Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of...

60
Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the Sonoran Desert Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the Sonoran Desert prepared for the Coalition for Sonoran Desert Protection by ECONorthwest August 2002 with funding from

Transcript of Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of...

Page 1: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Economic Benefits ofProtecting Natural Resources

in the Sonoran Desert

Economic Benefits ofProtecting Natural Resources

in the Sonoran Desert

prepared for the

Coalition for SonoranDesert Protection by

ECONorthwestAugust 2002

with funding from

Page 2: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

AcknowledgmentsThe Coalition thanks Defenders of Wildlife for their generous support for thecommission of this document.

Page 3: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Economic Benefits of Protecting

Natural Resources in the Sonoran

Desert

Prepared for

The Coalition for Sonoran Desert Protection

by

ECONorthwest99 W. Tenth, Suite 400

Eugene, OR 97401(541) 687-0051

August 2002

© ECONorthwest 2002

Page 4: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran
Page 5: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page i

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY AND READER’S GUIDE

Residents of Pima County, Arizona, face a large array of decisions affectingthe natural resources and landscapes of the Sonoran Desert. Most times, thesedecisions are cast as a choice between a healthy environment or a healthyeconomyÑwe can have one or the other but not both.

A variety of initiatives have been brought forward in Pima County in the lastyears regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, andby far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran Desert Conservation Plan, theplanning process for which was begun in late 1998 and is ongoing as thisreport is completed.

In this report we explain why the environment-vs.-economy view of things rep-resents a false choice. This choice may have made sense in the distant past,when natural resources were abundant, the economy was simple, and exploit-ing the environment was a common way of making a living. Today, all of thesedimensions of the relationship between the environment and the economyhave changed. Now, the health of ArizonaÕs economy increasingly depends onhaving a healthy environment

In the first chapter we explain the new roles that the environment plays in theeconomy of the western states. In the second, we draw on studies fromthroughout the West to explain how resource conservation in the West affectsthe number of jobs, level of incomes, and overall structure of local economies.In the third, we present readily available information about four categories ofpotential economic benefits of resource conservation initiatives in the SonoranDesert: (1) the increased supply of valuable natural resources; (2) savings fortaxpayers, utility ratepayers, and property owners; (3) a stronger local econ-omy, with more jobs and higher incomes; and (4) reinforcement of efforts toaccomplish other important goals.

The discussion shows there can be no doubt that well-designed resource conserva-tion initiatives in the Sonoran Desert can yield substantial economic benefits:more jobs, higher incomes, higher property values, and lower utility bills. In addi-tion, the resources that may be protected by conservation programs are, them-selves, often priceless.

Though few if any studies have directly measured the economic benefits fromprotecting lands in the Sonoran Desert, Summary Table 1 outlines the bountyof research from Arizona and across the West that underscores the substantialeconomic benefits of protecting places like the Sonoran Desert.

Many of these benefits lie outside the familiar economic context of marketsand dollar-denominated prices. This does not mean they are unimportant,

Page 6: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page ii ECONorthwest

Sum

mar

y Ta

ble

1: S

tudi

es fr

om A

rizon

a an

d th

e W

est I

ndic

ate

that

Con

serv

ing

Natu

ral R

esou

rces

in th

e So

nora

nDe

sert

Will

Yie

ld E

cono

mic

Ben

efits

Pote

ntia

l Eco

nom

ic B

enef

itsSt

udy

and

Expl

anat

ion

Intri

nsic

Val

ues:

Instr

eam

flow

s nec

essa

ry

A stu

dy in

New

Mex

ico fo

und

that

the s

tate’s

resid

ents

were

willi

ng to

pay

:fo

r fish

surv

ival

• $3

0/yr

for 5

year

s to

prov

ide th

e mini

mum

instr

eam

flow

s in

the R

io Gr

ande

Rive

r to

prev

ent e

xtinc

tion

of o

ne fi

sh sp

ecies

, and

• $7

9/yr

for 5

year

s to

prov

ide m

inim

um in

strea

m fl

ows i

n all

the s

tate’s

majo

r rive

rs (B

erre

ns et

al.,

1995

).Ov

er 8

0% o

f the

resp

onde

nts i

n an

othe

r sur

vey w

ere w

illing

to p

ay $

80/yr

to in

crea

se th

e stre

amflo

ws in

New

Mex

ico ri

vers

and

strea

ms (

Berre

ns et

al., 1

998)

. The

se re

sults

are i

ndica

tive o

f the

econ

omic

bene

fits o

f pro

tectin

g ins

tream

flow

s in

the S

onor

an D

eser

ts, as

sum

ing th

at Ar

izona

ns an

dNe

w M

exica

ns h

old si

mila

r valu

es.

Habit

at fo

r at-r

isk sp

ecies

A

study

foun

d th

at U.

S. h

ouse

holds

wer

e willi

ng to

pay

$50

-$33

0/yr

to p

rotec

t hab

itat c

ritica

l to

the s

urviv

al of

at-ri

sk fi

sh in

the S

outh

west,

inclu

d-ing

hab

itat a

long

the G

ila R

iver (

Ekstr

and

and

Loom

is, 1

998)

. Som

e por

tion

of th

is va

lue, s

till u

nqua

ntifie

d, w

ould

deriv

e fro

m h

abita

t pro

tectio

n in

the S

onor

an D

eser

t.

Rese

arch

ers s

tudy

ing th

e pro

tectio

n of

the M

exica

n Sp

otted

Owl

foun

d th

at U.

S. h

ouse

holds

wer

e willi

ng to

pay

an av

erag

e of $

40.4

9 to

pro

tect t

heow

l and

its 4

.6 m

illion

acre

s of c

ritica

l hab

itat i

n Ar

izona

, New

Mex

ico, C

olora

do, a

nd U

tah. A

cons

erva

tive e

stim

ate p

laces

the b

enefi

ts at

$1.8

billi

onto

$2.

6 bil

lion.

The

se fi

nding

s are

anot

her i

ndica

tion

of th

e mag

nitud

e of e

cono

mic

bene

fits a

ssoc

iated

with

Son

oran

Des

ert c

onse

rvati

on, i

nsof

ar as

it pr

otec

ts ha

bitat

for s

pecie

s of c

once

rn (L

oom

is an

d Ek

stran

d, 1

997)

.

Nativ

e eco

syste

ms a

nd

Califo

rnia

resid

ents

indica

ted th

ey w

ere w

illing

to sp

end

$177

milli

on to

$44

8 m

illion

per

year

to su

ppor

t leg

islati

on to

pro

tect 6

.9 m

illion

acre

s of

lands

cape

s of t

he d

eser

tth

e stat

e’s d

eser

t lan

ds (R

icher,

199

5). I

f Ariz

onan

s valu

e the

Son

oran

Des

ert t

o th

e sam

e deg

ree t

hat C

alifo

rnian

s valu

e Cali

forn

ia’s d

eser

ts, th

ese

findin

gs in

dicate

that

the e

cono

mic

impo

rtanc

e of p

rotec

ting

dese

rt lan

dsca

pes i

s con

sider

able.

Page 7: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page iii

Pote

ntia

l Eco

nom

ic B

enef

itsSt

udy

and

Expl

anat

ion

Recr

eatio

n an

d Ae

sthe

tic V

alue

s:

Bird

-watc

hing

and

natu

re-

Natu

re-b

ased

tour

ism, a

nd es

pecia

lly vi

sitor

s to

Ram

sey C

anyo

n, g

ener

ated

$1 m

illion

in va

lue-a

dded

activ

ity in

the S

ierra

Vist

a, AZ

area

dur

ing o

ne

relat

ed to

urism

year

(Leo

nes a

nd C

olby,

1998

). Pr

otec

ting

othe

r natu

ral a

reas

visit

ed b

y natu

re to

urist

s in

the S

onor

an D

eser

t wou

ld yie

ld ad

dition

al ec

onom

ic be

ne-

fits.

Recr

eatio

nal f

ishing

An ac

re-fo

ot o

f wate

r left

in a

strea

m ra

ther

than

use

d fo

r irri

gatio

n in

cent

ral a

nd so

uthe

rn A

rizon

a wou

ld ge

nera

te 15

0 an

gler-d

ays o

f rec

reati

onal

fishin

g wi

th an

econ

omic

value

of a

bout

$30

00 in

toda

y’s d

ollar

s (Ha

nsen

and

Halla

m, 1

990)

.

Wild

erne

ss re

crea

tion

and

Stud

ies o

f inc

reas

ing th

e am

ount

of w

ilder

ness

in C

olora

do an

d Ut

ah fo

und

that

the r

ecre

ation

al an

d int

rinsic

value

ben

efits

would

be r

ough

ly int

rinsic

value

$409

/acre

in U

tah an

d $1

,250

/acre

in C

olora

do. T

o th

e exte

nt th

at th

e Son

oran

Des

ert i

s com

para

ble to

Utah

and

Color

ado

wilde

rnes

s, th

ese f

inding

sar

e ind

icativ

e of t

he ra

nge o

f pot

entia

l eco

nom

ic be

nefit

s fro

m p

rotec

ting

the S

onor

an D

eser

t (W

alsh,

198

4; an

d Po

pe, 1

990)

.

