3.901,90 Cyprus 3.615,30 Estonia 3.228,60 Malta 1.245,90

Source: Eurostat

Page 11: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

11

Table 2: Pharmaceutical sales

Relative size of

referencing country Benchmarks

Country Hypothetical: Germany

the Netherlands

the Netherlands

Germany's hypothetical benchmarks

Belgium 2544 7,47 1,20 1,20 7,47Czech Republic 1163 16,35 2,63 Denmark 1485 12,80 2,06 Finland 1123 16,93 2,72 France 16968 1,12 0,18 0,18 1,12Germany 19014 1,00 0,16 0,16 Greece 2799 6,79 1,09 Hungary 959 19,83 3,18 Iceland 134 141,90 22,79 Italy 15328 1,24 0,20 Luxembourg 117 162,51 26,10 Netherlands 3054 6,23 1,00 6,23Norway 1400 13,58 2,18 Portugal 1484 12,81 2,06 Slovak Republic 344 55,27 8,88 Sweden 2434 7,81 1,25 Switzerland 3124 6,09 0,98 Turkey 1977 9,62 1,54 United Kingdom 12348 1,54 0,25 0,25 1,54Averages 0,45 4,09

Source OECD HEALTH DATA 2007, July 07

3. The Model

The players in this game are a pharmaceutical firm and the health authorities of two

countries, A and B. We refer to these players as the firm and the agencies. The firm

sells a drug in both countries. It holds a patent for the drug in both countries and

produces at no variable cost.8

Both agencies operate a positive list of reimbursed pharmaceuticals. If the drug is

listed for reimbursement in country i, patients pay a fixed and exogenous copayment

iC , and the difference between the price and the copayment, ii CP − is reimbursed by

8 The assumption that variable costs are negligible can be sustained empirically. Moreover, our analysis can be extended to situations with constant returns to scale. Having a positive marginal cost would only involve more complicated calculations, while in essence the results would be the same.

Page 12: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

12

the agency to the firm. If the drug is not listed for reimbursement, then the patients

pay the full price of the drug, iP .

We assume that aggregate demand in country A is given by )( AZD , with 0)(' <AZD ,

0)('' <AZD and ZA is the out-of-pocket payment. Country B is a K-replica of country

A, with K > 0 but not necessarily larger than one.9 We just say that country B has size

K while country A has size 1. Aggregate demand in country B is KD(ZB).

Note that by assuming that copayments are fixed, demand is fixed and independent of

the price as long as the price is above the copayment. If the price is below the

copayment we assume that the out-of-pocket payment Zi, i = A, B, is the price itself

(no taxes). Formally,

{ }iii PCMinZ ,= , i = A, B.

The following assumption is a fundamental assumption throughout our analysis. As

we will see, B would never implement an ER if it fails to hold.

Assumption 1 Patients pay less in country A than in country B, that is, BA CC < .

Notice that A and B have different aggregate demand for two reasons. One is country

size, as explained above. The other is that, even if an individual in A has the same

demand function as another in B and even if prices are the same in the two countries,

the latter individual will demand less due to the higher copayment.

The pharmaceutical firm aims at maximizing its joint profit from both countries, with

)( AA ZDP being profit in country A and )( BB ZKDP being profit in country B.

We assume that, in each country i, copayments are exogenously set beforehand by

some outside player (say the Government or The Parliament of this country i). Hence

we do not aim at studying what the optimal copayment Ci should be. This depends on

the outside players’ preferences, whether the firm is owned by nationals or foreigners,

equity and insurance considerations, consumption externalities, etc. The agency only

9 Suppose that, as for the individual demand function for the drug, there are T different types of individuals in country A, t = 1,2,...,T. We are assuming that if there are nt agents of type t in country A then there are Knt agents of exactly that same type in country B, for all t.

Page 13: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

13

bargains for low prices with firms in return for a “fixed gain”, the granting of

reimbursement rights. We believe this encompasses most real world cases.10

We assume that the agency is given the following mandate by the outside player: She

should negotiate prices with the firm in order to maximize net consumer surplus

minus the public costs of provision. Hence, the agency’s objective function does not

include the profits of the firm. We believe this assumption also to be in accordance

with reality. A motivation is that the outside player finds it beneficial to delegate the

bargaining over price to a more aggressive negotiator.