Incr

ease

d Pr

oper

ty V

alue

s:

Incr

ease

d pr

oper

ty va

lues n

earA

stud

y in

Tucs

on, A

rizon

a fou

nd th

at ho

mes

loca

ted w

ithin

one-

half

mile

of r

iparia

n ar

eas p

ropo

sed

for p

rotec

tion

com

man

ded

thre

e to

six p

erce

nt

prot

ected

ripa

rian

corri

dors

highe

r sale

s pric

es th

an co

mpa

rable

hom

es th

at we

re n

ot lo

cated

nea

r ripa

rian

area

s. In

addit

ion, t

he st

udy f

ound

that

unde

velop

ed la

nd n

ear t

hese

ripar

ian ar

eas w

as va

lued

10 to

27

perc

ent h

igher

than

oth

er u

ndev

elope

d lan

d (C

olby,

2002

). Th

e res

earc

hers

attri

buted

thes

e res

ults,

in pa

rt, to

lando

wner

ben

efits

from

natu

ral a

men

ities a

ssoc

iated

with

ripa

rian

area

s. Th

ese a

men

ities i

nclud

e opp

ortu

nities

for w

ildlife

view

ing an

d en

joying

open

spac

e as w

ell sh

ading

, whic

h low

ers c

oolin

g co

sts, a

nd a

highe

r wate

r tab

le, w

hich

main

tains

exist

ing w

ell le

vels.

This

stud

y ind

icates

that

othe

r pro

perty

own

ers w

ould

capt

ure a

dditio

nal e

cono

mic

bene

fits f

rom

pro

tectin

g rip

arian

area

s in

the S

onor

an D

eser

t.

Incr

ease

s in

prop

erty

value

s A

study

in S

eattl

e fou

nd th

at ho

uses

nea

r a b

ike/h

iking

trail

sell f

or 6

per

cent

mor

e tha

n m

ore d

istan

t, sim

ilar h

ouse

s.ne

ar o

pen

spac

e and

natu

ral

A Bo

ulder,

Colo

rado

stud

y fou

nd th

at ho

uses

adjac

ent t

o a g

reen

belt

were

value

d 32

per

cent

high

er th

an co

mpa

rable

hou

ses 3

,000

feet

away

.lan

dsA

study

in S

alem

, Ore

gon,

foun

d th

at ur

ban

land

adjac

ent t

o a g

reen

belt

was w

orth

$1,

200

mor

e per

acre

than

sim

ilar l

and

1,00

0 fee

t awa

y.Th

ese s

tudie

s, su

mm

arize

d in

Brab

ec (1

992)

, pro

vide m

ore e

viden

ce th

at pr

otec

ting

natu

ral a

reas

pro

vides

econ

omic

bene

fits t

o pr

oper

ty ow

ners

,an

d th

e sam

e sho

uld b

e tru

e of c

onse

rving

natu

ral r

esou

rces

in th

e Son

oran

Des

ert.

Page 8: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page iv ECONorthwest

however. To the contrary, many benefits of conservation do not lend them-selves to markets and prices precisely because of their importance.

Ernie Niemi and Kristin Lee, economists with ECONorthwest, prepared thisreport for the Coalition for Sonoran Desert Protection. Many people have pro-vided valuable insights and assistance, but we remain solely responsible forthe reportÕs contents. We prepared this report based on our knowledge of thenatural resources and the economies of the Sonoran Desert and surroundingareas, as well as information derived from government agencies or othersources believed to be reliable. Any statements nonfactual in nature constituteour current opinions, which may change as more information becomes avail-able. As time passes, the results of this report should not be used withoutaccounting for more recent data and relevant assumptions.

For more information regarding the contents of this report, please contact:Ernie Niemi at 541-687-0051 (phone) or [email protected].

Page 9: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

TABLE OF CONTENTS

CHAPTER 1: NATURAL RESOURCE CONSERVATION AND THE ECONOMY: AN OVERVIEW . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1ECOSYSTEMS AND ECONOMIES—A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK . . . . . . . .1

COMPETITION FROM COMMERCIAL USES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .3COMPETITION DIRECTLY FROM CONSUMERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5TRADEOFF MECHANISMS AND RIPPLE EFFECTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .8

THE MIX OF GOODS AND SERVICES FROM WILDLANDS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .9REFLECTIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .13

CHAPTER 2: TRACING THE IMPACTS OF RESOURCE CONSERVATION ON LOCAL & REGIONAL ECONOMIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15A WRONG WAY TO THINK ABOUT IMPACTS—THE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL15

THE REASONING UNDERLYING THE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL . . . . . . .16WHY THE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL DOESN’T WORK . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17

A BETTER MODEL FOR UNDERSTANDING THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF RESOURCE CONSERVATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .19THE RESPONSE OF COMMERCIAL RESOURCE USERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . .20THE BEHAVIOR OF CONSUMERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .21TRACE THE ADJUSTMENTS OVER TIME . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22RELEVANT AUTONOMOUS TRENDS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .24FEEDBACK TO THE ECOSYSTEM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25

REFLECTIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25

CHAPTER 3: POTENTIAL ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF SONORAN DESERT CONSERVATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .27INCREASED SUPPLY OF VALUABLE NATURAL RESOURCES . . . . . . . . . . . .27

INTRINSIC BENEFITS OF NATIVE SPECIES AND LANDSCAPES . . . . . . . .29RECREATIONAL AND AESTHETIC BENEFITS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31

SAVINGS FOR TAXPAYERS, UTILITY RATEPAYERS, AND PROPERTYOWNERS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33BENEFITS FROM PROTECTING VS. RESTORING AT-RISK SPECIES AND

LANDSCAPES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .34BENEFITS FROM REINING IN THE COSTS OF URBAN SPRAWL . . . . . . .35BENEFITS FOR NEARBY PROPERTIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .36

STRONGER LOCAL ECONOMY: MORE JOBS & HIGHER INCOMES . . . . . . . .38AMENITY-RELATED GROWTH . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .38BENEFITS FROM MORE EFFICIENT USE OF RESOURCES . . . . . . . . . . .39

REINFORCEMENT OF EFFORTS TO ACCOMPLISH OTHER IMPORTANTGOALS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .40PUBLIC HEALTH BENEFITS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .40SOCIAL-COHESION BENEFITS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .41

REFLECTIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .42

REFERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .43

Page 10: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran
Page 11: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 1

NATURAL RESOURCE CONSERVATIONAND THE ECONOMY: AN OVERVIEW

In this chapter, we examine the web of connections between ecosys-tems and economies and describe the ways in which actions to con-serve resources in their natural state can affect economic growth andprosperity. We begin with a conceptual framework for understandingthe relationship between ecosystems and economies. We then applythe framework, first to describe trends in the economic importance ofdifferent goods and services derived from ecosystems, and then toexamine the potential economic consequences of resource conserva-tion actions. Though the discussion is general, reflecting emergingforces and trends at play throughout the West, it sets the stage forour subsequent examination of resource conservation in the SonoranDesert.

ECOSYSTEMS AND ECONOMIES—ACONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK1

To help elucidate the economic consequences of resource conservation initia-tives, we turn to a fundamental focus of economic analysis: competition. InArizona and elsewhere in the West, it once may have made sense to concludethat there was no competition for natural resources. The resources were abun-dant, and the economy made use of the resources in limited ways. Jobs,wealth, and prosperity were derived from natural resources primarily throughextractive industries that converted resources into commodities or via develop-ment industries that displaced natural resources with human-made assets,such as buildings, roads, and dams.

In those days, resource conservation proposals could be seen as involving aninherent tradeoff between the economy and the environment. One could have ahealthy economy or a healthy environment, but not both, as represented bythe diagram in Figure 1-1. When resources were abundant, relative to thedemands placed on them, there was, in effect, no economic competition for theresources available from western wildlandsÑthey were free for the taking.2

Chapter 1

1The discussion in this section relies extensively on previous work, including Courant et al. (1997) andNiemi (1999).

2Of course, perceptions that there was no competition for western wildlands ignore the long-lived compe-tition among different Indian groups for some resources and between Indians and Euro-American set-tlers. They also overlook the implicit competition among the current and future generations over thesustainability of resources and resource uses over time.

Page 12: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 2 ECONorthwest

Today, things have changed. Economic competition for western naturalresources is real, complex, and growing. Natural resources are not abundantas human populations have grown, and wildlands in the West cannot satisfy

all the human demands placed onthem. Hence, whenever wildlandresourcesÑthrough inertia, public pol-icy, markets, or some other mecha-nismÑare allocated to one use, other,competing uses go without. These com-petitive tradeoffs have wide-reachingramifications for local economies andfor the current and future residents ofnearby communities and entire regions.

To evaluate the economic consequencesof resource conservation initiatives, onemust know what their impacts will beon the competition for wildlandresources: which competitors and useswill benefit, which will not, and howthese initial impacts will ripplethrough the overall economy. Moreover,it is essential that one view these

impacts in the context of regional, national, and even global forces and trendsthat, throughout the West, are fundamentally altering the ecosystemÕs role insupporting jobs, creating wealth, and shaping entire economies.

Figure 1-1: Competition for Natural Resources—Old V iew

DominantCommercial Use(Jobs and Profits)

NaturalResources

Intrinsic Values(Environment)

To evaluate the economicconsequences of resourceconservation initiatives, one mustknow what their impacts will be onthe competition for wildlandresources: which competitors anduses will benefit, which will not, andhow these initial impacts will ripplethrough the overall economy .Moreover , it is essential that oneview these impacts in the context ofregional, national, and even globalforces and trends that, throughoutthe West, are fundamentally alteringthe ecosystem’ s role in supportingjobs, creating wealth, and shapingentire economies.

Page 13: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 3

One could categorize the current competition for wildland resources in any of anumber of ways, but we propose a taxonomy that distinguishes among fourtypes of demand for the goods and services derived from wildlands. The fourtypes of demand are illustrated in Figure 1-2. The left side of the figure showstwo types of commercial demand for resources, i.e., for elements of wildlandsthat help firms earn profits. The right side shows two types of consumersÕdemand for elements of wildlands that directly influence individualsÕ quality oflife and standard of living. Each type of demand exists independently, but thecompetition among them is best understood by assuming that one type, theÒDominant Commercial UseÓ in the upper left corner, prevails, and then look-ing at the consequences for the others.

COMPETITION FROM COMMERCIAL USES

The most easily identifiable commercial demands entail the extraction ordevelopment of natural resources. We use the term extraction to embraceactivities, resource uses, and industries associated with crop production, tim-ber production, grazing, mining, and other activities that chemically, electri-cally, or physically remove one or more elements (flora, fauna, mineral, orenergy) of the ecosystem from its source.

We use the term development to refer to the occupation of a site by humanstructures, such as occurs during urbanization. Development also includesintense human activityÑdraining a wetland, changing the composition of aforestÕs floral community, concentrating off-road-vehicle traffic, and so forthÑ

Figure 1-2: Competition for Natural Resources—Current Reality

DominantCommercial Use(Jobs and Profits)

CompetingCommercial Uses(Other Jobs & Profits)

NaturalResources

Intrinsic Values(Environment)

Quality of Life(HouseholdLocation)

Page 14: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 4 ECONorthwest

that substantially alters an ecosystemÕs natural processes. Mining, ranching,and development are among the most important of the commercial demands,

although there are many others,including industrial tourism.Commercial demand for naturalresources comes from private and pub-lic enterprises, which we define broadlyto include chartered institutions, suchas private corporations, incorporatedcities, and public agencies, as well ashouseholds that farm land, build ahouse, or recreate, and other groupsthat sponsor extractive or developmentactivities.

Dominant Commercial Demand. Wedistinguish among two types of com-mercial demand for natural resources.We first identify a specific, extractive

or development use of a specific piece of wildland that has three importantcharacteristics: it directly uses natural resources; depletes the stocks ofresources; and has a dominant position relative to competitors because of itseconomic competitiveness, political support, or historical inertia. The identifi-cation of a particular use as the dominant one is arbitrary, but purposeful.This type of demand usually is associated with a familiar extractive industry,such as industrial farming, ranching, or mining, or with common developmentactivities: urbanization; developed recreation; road construction; and the like.In general, only one commercial industry benefits from a particular use ofwildland resources, but sometimes there may be more than one.

In public discussions of resource protection initiatives, the economic impor-tance of the dominant commercial use of wildlands usually is expressed interms of jobs and incomes for local residents, as well as profits for local firms.In many cases, this commercial use is portrayed as the sole way for local resi-dents to derive jobs, incomes, and profits from wildlands. In the SonoranDesert, for example, it is common to hear the belief that, if land developmentor cattle ranching are allowed, then the local economy will gain jobs, incomes,and profits, but if the natural resources of the land are protected, then theland will have no positive impact on these variables. In the most extremeform, this is the economy-vs.-environment argument reflected in the first dia-gram in this chapter, Figure 1-1.

Other Commercial Demands. In todayÕs economy, the dominant commercialuse generally is not the only one competing for wildland resources. We pur-posefully distinguish between the two categories of commercial uses to drivehome the message that there often is competition, within the extractive anddevelopment sectors themselves, for natural resources. This message is impor-tant because, too often, the competition for wildland resources is characterized

We purposefully distinguishbetween the two categories ofcommercial uses to drive home themessage that there often iscompetition, within the extractiveand development sectorsthemselves, for natural resources.This message is important because,too often, the competition forwildland resources is characterizedas simply a jobs-vs.-environmentcontest between a (dominant)industry seeking to use a resourceas a productive input and those whowant to protect the environment.

Page 15: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 5

as simply a jobs-vs.-environment contest between a (dominant) industry seek-ing to use a resource as a productive input and those who want to protect theenvironment. By highlighting competing commercial industries that incur eco-nomic costs from the dominant oneÕs use of natural resources, we emphasizethe point that the positive consequences arising from one set of extractive ordevelopment activities frequently have negative effects on one or more others.

In the Sonoran Desert, one readily can see the competing commercial demandsfor wildland resources. Urban development competes with ranching, develop-ment competes with segments of the recreation industry linked to the desertÕswide-open spaces, and one sector of the development industry competes withanother.

COMPETITION DIRECTLY FROM

CONSUMERS

On the left side of Figure 1-2, natural resources are economically importantbecause they are inputs in the production of other things, such as beef, hous-ing, and transportation systems, that consumers want to have. On the rightside, the connection between these resources and consumers is more direct.That is, consumers consider these resources economically important for whatthey are and for how they directly contribute to consumersÕ well-being. Figure1-2 shows there are two types of demand for natural resources coming directlyfrom consumers: one affects those residential location decisions linked to qual-ity of life; the other does not.

Quality-of-Life Demand. We use the term quality-of-life demand to repre-sent consumption amenities that influence location decisions. Sometimes wild-lands produce amenities, such as recreational opportunities, scenic vistas, and

healthy environments, that contributedirectly to the well-being of people whohave access to them. In the language ofeconomics, these are known as con-sumption amenities. Their contributionto consumersÕ well-being makes con-sumption amenities economicallyimportant in their own right, but theyalso influence the location decisions ofhouseholds and firms (Knapp andGraves, 1989; Mathur, 1993; Mueserand Graves, 1995), thus, adding totheir economic interest. The nearerpeople live to these amenities, the bet-ter their access and the greater theirconsumer surplus.

Sometimes wildlands produceamenities, such as recreationalopportunities, scenic vistas, andhealthy environments, thatcontribute directly to the well-beingof people who have access to them.In the language of economics, theseare known as consumptionamenities. Their contribution toconsumers’ well-being makesconsumption amenitieseconomically important in their ownright, but they also influence thelocation decisions of householdsand firms.

Page 16: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 6 ECONorthwest

Whitelaw and Niemi (1989) have likened this relationship to a second pay-check residents receive by living in a place where they have easy access toamenities, so that the total welfare of residents within commuting distance ofthe amenities is the sum of this second paycheck plus the purchasing power oftheir money income. The size of the second paycheck affects behavior in thelocal and regional economies by influencing household demand for residentiallocation.3 If the second paycheck is large enough, it will attract householdsthat otherwise would have located elsewhere. The influx of people increasesboth the labor pool and the number of consumers. The former attracts firmsseeking workers, and the latter attracts firms seeking consumer sales. Bothmechanisms allow natural-resource amenities from wildlands to affect wheregoods and services are produced. Thus, the quantity and quality of natural

resource amenities can affect the levelsand types of jobs, incomes, profits, andeconomic activities in general through-out the local and regional economies,including sectors with no direct link tothe use of ecosystem resources.

The strength of the quality-of-lifeimpacts on the economy depend onmany variables, including the distinc-tiveness of the amenities availablefrom the wildlands and how theseinteract with householdsÕ preferencesand other building blocks of economicdevelopment, such as transportation

and communication systems. It is clear, though, that quality-of-life impactscan be powerful. Researchers from the USDA Economic Research Service, forexample, found that amenities influence economic growth throughout theRockies (Vias, 1999), and the rural West (Cromartie and Wardwell, 1999).Repeated surveys have found that recent in-migrants to Oregon resoundinglysay that having access to the stateÕs quality of life is a primary motivation formoving, and that they are willing to accept a reduction in incomes to do so(Helvoigt, 1999). Separate studies have documented that western countieswith higher acreage of wilderness or unroaded areas on federal lands experi-ence faster growth in jobs and incomes (Rudzitis and Johnson, 2000;Southwick Associates, 2000).

The quantity and quality of naturalresource amenities can affect thelevels and types of jobs, incomes,profits, and economic activities ingeneral throughout the local andregional economies, includingsectors with no direct link to the useof ecosystem resources. Studieshave documented that westerncounties with higher acreage ofwilderness or unroaded areas onfederal lands experience fastergrowth in jobs and incomes.

3That location-specific consumption amenities are an important influence in residential location deci-sions is well documented. The early contributions are Rosen (1979) and Roback (1982). For more recentwork on this topic see Beeson (1991), Berger and Blomquist (1992), Blomquist et al. (1988), Brady(1995), Brown (1994), Browne (1984), Cooper (1994), Cromartie (1998), Cushing (1987), Figlio (1996),Gabriel et al. (1996), Gottlieb (1994), Greenwood et al. (1991) and Sherwood-Call (1994).