Now, in a market of size K we define the net consumer surplus as:

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⋅−=⋅ ∫ − )()()(

)(

0

1ii

ZD

i ZDCdqqDKZCSKi

.11

The objective function of the agency of a country of size K and copayment Ci is:

)()()( iiii ZDZPKZCSK ⋅−⋅−⋅ .12

We model the negotiation process as a Nash bargaining game. We first develop our

weak-threats scenario.13 Namely, we assume that if negotiations fail in a country, the

drug is not listed for reimbursement and the firm markets the product in that country

at the monopoly price, MP , with PM > CB > CA (otherwise, the drug subsidization

system would vanish). Notice that this price is independent of country size due to our

10 Some countries rely on the so-called “tiered pricing” whereby lower prices result in the drug enjoying a higher subsidy. Our model amounts to a very simple tiered pricing mechanism. As it will be explained below, negotiation failure results in the drug not being listed for subsidization. Hence, only two tiers are present: a subsidy P − Ci or no subsidy at all. 11 We consider the consumer surplus as a measure of health benefits as it is linked to the willingness to pay for the drug. 12 Note that, for all C < P, the objective function of the agency is decreasing in C. Although, as explained above, we take copayments as exogenously set beforehand, it is useful to understand why this is so. Suppose that one increases the copayment so that demand is reduced by one unit. This has a negative effect on gross consumer surplus equal to the original copayment, as the unit that is no longer sold was enjoyed by the marginal consumer. However, it also has a positive effect, as total expenditures (consumer plus government’s) are reduced by the price. Since our premise was that copayment was below price, the assumed objective function increases. In consequence, if the agency was in charge of setting copayments, drug consumption would not be subsidized. However, also as explained above, the outside player’s preferences may be quite different from those of the agency. 13 In the extensions section we discuss the tough-threats scenario, where B (but not A) is able to threaten the firm with not authorizing the drug for sale in country B.

Page 14: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

14

assumption of zero variable costs (and in general due to constant returns to scale gross

of sunk costs). In such case, there are no public expenses associated with subsidizing

the drug and the objective function of the government reduces to )( MPCS , the value

of the net consumer surplus at the monopoly price.

Finally, the agencies of both countries have the same bargaining power, denoted by β .

The bargaining power of the firm in either country is β−1 .

Throughout the text we will denote )( MM PCSCS = and )( MMM PDP=π . We will

also denote )()()( iiii CDCCCSCW += for i = A,B.

4. Independent Price Negotiations

Here we present our main benchmark case in which each country carries a price

negotiation with the pharmaceutical firm, independently from the other country.14 We

consider a situation where a failed negotiation results in the drug losing its subsidy but

still being authorized for sale. Letting MCSK ⋅ and MK π⋅ constitute the

disagreement payoffs of the agency and the firm, respectively, the Nash bargaining

problem for a country of size K is:

Maximize {P ∈ [C ,PM

]}

{ } { }1 ln ( ) ( ) ( ) (1 ) ln ( )M MNB K CS C P C D C CS K P D Cβ β π⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤= − − ⋅ − + − ⋅ −⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦ = ])(ln[)1(])()()(ln[]ln[ MM CDPCSCDCPCCSK πββ −⋅−+−⋅−−+ (1)

It is worth noting that in the bargaining problem of any country, we assume that the

agency places no value on the consumer surplus or the public expenses of the other

country. Note also that the size of the country, K, only constitutes a level effect in the

independent bargaining problem, and in consequence will not affect the final price.

By solving (1) we obtain the following lemmata.

14 This analysis heavily draws from Jelovac (2003).

Page 15: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

15

Lemma 1. When both countries independently negotiate the price with the firm, then

(i) the resulting price in each country i, i = A, B is:

)()(])([)1()1(*

i

M

i

Mi

ii CDCDCSCCSCP πβββ +

−−+⋅−= , (2)

and

(ii) this price is increasing in the level of copayment, Ci.

Lemma 2. ii CP >* for all i = A, B.

Note that in this bargaining solution the profits per capita in country i, )(**iii CDP=π

decrease in Ci, since

MMiiii CSCCSCDC βπββπ +−−+⋅−= ])()[1()()1(*

and

0)´()1(/* <−=∂∂ iiii CDCC βπ .

This implies that, profits per capita are larger in country A.

The intuition for Lemma 1 is given after we further characterize the solution to (1).

Lemma 1 implies the following equality:

[ ] [ ]Miii

Mi CDPCDCPCSCCS πββ −=−−−− )()()()()1( ** . (3)

This equality illustrates that the total surplus generated by the negotiation above the

disagreement point is split between the agency and the firm in the proportion β to

1−β, as it is usual in this type of problem.

In the bargaining problem, the disagreement positions of the agency and the firm do

not depend on the copayment C i. Hence, the effect of the copayment on the

Page 16: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

16

negotiated price is only due to its effect on the surplus generated by the negotiation

above the disagreement point. Let )( iCS denote this surplus, with

MMiiii CSCDCCCSCS π−−⋅+= )()()( . (4)

Note that S(Ci) is decreasing in iC :

0)()()()()( <′⋅=′⋅++′=′ iiiiiii CDCCDCCDCSCCS .