Page 17: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 7

Intrinsic Economic Value Demand. The lower right corner of Figure 1-2represents the demand for elements or characteristics of an ecosystem thatpeople value for their intrinsic properties. Intrinsic values, often termed Òexis-tence values,Ó do not entail an explicit current use of the resource.4 They arisewhenever individuals place a value on maintaining the existence of a species,scenic waterfall, or other resource for its own sake, or on the prospect that theresource will be useful, for example, to future generations. Actions thatincrease the robustness of the resources, for example, by preventing degrada-tion of critical habitat for an endangered species or by ensuring the flow of thewaterfall, increase the welfare of those concerned about these issues, andactions that degrade the resources decrease this welfare.

Unlike the other three demands for natural resources, demands related tointrinsic values, by themselves, are unlikely to have any manifest economiceffect on jobs, income, or other indicators of economic activity. The protectionof scenic vistas in the Sonoran Desert may be of intrinsic value to some resi-dents of Miami, Los Angeles, and other distant places, but the effect of this oneconomic activity in and near the desert will be small unless it is articulatedthrough tourism (in which case it appears as a commercial demand) or thepolitical system. Still, the resource affects the real well-being of real people,and this well-being belongs in any comprehensive analysis of the value of theresource.

For some environmental issues, intrinsic values may be surprisingly large,especially to those who are used to equating the economic importance of wild-lands to their extractive and development uses. Consider wild and unroadedlands, for example. The large, undisturbed landscapes of these areas offeropportunities for private, secluded recreation, provide habitat for nativespecies, and support scientific monitoring and research that cannot be con-ducted on lands that have been heavily roaded or developed. Given these char-acteristics, plus a widespread desire to protect wild lands for futuregenerations, most Americans see unroaded areas as national assets that war-rant protection. In a nationwide poll conducted in January, 2000, 76 percent ofrespondents supported the protection of roadless areas in national forests fromlogging, road-building, and other development (DiVall and Onorato, 2000).

4Some argue that the intrinsic value category, alone, does not fully recognize the value of the life-supportservices ecosystems provide that make the earth habitable (Baskin, 1997). We do not debate the pointhere but, instead, expand the category of intrinsic values to include this life-support value.

Page 18: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 8 ECONorthwest

TRADEOFF MECHANISMS AND RIPPLE

EFFECTS

We have constructed the analytical framework associated with Figure 1-2 todemonstrate the complex and growing competition for wildland resources inthe West. A central message to be drawn from the framework is that, when

one type of demand enjoys the use of agiven set of natural resources, somecompeting demands go without. In thiscontext, there are economic tradeoffsthat ripple through local and regionaleconomies from any use of wildlandresources, including protection of thelandÕs natural characteristics. Hence,when trying to trace the economic con-sequences of initiatives to protect thenatural character of wildlands, onecannot look solely at the historical useof the resources but, instead, must also

look at the impacts on the competing uses. To illustrate this principle, weextend our framework, again setting the dominant commercial use as the win-ner of the allocative process and looking at the costs on the others (but empha-sizing that the same logic applies when resources are allocated to the otherthree types of demand). These costs materialize through two mechanisms:direct displacement and subsidies.

Direct displacement. This type of cost can materialize via two pathways:competitive bidding and negative externalities. The former materializes whenan increase in the output of a resource use, other things equal, reduces theoutput of other uses. To extend the framework associated with Figure 1-2,expanding the output of the dominant commercial use reduces the value ofcompeting commercial uses, the quality of life for residents, the intrinsic valueof the wildland resources, or perhaps all three. This outcome might material-ize, for example, when an urban development reduces the amount of wateravailable for other uses, such as instream flows.

Displacement also occurs when the production of the dominant commercialindustry is accompanied by negative externalities.5 Negative externalities areubiquitous when extractive and development activities affect the quality of air,water, habitat and landscapes.6 There currently is considerable concern in theSonoran Desert, for example, about the impacts of urban development on the

A central message to be drawn fromthe framework is that, when onetype of demand enjoys the use of agiven set of natural resources, somecompeting demands go without. Inthis context, there are economictradeoffs that ripple through localand regional economies from anyuse of wildland resources, includingprotection of the land’ s naturalcharacteristics.

5In some cases externalities are positive. We include such cases as a part of the input demand.

6There is an extensive literature regarding when a particular cost or benefit is or is not an externality,or whether a particular price or production phenomenon stems from displacement, an externality, or asubsidy. See, for example, Baumol and Oates (1988 pp. 14-15).

Page 19: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 9

quantity and energy of water flowing downstream during a flood event. Sometypes of development can increase the risks of flood-related damage down-stream, thereby displacing opportunities for future development of down-stream parcels.

Subsidies. The second mechanism by which the dominant commercial use ofnatural resources can impose costs on those with other, competing demandscomes into play when government subsidies distort the prices or productionlevels of the dominant commercial industry. Similar distortions can arise fromregulatory and other actions, but, to conserve space, we lump them all underthe rubric of subsidies. Subsidies draw money from, and thereby restrict theoutput and profits of other commercial industries. They also lower the dispos-able incomes of households. Hence, subsidies are akin to externalities.

Subsidies may be conspicuous, as when states give tax concessions to anindustry, but they may be more hidden. Regardless of their visibility, subsidiessuppress the level of production in other industries and lower the well-being ofaffected households. These effects may materialize in the vicinity of the subsi-dized industry, but not necessarily.

THE MIX OF GOODS AND SERVICES

FROM WILDLANDS 7

There exists no comprehensive evaluation of the value of the different ecologi-cal goods and services derived from western wildlands. A rough idea of theirvalue can be obtained, however, by looking at data for the nationÕs nationalforests, most of which lie in the West. We first examine the economic impor-tance of easily measured goods and services, then look at two that are not so

easily measured: high-quality stream-flows; and wild and unroaded areas.

Easily-Measured Goods andServices. In 1995 researchers at theForest Service estimated the contribu-tions to the Gross Domestic Product, orGDP, of different ecological goods andservices from the national forests (U.S.Department of Agriculture, 1995). GDP

is a common indicator of the value of all goods and services produced domesti-cally and provides a widely accepted measure of the nationÕs overall economy.As it usually is calculated, however, GDP ignores the environment, personalrecreation, and other unpriced goods and services. Hence, the researchersattempted to fill in some of the blanks.

There exists no comprehensiveevaluation of the value of thedifferent ecological goods andservices derived from westernwildlands. A rough idea of theirvalue can be obtained, however , bylooking at data for the nation’ snational forests.

7The discussion in this section relies on previous work, including Niemi and Fifield (2000).

Page 20: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 10 ECONorthwest

They estimated that the most easily measured goods and services from thenational forests would contribute $145.1 billion to GDP, about two percent ofthe national total, by the year 2000. Recreation accounts for three-quarters ofthis contribution, or $108.4 billion, as shown in the left side of Figure 1-3, andfish and wildlife account for another $14.4 billion. In contrast, the researchersfound that timber, forage, and mineralsÑthe goods that historically were soimportantÑnow account for less than 12 percent of the total. Moreover, theresearchers predicted that, for the foreseeable future, the value of the serviceswould increase, relative to the value of timber, range, and minerals.

Figure 1-3: An Accounting of the Most Easily Measured Items Showsthat Services Account for the Bulk of the V alue and Jobs Produced bythe National Forests

Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture (1995).

The right side of Figure 1-3 shows a similar pattern for jobs. Recreation, alone,accounts for more than three-quarters of the total jobs derived from the easily-measured goods and services the national forests provide the Americanpublic.8

Contribution to Gross Domestic ProductTotal Value: $145 billion (1999 dollars).Excludes carbon sequestration, clean waterand other services provided by national forests.

Contribution to Jobs3.3 million jobs derived from the national forests.Excludes carbon sequestration, clean waterand other services provided by national forests.

8The Forest Service recently reported that historical data have over-estimated actual recreational use ofthe national forests, but it has not yet corrected its estimates of the jobs and GDP attributable to recre-ation. As we explain below, however, the national forests also produce other services, such as high-qual-ity streamflows, and unroaded and wild areas.

Page 21: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 11

Table 1-1 provides some additional insights into the make-up of recreationalvalues. The data in the table come from an extensive analysis of federal landsin the interior Columbia River Basin. For these lands, all recreational activi-ties generated a total value of $23 per acre per year. Further research isneeded to discern the comparable values in other areas of the West, but thesevalues provide some reference points for understanding the recreational valuesof wildlands throughout the West.

Table 1-1: Illustrative V alues of Recreation on W estern Public Lands(Federal Lands in the Interior Columbia Basin)

Activity Annual V alue (Dollars Per Acre) a

Fishing 5.54

Hunting 5.32

Day Use 2.96

Winter Sports 2.84

Camping 1.94

Trail Use 1.84

Motoring Viewing 1.05

Viewing Wildlife 0.94

Nonmotor Boating 0.22

Off-Road Vehicle Use 0.13

Snow Mobiling 0.07

Total 22.85

a 1998 dollars.

Source: ECONorthwest with data from Haynes and Horne (Haynes and Horne, 1997).

Recreation is not the only service derived from wildlands that has considerableeconomic value. Others include (1) the delivery of high-quality streamflows; 2)the provision of unroaded, wild areas; and (3) the sequestration of atmosphericcarbon. Thus, even though the data on the easily measured values and jobsclearly show that recreational services derived from the national forests faroutweigh timber, range, and the other goods, adding into the mix these otherservices demonstrates that the services are even more important. In the fol-lowing discussion we elaborate on the values of two types of services especiallyimportant in the Southwest: high-quality streamflows and unroaded, wildareas.

Page 22: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 12 ECONorthwest

High-quality streamflows. For the entire national forest system, the totalvalue of all water flowing from the national forests is conservatively estimatedto be $3.7 billion per year (Niemi and Fifield, 2000). By this estimate, thewater coming from the national forests is worth slightly less than the timbervalue in the left pie chart in Figure 1-3. The water-value estimate, however, isrough and ÒconservativeÓ and future refinements may show that the actualvalue is greater.

As with the national forests as a whole, the value of services derived fromnational forest water often outweighs the commodity value. Historically, it waswidely believed that water was most valuable if withdrawn from a stream andused to irrigate crops or for municipal-industrial purposes. As the agriculturalsector has become less profitable and a smaller portion of the overall economy,

however, the economic benefits of usingwater for irrigation have diminished.At the same time, as the increasinglyaffluent population sought more recre-ational opportunities, but the opportu-nities associated with free-flowingstreams became more scarce, the eco-nomic benefits of leaving water instreams have risen.

A study by the U.S. Department ofAgriculture of the potential economic effects of shifting marginal amounts ofwater from irrigation to instream flows found that, in virtually all parts of thecountry, the net effect would be positive (Hansen and Hallam, 1991). In mostplaces, reducing the amount of water used for irrigation by one acre-foot wouldnot reduce farm production, whereas leaving the water instream would triggersignificant increases in the opportunities for recreational fishing. This is espe-cially true in the Southwest, where the recreational-fishing value per acre-footof water can exceed $1,000, but the irrigation value is zero. Additional recre-ational values associated with boating, swimming, and other activities alsocould materialize.

Streamflows with high-quality water in a natural setting generally are morevaluable than those with low-quality water quality or degraded natural condi-tions, such as trampled streamside vegetation. Water from the national forestsgenerally is cleaner and cooler than stream water originating from othersources, largely because the national forests occupy higher lands and oftenhave experienced less intensive development. Undeveloped areas also tend toexhibit more stable flows, with lower peak flows during wet months andhigher minimum flows during dry months.

Resource conservation can affect many of these attributes. Roads can affectboth the timing and quality of runoff, as can grazing and other activities inriparian (streamside) areas (Brown and Binkley, 1994). Some recreationalactivities, if not managed correctly, can affect the concentration of pathogens

Combined, the research results forthe nation as a whole and theColumbia Basin indicate that thespecial values associated with wildand unroaded areas constitute thelargest component of the total valueof the goods and services derivedfrom wildlands.

Page 23: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 13

in streams and increase siltation. Recommended conservation actions on typi-cally reduce the amount of development that distorts natural streamflows(Doppelt et al., 1993).

Unroaded, wild areas. Wild lands without roads have some special economicvalues: for recreation, the protection of species, and increasing human under-standing of ecological processes. Measuring these values is difficult, but someuseful insights into the general size was revealed by recent research regardingthe 78 million acres of federal lands in the Columbia River Basin (Haynes andHorne, 1997). Forest Service economists working in the area found that the val-ues recreationists placed on activities taking place in a wilderness area wereroughly double the values of similar activities on federal lands outside wilder-ness areas. They also found that the existence value of unroaded areas wasroughly equal to the total value of all recreation occurring on federal lands.

In other words, the special values asso-ciated with wild and unroaded areasexceed the value of recreation on allfederal lands in the region. Thenational analysis described above indi-cates that recreation accounts forthree-quarters of the total value in theaccounting of easily measured goodsand services derived from the nationalforests. Combined, the research resultsfor the nation as a whole and the

Columbia Basin indicate that the special values associated with wild andunroaded areas constitute the largest component of the total value of the goodsand services derived from wildlands.

REFLECTIONS

The central theme of this discussion is that the relationship between naturalresources and the economy is complex. With competing demands for theresources, a resource conservation initiative will generate benefits as well ascosts. Evidence from throughout the West shows that the benefits of conserva-tion often are increasing relative to the costs, insofar as the costs involvereductions in the supply of plentiful commodities, and the benefits come fromincreases in the supply of otherwise scarce goods and services, such as cleanwater and roadless-area recreational opportunities.

Evidence also shows that the mixture of competing demands for naturalresources is constantly shifting, with some demands growing relative to oth-ers. Any careful evaluation of the costs and benefits of a resource conservationinitiative must take this evolutionary process into account. In many instances,conservation initiatives restrict the supply of resources for long-standingdemands that are diminishing in their economic importance, and increase the

Wild lands without roads have somespecial economic values: forrecreation, the protection of species,and increasing humanunderstanding of ecologicalprocesses. In other words, thespecial values associated with wildand unroaded areas exceed thevalue of recreation on all federallands in the region.

Page 24: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 14 ECONorthwest

supply for demands that have emerged only recently. Such shifts mirror thosethat would occur if the resources were governed by market mechanisms.Hence, whereas criticism of conservation initiatives commonly conclude thatthey interfere with markets, the reality is oftenÑif not generallyÑjust theopposite, and the initiatives result in resources being transferred from a low-value to a high-value use.

Page 25: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 15

TRACING THE IMPACTS OF RESOURCE CONSERVATION ON

LOCAL & REGIONAL ECONOMIES

The growing competition for natural resources, described in the precedingchapter, means that any resource-management decision that increases onegroupÕs access to resources at the expense of others will have both positive andnegative impacts on the economy. Furthermore, growing evidence indicatesthat, in general, the services that might be derived from natural resources,and especially wildlands, are increasing in value relative to the goods. Thisshift in values indicates that, to promote greater prosperity, society ought toshift its resource management regimes, through resource conservation initia-tives, to increase the supply of services, such as recreational opportunities,scenic vistas, and natural streamflows.

Many people and public officials, how-ever, are not too interested in the factthat resource conservation initiativescan increase the value of naturalresources. They are more concernedabout the economic impacts, i.e., howresource conservation affects jobs,incomes, and the overall economicstructure of local and regionaleconomies.

To address these concerns we proceed in two steps. First, we discuss a com-mon model of economic impacts, called the economic-base model, to see why itoften predicts that resource conservation initiatives will have powerful,adverse economic impacts. We then describe an alternative model that moreaccurately represents how economies adjust to resource conservation initia-tives (or any other changes).

A WRONG WAY TO THINK ABOUT IMPACTS—THE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL9

Perhaps the most common model used to predict the impacts of resource con-servation initiatives is the economic-base model. We explicitly reject the valid-ity of this model because it so often yields widely misleading results. But,because it is so widely used, we first briefly describe it and explain why itdoesnÕt work.

Chapter 2

Many are not too interested in thefact that resource conservationinitiatives can increase the value ofnatural resources. They are moreconcerned about the economicimpacts , i.e., how resourceconservation affects jobs, incomes,and the overall economic structureof local and regional economies.

9This discussion is derived from Niemi et al. (1999).

Page 26: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 16 ECONorthwest

THE REASONING UNDERLYING THE

ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL

An economic-base model divides the economy of an area into two sectors: theexport sector, which produces goods and services sold to buyers outside thearea, and the local sector, which sells its products within the area. Proponentsof the economic-base model conclude that, because the export sector bringsfrom the outside money that is spent and respent on local goods, it is the Òeco-nomic baseÓ that ÒsupportsÓ the local sector. Because resource-extractiveindustries typically export their products to other regions or countries, theirsupporters frequently rely on the economic-base model to conclude that thisindustry supportsÑor plays the primary role in supportingÑwesterneconomies. Accordingly, supporters extend the reasoning to assert that thebasic industry must be nourished if the overall economy is to grow, and pro-tected if the economy is to be insulated from contraction.

An economic-base analysis typically proceeds in a straightforward manner.The analyst first assumes that the export sector consists of only those indus-tries with certain characteristics. The focus almost always is on resource-extraction, development, or manufacturing industries, although sometimesthey include major industries in the service and trade sectors, such as tourism,universities, or a concentration of government agencies. After deciding whichindustries are included in the export sector pie, the analyst then decides how

big a slice to allocate to each industry.This typically is done by looking at thepercent of statewide employment ineach of the so-called exporting indus-tries and comparing it to the industryÕsnational percentage. The reasoning isthat the more a stateÕs (or regionÕs) per-centage exceeds its national counter-part, the more the industry contributesto the stateÕs total exports. Havingdetermined that an industry produces

X percent of the total exports from the export sector the analyst concludes thatthe industry supports the same percentage of the local sector.

With this line of reasoning, economic-base studies have found that extractive,development, and manufacturing industries exert tremendous leverage overthe economies of western states and communities. Not surprisingly, with theseresults, both the analysts who applied such models and the lay members of thecommunity who accepted the reasoning of the economic-base model readilybelieved that any curtailment of basic industries would have devastating eco-nomic and social consequences.