As the copayment increases, there is less to be split between the two parties and the

negotiated solution converges to the monopoly solution. The public costs of the

subsidy for an agency decrease, and the agency can afford higher negotiated prices. At

the same time, as the copayment increases, there is less for the firm to gain by

negotiating and hence it requires a larger price. This explains lemma 1. The next is a

direct corollary.

Corollary 3. For any K and with independent negotiations, the negotiated price in the

country with a large copayment exceeds the negotiated price in the country with a

small copayment: **BA PP < .

Hence, henceforth we consider the situation where Country A is the reference country

for Country B.

5. The types of external referencing in the weak-threats scenario

In this section we consider the effects of an ER policy by B based on the price of

country A. Our aim is to explain how B’s ER affects the bargaining outcome in

country A and to investigate whether it is in the interest of B to implement this

regulation. As explained in the introduction, an ER policy may take many different

forms, in particular what is defined as a price cap must be settled first. Is it any price

in country A? Or is it the price in A as long as it results from successful negotiations?

Page 17: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

17

In the first case we say that the ER policy is unconditional, in the second case we say

that the ER policy is conditional. If ER is conditional, we must specify what happens

in the case of failed negotiations in A. As we are under the weak-threat scenario, we

assume that if negotiations in country A fail, B ceases to reimburse the drug but still

allows the firm to sell the drug at a full price chosen by the firm.

5.1 The effects of an unconditional ER policy

An unconditional ER requires the least information on the part of B. It is the only

feasible policy if B is unable to verify whether the negotiation in A has been

successful (or, equivalently, whether the drug is on A's positive list). In this case, if

negotiations fail in country A, the firm is allowed to set a price P that maximizes the

following expression: ))(}0),({( BCKDPDMaxP + . Note that this problem is

unbounded, as the demand in country B is fixed. Hence, there is no surplus associated

to the bargaining problem. In consequence, negotiations fail.15 This illustrates, in a

very extreme way, what the problem with external referencing is, in general: It

increases the disagreement payoff of the firm as compared to the disagreement payoff

under independent negotiations (πΜ). In this case the increase is in fact unbounded.

In conclusion, an unconditional price cap with fixed copayments is non-optimal,

resulting in really adverse results for all countries, both referencing and referenced. In

fact, one may say that this negative result motivates our research, as it is telling us that

ER must have more to it than the mere “copying” of other countries’ prices. Either

more sophisticated policies should be in place (normative approach) or are in place

despite not being actually observed as negotiations succeed (positive approach). For

this reason we turn our attention to conditional ER.

15 If an exogenous bound exists on the payments that country B can make, then we have to qualify our previous statement on negotiation failure. It only holds if the exogenous bound is large enough. If it is not, we would run into some convoluted casuistics that lie beyond the point we want to make, the extreme adverse effects of an unconditional ER on bargaining.

Page 18: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

18

5.2 The effects of a conditional ER policy

Letting MCS and MK π)1( + constitute the disagreement payoffs of A’s agency and

the firm,16 the Nash bargaining solution in country A is the solution to the following

program:

{ } Maximize],[ M

A PCP∈

{ } { }MBA

MAAA KCKDCDPCSCDCPCCS πββ )1()}()({ln)1()()()(ln +−+−+−−− . (5)

To guarantee that P is strictly larger than CB, we make the following assumption.

Assumption 2. MAB CDC π<)( .

By solving (5) we obtain the following lemma.

Lemma 4. Under Assumption 2, when the conditional ER is adopted in country B, the

negotiated price in country A is:

)()()1(

)()()1()1(

BA

M

A

MA

AWC

CKDCDK

CDCSCCSCP

++

+−

−+−=πβββ , (6)

which is increasing in both AC and BC as well as in K.

Lemma 4 allows us to write the following equality:

{ }MAA

WCA

A

BA CSCDCPCCSCD

CKDCD−−−

+− )()()(

)()()()1( β

{ }))1()}()({ MBA

WC KCKDCDP πβ +−+= . (7)

16 If the negotiations with country A fail the firm will sell the drug with no subsidy in both countries.

Page 19: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

19

This equality illustrates that the total surplus generated by the negotiation above the

disagreement point is split between country A and the firm in the ratio:

)1()(

)()()1( to βββ −>+

−A

BA

CDCKDCD .

This shows that the implicit negotiation power of the firm is higher when country B

engages in a conditional ER as compared to independent negotiations.