The ultimate flaw , of course, is thatthe economic-base model giveswrong answers. Repeatedly , themodel has predicted that shrinkagein a basic industry would trigger acollapse in a local or regionaleconomy , but the opposite hashappened.

Page 27: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 17

WHY THE ECONOMIC-BASE MODEL

DOESN’T WORK

Several serious flaws in reasoning cause economic-base models to give a highlyinflated sense of the basic industriesÕ economic importance. It takes only somecommon sense, plus a quick look at economic history, to expose these flaws.

The ultimate flaw, of course, is that the economic-base model gives wronganswers. Repeatedly, the model has predicted that shrinkage in a basic indus-try would trigger a collapse in a local or regional economy, but the oppositehas happened. Numerous studies have demonstrated the modelÕs failure (Bray,1980; Krikelas, 1992; Leven, 1986; Power, 1996; Tiebout, 1956). In the PacificNorthwest, for example, the model predicted massive reductions in employ-ment and widespread economic and social chaos if logging on federal landswere reduced to prevent extensive environmental damage, but these catastro-phes did not materialize. Instead, the region enjoyed prolonged, robust growthin jobs, incomes, and industrial diversification (Niemi et al., 1999).

To help drive home the ultimate failure of the economic-base model, in the fol-lowing paragraphs we discuss some of the particular flaws in its underlyingline of reasoning.

The initial steps of an economic-base analysis entail identifying the industriesincluded in the export sector and determining their relative strengths. Thetypical approach is to look only at an areaÕs big industries, especially resourceextraction, development, and manufacturing, and to concentrate on thosewhose percentage of the subject areaÕs total employment exceeds the compara-ble, national percentage.

This reasoning seems plausible at firstblush, until one considers the implica-tions. What happens, for example, if theeconomic mix of a community, state, orregion exactly matches the national

mix? In the economic-base framework, such an economy would be dead in thewater, with no export sector, no economic base and, hence, nothing to supportthe local sector. Furthermore, even if one accepts all the rest of the economic-base reasoning, consider how it views an industry that exports all of its prod-uct, but has a smaller percentage of local employment than its nationalcounterpart has of total, national employment. The analyst would exclude theindustry from the export sector even though it is entirely an exporting industry.These and other logical inconsistencies render the exercise largely meaningless.

Economic-base models also take a snapshot of the economy and pretend it is amovie. That is, they contain a simplifying assumption that arrests the econ-omy in its current configuration so that any increase or decrease in the basicindustry can be traced through the now-assumed-to-be-static economy. In gen-

Economic-base models also take asnapshot of the economy andpretend it is a movie.

Page 28: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 18 ECONorthwest

eral, the results from this approach tend to overestimate the negative impactsand underestimate, even ignore, the positive impacts of any change from thestatus quo. This bias can be called the dumb-person bias, because the tech-nique explicitly assumes that investors, managers of firms, workers, and con-sumers will not adapt to the change in the basic industry but instead willcontinue to behave as if the management decision had not occurred(Mendelsohn et al., 1994). In reality, though, investors, managers, workers,and consumers are neither static nor dumb. The regional and subregionaleconomies of the U.S. are tremendously dynamic, and they adapt remarkably

to changing conditions. If the supply ofa productive input is restricted, or ifthe demand for a final product falls,investors will try to reduce their risksand the managers of firms will adapttheir production processes accordingly.

Courant, et al. (1997b) demonstratethat when using an economic-basemodel to crank through the effect onemployment or income of eliminating agiven amount of employment in the

basic industry, an analyst is answering the following question: What wouldhappen if the given amount of basic-industry employment were eliminated,and

¥ Those who lost their jobs as a result never worked again, but also didnot move;

¥ The local and regional establishments that sold goods and services tothe dislocated, basic-industry workers permanently lost that businessand obtained no replacement business (and also did not move);

¥ Those enterprises in the region that used the output of the originalworkers when they had jobs obtained no replacement inputs fromelsewhere (and also did not move); and

¥ Everyone throughout this chain who lost her or his job acted exactlythe same way as the original job losers, in that they never workedagain and stayed put?

There may be reasons for answering this question: it puts a theoretical upperbound on the extent of adjustment an economic region will have to undergo inresponse to a change in policy (or technology, or demand). However, as Power(1996) so nicely puts it, using the economic-base model for forecasting is likedriving a car while looking in the rear-view mirror. Thus, the economic-basemodel, at best, generates a measure of the maximum extent to which changesmight take place, but this is very different from a forecast of what will actuallyhappen.

Using the economic-base model forforecasting is like driving a car whilelooking in the rear-view mirror . Theeconomic-base model, at best,generates a measure of themaximum extent to which changesmight take place, but this is verydifferent from a forecast of what willactually happen.

Page 29: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 19

A BETTER MODEL FOR UNDERSTANDING THE

ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF RESOURCE

CONSERVATION

The key to forecasting how an economy will respond to a resource conservationinitiative is having an understanding of how the economy responds to anychange or stimulus.

Adjusting to change is one of the widely trumpeted virtues of marketeconomies. Experience in the western states of the U.S. and elsewhere showthat, when a specific industry in a specific location goes into decline, for what-ever reasons, the adjustment process entails two sets of things, which musthappen in some combination: (1) other activities will replace the industry indecline; and (2) capital and people whose incomes fall will seek replacementemployment and, if they donÕt find it locally, they search for it elsewhere. Toforecast how a given local economy will adjust requires not only a detailedknowledge of what that economy currently does and how capital and peopleare currently employed but also knowledge of other things that it might doand of how quickly capital and people respond.

Developing this detailed knowledge, and explicitly recognizing the dynamiccharacter of the economy, is the approach we recommend for understandingthe economic impacts of resource conservation initiatives on jobs, incomes, andthe overall structure of local and regional economies. We call this approach theDynamic-Adjustment Model. The model recognizes that restricting some activ-ities to conserve desired characteristics of some natural resources will alterthe relationship between these resources and the economy along two path-ways. Along the first, which is the most direct, the restrictions in resource-degrading activities and the ecosystemÕs response will alter the vegetation,

hydrology, and other biological andphysical characteristics not just on theaffected lands but also elsewhere in thelarger landscape or watershed, espe-cially downstream. These alterationswill change the supply of goods andservices to meet the four types ofdemand shown in Figure 1-2, and theeconomy will respond accordingly.

Along the second pathway, the restric-tions in resource-degrading activitieswill lead to alterations in societyÕsknowledge about the interactionsbetween the resources and the econ-

omy, the institutions society uses to manage these resources, and the incen-tives the institutions create for different types of resource managementbehavior. Information developed during scientific analyses associated with a

There is no simple way to trace allthe changes. If one wants tounderstand the impacts a resourceconservation initiative will have onjobs, incomes, and the like, one hasto trace the economy’ s adjustments,recognizing that each worker ,household, firm, and community willtry to mitigate the impacts itconsiders negative and toaccentuate those it considerspositive.

Page 30: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 20 ECONorthwest

conservation initiative, for example, might improve local residentsÕ under-standing of and stimulate a change in their behavior toward these resources.Resource-use restrictions might lead to changes in institutions, such as theproperty-tax system and the willingness of private lenders to extend credit tolandowners helping restore native ecosystems.

There is no simple way to trace all the changes. If one wants to understandthe impacts a resource conservation initiative will have on jobs, incomes, andthe like, one has no alternative but to trace the economyÕs adjustments, recog-nizing that each worker, household, firm, and community will try to mitigatethe impacts it considers negative and to accentuate those it considers positive.In the following discussion we present some of the highlights.

THE RESPONSE OF COMMERCIAL

RESOURCE USERS

The economic-base model suggests that commercial resource users respond toa resource conservation initiative in a simple, linear fashion: a reduction inthe supply of resources for an extractive, development, or manufacturingindustry will cause the industry and all dependent activities to contract. Endof story.

In reality, though, one should expect a wide array of response from a large setof enterprises. When a resource conservation initiative constricts the supply ofresources for a resource-degrading activity, one should expect the commercialfirms associated with that activity to pursue alternative supplies of theresource, develop alternative production processes that use less of the

resource, or both. Reductions in loggingon federal lands in western states, forexample, have induced mills toincrease their utilization of logs thatotherwise would have been exported,and expanded their use of technologyand labor to produce more finishedproducts per unit of timber.

As a resource conservation initiativeconstricts the supply of resources forresource-degrading activities, itincreases the supply of resources for

activities that capitalize on the recreational and other services available fromprotected and restored resources. Accordingly, one should expect to see com-mercial interests search for ways to take advantage of the situation. An initia-tive that would protect open space by restricting urban development, forexample, should induce developers of adjacent lands to pursue developmentsattractive to households, consumers, and firms that prefer to locate near openspace.

As a resource conservation initiativeconstricts the supply of resourcesfor resource-degrading activities, itincreases the supply of resourcesfor activities that capitalize on therecreational and other servicesavailable from protected andrestored resources. Accordingly , oneshould expect to see commercialinterests search for ways to takeadvantage of the situation.