It is also interesting to analyze how changes in K change the outcome of the

negotiation in A on the face of an ER. A raise in K affects the bargaining between A

and the firm in two ways. First, the pie to be shared between both parties is larger;

hence there is an outwards shift in the frontier of the problem. Second, the firm has a

stronger disagreement payoff whilst A’s disagreement payoff remains the same. The

next proposition tells us the outcome of these two effects.

Proposition 5. Suppose that Assumptions 1 and 2 hold. Then:

(i) 0* >− AWC PP and this difference increases in K.

(ii) 0* <− BWC PP , this difference decreases in K and it converges to an asymptote

as K tends to infinity. This asymptote decreases in the difference CB − CA.

Therefore, the difference between WCP and *BP decreases monotonically as

CA tends to CB.

The proposition is illustrated in Figure 1. It implies that B always prefers to commit to

a conditional ER policy than to engage in independent price negotiations with the

firm. It also implies that this preference diminishes as the size of country B increases

and as copayments become more homogeneous, but is always positive. However, as a

direct result of the adoption of the ER in country B, the price negotiated in country A

raises. This is explained by the change in the differences between failure and success

payoffs of A and the firm. Moreover, as K increases the negotiated price in country A

Page 20: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

20

raises, but never to be so high that B loses out by choosing the ER policy rather than

independently negotiating with the firm. Public expenses as well as the firm’s profit in

country B are lower. The opposite holds in country A.

Figure 1. Comparing independant price negotiations to weak conditional ER as country B’s size (K) increases relative to country A’s. The value of R is derived in the Appendix (proof of Proposition 5). It decreases as CA increases.

Finally notice that consumers in either country are not affected by the ER policy since

they pay a fixed copayment. The next proposition states that the total profits of the

firm decrease because of the adoption of such an ER policy.

Proposition 6. Under Assumptions 1 and 2, the total profits of the firm are lower

when country B engages in ER, that is,

{ } )()()()( **BBAABA

WC CKDPCDPCKDCDP +<+ .

Consequently, the sum of public expenses in both countries also decreases, implying

that the decrease in B’s expenses compensates for the extra expenses in country A.

This means that if country B wanted to fully compensate A for her “free riding”, she

could do so and still achieve higher welfare than under independent negotiations.

R

*AP

*BP

As CA increases towards CB.

PWC

K

Page 21: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

21

6. Extension to feasible transfers from the firm to the benchmark country

Assume that, similarly to what occurs when a break up of negotiations is observed, B

delists the drug if a transfer is observed from the firm to country A. In this case the

negotiations in A will be based on both the price P and the transfer T. The Nash

Bargaining Problem becomes:

{ } Maximize 0,],[ >∈ TPCP MA

{ } { }MMA

MAAA KKTCPDCSTCDCPCCS ππββ )1()(ln)1()()()(ln +−+−−+−+−−

By letting τ = PD(CA) − T and cancelling terms, this is equivalent to:

{ } Maximize Mπτ >

{ } { }MMAAA CSCDCCCS πτβτβ −−+−+− ln)1()()(ln

Let us compare this problem with the independent negotiations problem (1) for

country A (that is, for K = 1 and C = CA). Notice that choosing P in (1) is tantamount

to choosing τ here, since both D(CA) and T are constants. Therefore, the two problems

are equivalent. Hence, by accepting transfers, the agency in the benchmark country is

able to revert to an independent negotiations process. This is a preferred situation by

A, by Proposition 5. The next question is whether the firm also finds it beneficial to

engaging is such transfers. The answer is no. First, using transfers decreases firm’s

profit in country A up to the value obtained under independent negotiations, which is

lower than that under ER (also by Proposition 5). Second, using transfers implies that

the drug will be delisted in country B, leading to profits πM < πWC. Therefore, no

transfers should be observed in this case.

In contrast, it is interesting to note that if the firm is able to make transfers to the

agency in the benchmark country in exchange for higher prices, and that these

transfers are unobservable to the referencing country, the situation is equivalent to one

of unconditional ER: the firm is able to induce a large price in both countries. The

Page 22: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

22

only difference with the unconditional ER situations is that the benchmark country is

not forced now to delist the pharmaceutical drug.

7. Extension to tough-threats

In this subsection we assume that B, but not A,17 is able to make tough threats in the

following sense. Suppose first that negotiations are independent. If negotiation in

country B fails, B does not authorize the drug for sale. Suppose now that B

implements a conditional ER policy. Then, if negotiations in country A fail, again B

does not authorize the drug for sale. This changes the status quo of both the Nash

bargaining problem in B under independent negotiations and the Nash bargaining

problem in A when B engages in ER. A full description of these problems and their

solutions can be found in Appendix B, where we show that, first, under independent

price negotiations, the negotiated price in country B is independent of B’s relative

size. This result was also obtained under weak threats, and the intuition provided there

is valid for this case as well. Second, we also show that the negotiated price in A

under a conditional ER by B, denoted by TCP , is increasing in both AC and BC and

decreasing in the relative size of country B. Intuitively, under tough threats the status

quo of both the firm and A are independent of K. An increase in K only affects the

bargaining problem by shifting the firm’s losses due to negotiation failure upwards,

not A’s. This results in smaller negotiated prices. Third, we also show that TCP is

lower than the independently negotiated price in A. Hence, in contrast to the weak-

threats case, A is benefited by B’s ER. One cannot say that Country B free rides on

Country A. Rather, now it is country A who free rides on B’s tough position.

Finally, and most importantly, we show that an open set of parameters exists where B

finds it beneficial to engage in ER. More specifically, ER is more likely to be

implemented (a) the larger the difference between copayments and/or (b) the smaller

the agencies’ negotiation power β. That B finds it beneficial to engage in ER is quite

surprising because, by engaging in ER, B seems to be “copying” the price of a country

that is unable to make tough threats. The intuition behind (a) is that under independent 17 This is consistent with the assumption that A is unable to engage in ER due to an overall weak position vis à vis the firm.

Page 23: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

23

negotiations (our point of comparison), B’s position is weakened (even under tough

threats) if country B’s copayment is high. This in turn is explained by the fact that

when copayments are high, the firm does not gain so much from a successful

negotiation. The intuition behind (b) is that the firm’s tough threat is transmitted into

the price negotiation in A through B’s ER policy. This turns out to be more effective

the weaker the agencies’ negotiation power is. In contrast, if the agencies’ negotiation

power is large and/or copayments are close enough then B may prefer to stick to

independent negotiations with the firm. We show this in Appendix B by means a

numerical example.

8. Graphical analysis

In Figure 2 we illustrate our results by depicting the Nash Bargaining problem in the

classical form, i.e., as a maximization under constraints.

Figure 2. The Nash bargaining solution (NBS) in country A (i) under a weak conditional ER (WC-

y = Firm’s profit

x = Objective of A

−1

−(1+Δ)

WC-ER

TC-ER

IPN S1

S0

(1+K)πΜ

πΜ

CSM

(1−β)/β

(1+Δ) (1−β)/β

As K increases

Frontier under independant negotiations

Frontier under ER

As K increases

Page 24: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

24

ER), (ii) under a tough conditional ER (TC-ER), and (iii) under independent negotiations (IPN). The crosses denote statu quo points. The dots represent the NBS in each case. The final and total profits of the firm can be read out of the vertical axis except for independent price begotiations.

8.1 Construction of Figure 2

Formally, let )(PXx = and )(PYy = be agency A’s and firm’s payoff when price is

P, and let 0x and 0y be these player’s disagreement payoffs. Then we can express the

NBS (Nash bargaining solution) as the solution to

)()(

)log()1()log(),( 002

PYyPXxtosubject

yyxxyx

Max

==

−−+−ℜ∈ +

ββ

Then the frontier )(xy φ= is found by solving )(PXx = for P and substituting the

solution into )(PYy = . Let us refer to the objective function of the previous problem

simply as OF. The NBS is found at the tangency point between the frontier and the

isoquants of OF, which have to be shifted as if the axes have origin in the

disagreement point (x0, y0). Formally, it is the solution to:

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

−−

−−=′

=

,1

)(

)(

0

0

xxyyx

xy

ββφ

φ

where the right-hand side term of the second equation is the slope of OF’s isoquants.

Equivalently, the solution lies at the intersection between the frontier )(xy φ= with

slope )(xφ′ , and the ray obtained by rearranging the second tengency equation:

φβ

β ′−−=

−− 1

0

0

xxyy

,

with slope:

φβ

β ′−−

1 .

Page 25: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

25

When A conducts independent price negotiations, we have that

)()()()( AAA CDCPCCSPX −−= and )()( ACPDPY = .

The slope of the frontier is -1, as can be readily checked. The disagreement payoff is

given by S0 = ( )MMCS π, , where both the agency and the firm’s payoffs correspond to

the monopolistic solution. It is also important to draw the corresponding ray through

S0, with slope:

ββ−

−1 .

The NBS is found at the intersection of the frontier and that ray, denoted by IPN.

This exercise can be repeated for the case where B engages in conditional ER with

weak threats. There, )()()()( AAA CDCPCCSPX −−= (as before) whereas

)}()({)( BA CKDCDPPY += . The frontier rotates outwards and the slope becomes

( )Δ+− 1 , with )()(

A

B

CDCDK=Δ .