Page 31: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 21

THE BEHAVIOR OF CONSUMERS

When consumersÕ demand for natural-resource amenities affects household-location decisions, as we described in the previous chapter, the mechanismsthat translate resource conservation into changes in economic behavior arevaried and complicated. The mechanisms come into play when the resourceconservation initiative will affect the attractiveness of a given site (and adja-cent properties), relative to the attractiveness of different sites. Generally,quantifying this impact lies beyond the reach of current analytical techniques.The changes in attractiveness in turn will affect residential location. Here,again, however, the available analytical tools generally have little grip.10

The effects on attractiveness and households are not limited to the immediatevicinity. Rural amenities can affect residential location in or near regionalurban centers. The improvement (or degradation) of a natural resourceamenity in the hinterland can affect the attractiveness of residential locationfor workers and retirees in metropolitan areas, because these households valueproximity, even at some distance, to the amenity. In this way, rural resourcemanagement can affect both urban and regional development.

How big these effects are we (and others) donÕt yet know. Two relevant lines ofempirical economic research suggest, however, that the effects could be impor-tant. The first is reflected in the literature on amenities, wages, and housingprices, which persuasively establishes that wage and price differentials acrossthe U.S. are generally more closely related to amenity levels than to cost-of-living differences or temporary, labor-market disequilibrium. Surveys of in-

migrants to Oregon, for example,indicate that consumers are willing toaccept considerably lower wages toenjoy OregonÕs quality of life (Judson,1999).

The second appears in the literature onthe sacrifices households make to gain

access to amenities, such as outdoor recreation opportunities, scenic beauty,clean air and water, secure neighborhoods, etc. (Bergland, 1988; Brown, 1982;Eberle,1991; Englin, 1991; Stewart, 1994; Uysal, 1985). This literature estab-lishes that people who live near recreational sites use them more. Thus, as thepopulation of western states grows, the demands for natural resource ameni-ties should grow even faster.

This literature establishes thatpeople who live near recreationalsites use them more. Thus, as thepopulation of western states grows,the demands for natural resourceamenities should grow even faster .

10It is important, however, to remember that despite our current inability to measure these impactsaccurately, the evidence clearly supports the conclusion that they can exceed zero, often by a largeamount.

Page 32: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 22 ECONorthwest

TRACE THE ADJUSTMENTS OVER TIME

Restrictions on resource-degrading activities will not have a single, one-time-only impact on the economy. Instead, the economyÕs response will evolve overtime. Whatever the initial, negative impacts, the economy will attempt to miti-gate, and whatever the initial, positive impacts, it will try to accentuate.

The evolution will occur in the four general stages shown in Figure 2-1. InStage 1, the resource conservation initiative is adopted and, in Stage 2, thisaction sends economic signals to the local, statewide, regional, and nationaleconomies, indicating a change in the economic role of the affected resources.The signals have four major destinations, represented by the four types ofcompeting demands for the resources, as indicated in Figure 1-2. AlthoughFigure 2-1 shows Stages 1 and 2 occurring as a single, abrupt event, they gen-erally transpire over a longer period.

Stages 3 and 4 of Figure 2-1 illustrate the dynamic character of the economyÕsresponse to the adoption of the restrictions. In Stage 3, the economy responds

with changes in prices or incomes orboth. In Stage 4, prices and incomesreach their new levels, and the econ-omy exhibits the long-run effects of theresource conservation initiative. Thelong-run adjustment may entail feed-back loops, through which changes inprices and incomes may influencefuture resource-management decisions.

How long does the transitionÑStages 3and 4Ñtake? There is no single, simple

answer. There are good reasons, however, to believe that many aspects of theeconomy are adjusting more quickly than in the past to changes in resource-management policy. For example, by the middle of 1997, lumber pricesthroughout the U.S. had stabilized in response to the April 1994 adoption ofdrastic logging reductions. This was far quicker than many industry analystshad expected (Bernton, 1997). Labor markets also are dynamic. Power (1996)reports that, of the workers nationwide who lost their jobs because of plantclosures or other mass layoffs in the 1980s, about half were unemployed 10weeks later and the percent remaining unemployed after twelve months wasroughly the same as the background rate of unemployment in the overall laborforce. In the 1990s, workers apparently adjusted more quickly and, toward theend of the decade, most displaced workers found replacement jobs within a fewweeks and about half of those found replacement jobs with equivalent orhigher wages (Helwig, 2001; Ilg, 1996).

This is not to say that everyone adjusts this quickly, or that the costs ofadjusting to resource conservation initiatives are trivial. Instead, we are only

Restrictions on resource-degradingactivities will not have a single, one-time-only impact on the economy .Instead, the economy’ s responsewill evolve over time. Whatever theinitial, negative impacts, theeconomy will attempt to mitigate,and whatever the initial, positiveimpacts, it will try to accentuate.

Page 33: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 23

Figure 2-1: The General T ransition Process by Which a ResourceConservation Initiative Leads to Changes in the Economy

Stage 1: A community acts to adopt and implement a resource conservation initiative

Stage 2: The change in resource-management practices, and theprocess leading to it, sends signals to four groups:

Those whobenefit from the

dominantcommercial use

absent theinitiative

Those associatedwith competing

commercial usesof the resources,

absent theinitiative

Those whoexperience a

change in qualityof life frominitiative

Those whoexperience achange in the

resources’intrinsic value

Stage 4: The economy reaches its long-run transformation:

Change ineconomicstructure

Change in totalemployment,income, etc.

Change indistribution ofemployment,income, etc.

Change ineconomicwelfare

Stage 3: The economy responds to the signals:

Prices change. Incomes change. Local quality of life changes. Buyersand sellers alter their consumption patterns. Firms and households

alter their locational patterns.

Page 34: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 24 ECONorthwest

pointing out that adjusting to change is one of the widely-trumpeted virtues ofmarket economies. To understand the economic consequences triggered by con-servation initiatives, one must take this dynamism into account. Ignoring itinvariably leads to exaggerated estimates of job losses and unrealistic predic-tions of economic catastrophe.

RELEVANT AUTONOMOUS TRENDS

The precise path through the transition will depend not just on the character-istics of the restrictions on logging and related activities but also on the multi-ple economic forces and trends that are continuously altering and shaping theeconomy at all levels. Three of these seem especially important:11

¥ Increasing importance of education;

¥ Increasing integration of metropolitan and nonmetropolitaneconomies;

¥ Rising demand for consumer amenities.

The three are closely related, and define fundamental changes throughout theWest. In past decades, workers could increase their expected earnings by locat-ing near an exploitable resource, such as a mineral deposit about to be mined.Mines, sawmills and other resource-exploitation industries located in ruralcommunities, and supported high wages for unskilled workers. Such industrieswere deemed so crucial to the economy that people accepted the pollution andecosystem degradation they caused.

Today, though, things are different. It is more important for a worker to havea good education than to locate near a particular industry. With the expansionof global trade, U.S. producers of commodity products often no longer com-mand the premium prices and their workers no longer receive the premiumwages they once did. Economic activity is increasingly concentrated in metro-

politan areas, and improved roads andcommunication systems have reducedthe economic isolation of smaller com-munities. Virtually everyone has lesstolerance for the pollution, degradedstreams, and unattractive landscapesassociated with extractive and develop-ment activities. Moreover, communitiesand firms of all types are learning thatthey have difficulty attracting and

The three trends are closely related,and define fundamental changesthroughout the W est. If they hold,workers and communities seeking toprosper will increasingly have tolook for opportunities other thanthose that entail the extraction anddevelopment of natural resources.

11For a more detailed discussion of these trends, see ECONorthwest (1996) and Niemi, Gall andJohnston (1999).

Page 35: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 25

keeping skilled workers if the environment is degraded and the quality of lifeis low.

If these trends hold, workers and communities seeking to prosper will increas-ingly have to look for opportunities other than those that entail the extractionand development of natural resources. Hence, throughout the West strong eco-nomic pressures will push once-dominant industries from the economyÕs centerstage to its periphery. They will continue as an important part of the economy,but will not be a major source of new jobs and higher incomes.

FEEDBACK TO THE ECOSYSTEM

As we argue above, a resource conservation initiative may affect the geo-graphic distribution of the human population as well as its consumption andproduction behavior. These changes, in turn, will affect the ecosystem which,in turn, will have further effects on the economy, and so forth. Of particularconcern is the potential for a feedback loop in which resource conservationyields enhanced consumption amenities, which induce development, whichdegrades the amenity, which reduces the amenitiesÕ value.

This outcome is not that different from the one that occurs when an extractiveindustry operates without having to bear the full costs of its impacts on theenvironment. If there is no market or regulatory mechanism to rein inamenity-based development the resulting demand for the amenities willexceed the optimal level. If competitive market conditions and fully specifiedproperty rights do not exist to provide this regulation more or less automati-cally, through Adam SmithÕs Òinvisible hand,Ó then it must come throughdeliberate societal management and regulation.

REFLECTIONS

The preceding discussion describes the myriad ways in which an economy canadjust to a resource conservation initiative. For the most part, these adjust-ments will take place unseen and incrementally as individuals, households,investors, landowners, business managers, and public entities react to the ini-tiative in their own way, in pursuit of their own objectives.

One should not assume, however, that a community necessarily must sit backand let the transition occur on its own, powerless to influence its direction. Tothe contrary, communities throughout the West have demonstrated that theycan, through concerted action, enhance their ability to capitalize on economictransitions stemming from resource conservation initiatives.