The frontier is thus steeper than before, and more so the larger K is. The disagreement

point now becomes S1 = ( )MM KCS π)1(, + , just above the one with independent

negotiations.Accordingly, we draw through S1 a ray with slope:

)1(1Δ+

−−

ββ .

The NBS in this case is denoted WC-ER in Figure 2.

Finally, if B engages in ER but is able to make tough threats, the frontier stays the

same as that with weak threats. However, the disagreement point is now the same as

under independent price negotiations, S0. Therefore, we now draw the relevant ray

through S0, with the same slope as under ER with weak threats. The solution lies on

the point TC-ER in Figure 2.

Page 26: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

26

8.2 Interpretation of Figure 2

The diagram clearly shows that the frontier of the problem shifts clockwise with ER,

and it also indicates the higher position of the firm’s disagreement payoff when

bargaining under weak threats. This explains the ranking of the values of A’s

objective function, where the maximum is achieved with tough ER, then independent

negotiations and then external referencing with weak threats.18 We have also depicted

the effects of size of the referencing country (K). On the one hand, the increase in K

affects the frontier under ER, causing a positive effect on A’s payoff. This is

irrespective of whether threats are weak or tough. On the other hand, the increase in K

affects the threat point only under a conditional ER with weak threats, causing a

negative effect on A’s payoff. This explains why under tough threats A’s payoff can

only increase, whereas under weak threats we have both a positive and a negative

effect. It turns out that the latter dominates.

9. Conclusions

Using a model where two countries differ only in their population size and

reimbursement policies, our most general result is that a country has an incentive to

engage in ER if its copayment levels are high as compared to the other country’s. This

preference dwindles as the relative size of the country engaging in ER increases. We

have analyzed how external referencing affects the negotiations in the country of

reference, A, proving that the design of the policy makes a substantial difference. One

of the reasons for these differences is the fact that changing the design of the ER

policy results in changes in the disagreement point in A’s bargaining problem.

Instead, an ER policy always increases the surplus to be shared between country A

and the firm no matter its design. The idea is that the profits obtained by the firm in

country B become part of the pie.

We have also examined which is the best policy for B. Clearly B should never adopt

unconditional ER. That is, “foreign” prices should only be used as price caps if these

drugs are included in the foreign positive list. A tough ER is better than a weak ER as 18 In the case of an unconditional ER the firm’s status quo grows to the point where the firm captures all the rents form both countries. Such policy should never be observed.

Page 27: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

27

it is based on harsher threats in the case that negotiations in A fail. However, if tough

threats are feasible under ER, they will also be under independent negotiations in

country B. The right comparison is between the conditional ER with harsh threats and

independent price negotiations also with harsh threats. This leads to the weaker results

given in Subsection 4.2.

Of course, one would like to know whether and why some countries use harsh threats

and others do not. This may depend on institutional features that we have not

modelled and that lie beyond the scope of our paper. We content ourselves by

looking at the two cases in a way that seems to us to be the most consistent one.

Finally, for the case with weak threats, we can provide a clear empirical prediction

that hinges on the relative size of the referencing country. Perhaps surprisingly, it

turns out that the relative size of the referencing country is irrelevant as to the sign of

the advantage of ER over independent negotiations. It is always positive. Only the

size of the advantage is affected. In other words, should ER have some external and

fixed cost that we have not taken into account,19 then ER will only be implemented if

the size of the referencing country is not too large. In a nut shell, “only small

countries should be observed to engage in ER and/or ER should be based on large

countries.” Our analysis yields an analogous prediction if one substitutes “large

country” by “small copayment country” and vice versa.

19 For instance, some political cost.

Page 28: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

28

References

Cabrales, A. and S. Jimenez-Martin (2007), The Determinants of Pricing in

Pharmaceuticals: Are U.S. Prices Really Higher than Those of Canada?, UFAE and

IAE Working Papers 697.07.

Danzon, P.M. (1997) Price Discrimination For Pharmaceuticals: Welfare Effects in

the US and the EU, International Journal of the Economics of Business 4 (3), pp.

1357-1516.

Danzon, P.M. and L.W. Chao (2000a), Does Regulation Drive Out Competition in

Phar-maceutical Markets, Journal of Law and Economics 43, pp. 311-357.

Danzon, P.M. and L.W. Chao (2000b), Cross-national price differences for

pharmaceuticals: how large, and why?, Journal of Health Economics 19, pp. 159-195.

Danzon, P.M., Y.R. Wang and L. Wang (2005), The Impact of Price Regulation on

the Launch Delay of New Drugs--Evidence from Twenty-Five Major Markets in the

1990s, Health Economics 14 (3), pp. 269-92.

Garcia Mariñoso, B. and P. Olivella (2005), Informational Spill-overs and the

Sequential Launching of Pharmaceutical Drugs. Mimeo City University, London.

Heuer, A., M. Mejer and J. Neuhaus (2007), The National Regulation of

Pharmaceutical Markets and the Timing of New Drug Launches in Europe, Kiel

Institute for the World Economy Working Paper No. 437.

Jelovac, I. (2003), On the Relationship between the Negotiated Price of

Pharmaceuticals and the Patients’ Copayment, CREPP working paper 2002/04

(Université de Liège).

Kyle, M (forthcoming), Price controls and entry strategy, Review of Economics and

Statistics, forthcoming.

Paris, V. and E. Docteur (2007), Pharmaceutical prices and reimbursement policies in

Germany, OECD Health Working Papers, Paris.

Page 29: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

29

Pecorino, P. (2002), Should the US allow prescription drug reimports from Canada?,

Journal of Health Economics 21, pp. 699-708.

Windmeijer, F., E. de Laat, R. Douven, and E. Mot (2006), Pharmaceutical Promotion

and GP Prescription Behaviour, Health Economics 15 (1), pp. 5-18..

Page 30: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

30

Appendix A

Proof of Lemma 1

For convenience we eliminate the sub-indices in this proof. The first-order condition

associated to the Nash bargaining program (1) can be written as:

0)(

)()1()()()(

)(**

1

*

=−

−+−−−

−=∂

∂MM

P CDPCD

CSCDCPCCSCD

PNB

πββ .

Rearranging this expression, equation (2) in Lemma 1 is obtained. This is the solution

to (1) since (1) is concave in P:

=∂

∂2

12

PNB 0

)(.)()1(

)()()()(

22

<⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

−−−⎥

⎤⎢⎣

−−−− MM CDP

CDCSCDCPCCS

CDπ

ββ .

To check that P* is increasing in C, rewrite the first-order condition associated to (1)

as:

[ ] [ ] 0)()()()()1( ** =−−−−−− MM CDPCSCDCPCCS πββ .

Applying the implicit function theorem to this expression, we obtain:

[ ])(.)()1(

)()()()()()1( ***

CDCDCDPCDCPCDCSC

CP

ββββ

−−−′−′−−+′−

−=∂∂

[ ] 0)1()()( * >−−

′−= CP

CDCD β

.

This is positive, as equation (2) implies CP )1(* β−> .

Proof of Lemma 2

By definition, )(PDPM ⋅>π , MPP ≠∀ . Therefore, ii

MM

i CCD

PC >⇒<)(

π .

Page 31: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

31

Moreover, Mi

Mi CSCCSPC >⇒< )( . Therefore, ii CP >* , BAi ,=∀ .

Proof of Corollary 3

By Lemma 1 part (ii) and BA CC < .

Proof of Lemma 4

The first-order condition associated to the Nash bargaining program (5) can be written

as:

=∂

∂**

2

PPNB

+−−−

− MAA

WCA

A

CSCDCPCCSCD

)()()()(β

MBA

WCBA

KCKDCDPCKDCD

πβ

)1()}()({)()()1(

+−++

−+ = 0.

Rearranging this expression, equation (6) in Lemma 2 is obtained. This is the solution

to (5) since (5) is concave in P:

=∂

∂2

22

PNB −⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−−−

−2

)()()()(

MAAA

A

CSCDCPCCSCDβ

2

)1()}()({)()()1( ⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+−+

+−− M

BA

BA

KCkDCDPCKDCD

πβ < 0.

Differentiating WCP with respect to CA and CB, we obtain, respectively:

[ ][ ] [ ] .

)()()1()(

)()()()()(1)1( 22

BA

M

AA

MAAAA

A

WC

CKDCDKCD

CDCSCCSCDCDCSC

CP

++′−⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡ −′−′+−=

∂ πββ

Using the fact that )()( AA CDCSC −=′ we can simplify the expression to:

Page 32: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

32

[ ] [ ],0

)()()1(

)()(

)1()( 22 >⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

+

++

−−′−=

BA

M

A

MA

AA

WC

CKDCDK

CDCSCCS

CDC

P πββ

and

[ ] 0)()(

)1()( 2 >+

+′−=∂∂

BA

M

BB

WC

CKDCDKCDK

CP πβ

Finally note that:

0))()((

))()((2 >

+−

=∂

BA

BAMWC

CKDCDCDCD

KP βπ

Proof of Proposition 5

Part (i).

Using Lemma 1 (for i = A) and Lemma 4, we can write

[ ]**

)()()()()(

ABAA

BAMA

WC PCKDCDCD

CDCDKPP >⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+

−+= πβ , and

0)()(

)()(*

>⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+−

=∂

−∂

BA

BAMAWC

CKDCDCDCD

KPP βπ .

Part (ii).

As K tends to infinity, PWC tends to:

)()()()1()1(lim

B

M

A

MA

AWC

CDCDCSCCSCP πβββ +

−−+−= .

To compare WCPlim with *BP as defined in Lemma 1, it is enough to notice that the

auxiliary function f (Z) is increasing in Z, where:

)()()(

zDCSzCSzzf

M−+= .

Page 33: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

33

Using CS’(Z) = −D(Z) and assuming that Z < PM, we have that:

[ ][ ] .0

)()()()( 2 >

−′−=′

zDCSzCSzDzf

M

This implies WCPlim < *BP , since CA < CB. Given that PWC is increasing in K (see Lemma

4), PWC − *BP < 0, K∀ .

The fact that 0)( >′ Zf also implies that the difference R = *BP − WCPlim decreases as CA

tends to CB. Therefore, the difference between PWC and *BP decreases monotonically

as CA tends to CB.

Proof of Proposition 6

Define { }.)()()()(),,( **BA

WCBBAABA CKDCDPCKDPCDPKCC +−+=Δ We need to

prove that ),,( KCC BAΔ > 0. Suppose first that K = 0. In this case WCA PP =* and

therefore ( ) .0)()0,,( * =−=Δ AWC

ABA CDPPCC Hence it suffices to prove that K∂Δ∂ > 0.

That is, we need:

.0))()(()()(

)())()(()(

*

*

>∂

∂+−−

=−∂

∂+−=

∂Δ∂

KPCKDCDCDPP

CDPK

PCKDCDCDPK

WC

BABWC

B

BWC

WC

BABB

Substituting WCP from Lemma 4, *BP from Lemma 1, and the formula of

KPWC

∂∂

derived in the proof of Lemma 4 in the expression we obtain:

[ ]

,)()(

))()(()()(

)()1(1

)()1()()`(

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+−

−+

+−+

−−=∂

Δ∂

BA

BA

BA

BM

BAB

CKDCDCDCD

CKDCDCDK

CDCfCfK

βπ

β

Page 34: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

34

with the function f (Z) defined within the proof of Proposition 5. Notice that the

second term is zero. The expression in brackets in the first term is positive since

0)( >′ Zf is proven for Proposition 5.

Appendix B

Independent negotiations with tough threats for country B

The Nash bargaining program is the following:

{ }],[ Maximize M

B PCP∈

{ } { } { })({ln)1()()()(lnln BBBB CDPCDCPCCSK ββ −+−−+ .

The Nash bargaining solution, when interior, is the following:

)()()1()1(*

B

BB

T

CDCCSCP ββ −+−= .

This solution price is decreasing in CB:

[ ] 0)(

)()()1( 2

*

>′

−−=∂∂

B

BB

B

T

CDCDCCS

CP β ,

and it is decreasing in β.

Conditional ER with tough threats

The Nash bargaining program is the following:

{ } Maximize],[ M

A PCP∈

{ } { }MBA

MAAA CKPDCDPCSCDCPCCS Π−+−+−−− )()({ln)1()()()(ln ββ .

The Nash bargaining solution, when interior, is the following:

Page 35: External referencing and pharmaceutical price negotiationidei.fr/sites/default/files/medias/doc/conf/pha/conf_2008/jelovac.pdf · Dublin. On the European experience, we have greatly

35

)()()()()1()1(

BA

M

A

MA

ATC

CKDCDCDCSCCSCP

++

−−+−=

πβββ .

This solution price is increasing in both CA (see the proof of Proposition 5, which is

similar) and CB, and it is decreasing in K. It is also lower than *AP defined in Lemma

1.

Numerical example

Let us provide a numerical example where B engages in a conditional ER policy when

agencies’ negotiation power β is weak while B prefers to stick to independent

negotiations when β is higher. Suppose demand is linear and given by D(P) = 120

−3P. Unsubsidized monopoly price is PM = 20 and monopoly profits are πM = 1200.

Copayments in country A and country B are given, respectively, by CA = 5 and CB =

6. Suppose also that countries have the same size (K = 1). Suppose first that β = 0.5.

Then independent price negotiations in country B lead to a price P*T = 11.5 while a

conditional ER policy by B leads to a price TCP = 11.2914 < 11.5. Hence B prefers to

engage in ER. Suppose now that β = 0.6. Then P*T = 9.2 while TCP = 10.1925 > 9.2.

Hence B prefers not to engage in ER.