One of the most important steps communities can take to manage the transi-tion is to ensure wide dispersal of accurate information about what the transi-tion will, and will not, entail. Because many people will view a resource

Page 36: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 26 ECONorthwest

conservation initiative through the lenses of the economic-base model, theywill anticipate that it will have only adverse impacts on the economy and failto see the positive potential. To the extent this occurs, the community will failto look for, recognize, and seize opportunities to capitalize on the positiveimpacts. By making disseminating information about the full range of poten-

tial impacts, a community can help itsmembers make better decisions abouthow the initiative will affect them.

Other steps that may be relevantinclude developing the physical andsocial infrastructure appropriate fornew commercial activities that mightbe induced by the initiative. If the ini-tiative entails plans to repair ecologicaldamage from past activities, for exam-ple, it might be appropriate to ensurethat workers have relevant training,and the entities that will oversee the

restoration effort are prepared to develop efficient contractual relationshipswith vendors. If the initiative enhances opportunities for outdoor recreation,the community might take actions to facilitate recreational use and ensurethat the local economy is prepared to sell appropriate goods and services tousers. It the initiative will protect scenic vistas from development, it may beappropriate to ensure that the vistas remain visible from different neighbor-hoods or public facilities.

In sum, there is much that individuals, firms, and communities as a whole cando to improve the economic outcome from a resource conservation initiative.Thoughtful, deliberate action can make the negative impacts smaller and thepositive impacts larger than they otherwise would be.

One should not assume, however ,that a community necessarily mustsit back and let the transition occuron its own, powerless to influenceits direction. T o the contrary ,communities throughout the W esthave demonstrated that they can,through concerted action, enhancetheir ability to capitalize oneconomic transitions stemming fromresource conservation initiatives.

Page 37: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 27

POTENTIAL ECONOMIC BENEFITS OFSONORAN DESERT CONSERVATION

The discussion in the preceding chapters outlines the various mechanisms bywhich conservation of natural resources in the West can alter the values of thegoods and services derived from the resources and influence the jobs, incomes,and economic structures of local and regional economies. Here, we build onthis foundation to provide an initial, preliminary description of the potentialeconomic benefits of resource conservation in the Sonoran Desert. As in thepreceding chapters, we apply a broad definition of economic benefits, embrac-ing the range of potential, positive economic effects illustrated in Figure 3-1.Thus, we embrace outcomes where conservation would increase the value ofthe resources themselves, generate cost savings for local residents, generatejobs and incomes, and reinforce efforts to accomplish other goals.

We emphasize that our description is necessarily rough and incomplete. Fewstudies have addressed even narrow slices of the relationship between thisareaÕs environment and its economy and, to our knowledge, nobody has previ-ously assembled a comprehensive description of the potential economic bene-fits of resource conservation in the Sonoran region. Accordingly, our objectivesare limited. We aim, first and foremost, to describe the set of potential eco-nomic benefits from resource conservation in the Sonoran Desert. Where thereare supportive data and studies, we also discuss the possible magnitude ofindividual, potential benefits.

INCREASED SUPPLY OF VALUABLE

NATURAL RESOURCES

The most direct economic benefits from resource conservation initiatives in theSonoran Desert would result from an increase in the supply of the resourcesthemselves. A successful initiative that protects, maintains, and restores thedesertÕs natural resources would increase the quantity of native resources andlandscapes, their quality, or both. To the extent that the resources have valueto residents of the desert, visitors, or others, then the increase in quantity orquality would represent real economic benefits.

These economic benefits could materialize in many different ways. Some peo-ple would place an intrinsic value on protecting, maintaining, and restoringthe resources and landscapes, concluding that the conservation initiative isbeneficial insofar as it increases the probability that their children, grandchil-dren, and others of future generations will be able to see the desert in essen-tially the same condition. Others will see benefits from enhancements in therecreational opportunities and aesthetic characteristics resulting fromresource conservation.

Chapter 3

Page 38: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 28 ECONorthwest

Figure 3-1: Conservation of Natural Resources in the Sonoran Desert Can Yield Many Economic Benefits

Sonoran DesertConservation

Increased Supply of V aluable Natural Resources• Conservation can protect and enhance the intrinsic values of

native species and landscapes, relative to what would existabsent conservation

• Conservation of native species and landscapes can providerecreational and aesthetic benefits

Savings for T axpayers, Utility Ratepayers, and Property Owners• Protecting at-risk species and landscapes can be cheaper

than restoring them after they’ve become degraded

• Conservation can retard urban sprawl and reduce theassociated costs

• Conservation can enhance values of nearby property byprotecting natural open space, reducing flood-related risks,preventing subsidence from depletion of groundwater, etc.

Stronger Local Economy: More Jobs & Higher Incomes• High-quality natural resource amenities can lead to a more

diverse economy, more jobs, and higher incomes

• Reining in activities that are wasteful of native species andlandscapes and/or impose spillover costs on other industriesand households can make the economy more efficient andproductive

Reinforcement of Efforts to Accomplish Other Goals• Conservation can contribute to improvements in public health

by encouraging healthier lifestyles and discouraging harmfulpollution

• Conservation can reinforce efforts to promote social cohesionamong different groups, neighborhoods, and communities

Page 39: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 29

INTRINSIC BENEFITS OF NATIVE SPECIES

AND LANDSCAPES

One primary objective of most resource conservation initiatives is to protectand enhance the intrinsic values of native species, ecosystems, and landscapes.Considerable evidence indicates that such values can be substantial, though itis analytically difficult to quantify them.12

One category of intrinsic values is associated with the spiritual and culturalroles natural resources play in the lives of the regionÕs Indian people. Thedetails of these roles can vary for different natural resources and from tribe totribe. In some instances, however, the individual resources, as well as theoverall ecosystems, affected by a conservation initiative may be integral ele-

ments of a tribeÕs religion and centralto its cultural activities and identity.This relationship seems especially truefor streams and the associated riparianareas.

We know of no estimate of the poten-tial size of the spiritual and relatedvalues that might accrue to Indian peo-ple from conservation initiatives in theSonoran Desert. Indeed, we do notanticipate that any such estimates will

be forthcoming in the foreseeable future, as determining such benefits is adaunting challenge, conceptually and practically, for it entails answering suchknotty questions as, What is the value of a culture? and What is the value of agroupÕs religion? To many the values are without limit and, insofar as a con-servation initiative would sustain a culture and it religion, the benefits wouldbe priceless.

Native ecosystems and landscapes of the Sonoran Desert, and the biologicaldiversity they foster, make additional, intrinsic contributions to human well-being by providing essential habitat for sensitive plant and animal species.Many Americans consider the Sonoran Desert and its native biological diver-sity to be important national treasures, the loss of which would diminish theirwell-being. The impacts of resource conservation initiatives on the intrinsicvalue of the desertÕs native resources are measurable in principle, but weknow of no research that has applied these principles to these resources.Several related studies, however, demonstrate that the values probably aresubstantial.

“For the many tribes of the aridSouthwest, rivers, streams, andsprings were, and continue to be,the ‘center of existence.’ ... Even forArizona tribes whose presentlocation may not make the riparianconnection obvious, there almostalways is a cultural link.”

Miller and others (1996)

12In the past three decades or so, economists have devoted significant attention to the measurement ofintrinsic values. A vast literature on the subject exists. For an introduction, see Cropper and Oates(1992), Power (1996), and Power and Barrett (2001).

Page 40: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 30 ECONorthwest

Survey research in neighboring New Mexico, for example, found that thestateÕs households indicated they were willing, on average, to pay $30 per yearfor five years to protect the minimum instream flows needed to prevent extinc-tion of a small fish in the Rio Grande. Respondents to the survey further indi-cated they were willing to pay $79 per year over the period to provideminimum streamflows in all the stateÕs major rivers (Berrens et al., 1995).Related research found that residents of New Mexico indicated a strong will-ingness to pay to increase the natural streamflow in the stateÕs rivers andstreams: more than 80 percent of respondents to a survey indicated a willing-ness to pay about $80 to increase streamflows (Berrens et al., 1998).

Similar results have been found elsewhere, documenting the values the publicplaces on protecting at-risk species and desert land. Ekstrand and Loomis(1998), for example, found that U.S, households responding to a survey indi-cated a willingness to pay $50-330 per year to protect habitat critical to thesurvival of at-risk fish in the Southwest, including habitat along the GilaRiver. Researchers in the Pacific Northwest (Hagen et al., 1992) found that theintrinsic value benefits of protecting the old-growth forests that provide criti-cal habitat for the Northern Spotted Owl far exceeded the costs. Loomis andEkstrand (1997) found that U.S. households were willing to pay an average of$40.49 to protect the Mexican Spotted Owl and its 4.6 million acres of criticalhabitat in Arizona, New Mexico, Colorado, and Utah. Richer (1995) found thatCalifornia residents indicated they were willing to spend $177-448 million per

year to support legislation to protect6.9 million acres of the stateÕs desertlands.

We report these results not to implythat residents of Arizona and otherstates are willing to spend the sameamounts to protect at-risk species,streamflows, and desert lands in theSonoran Desert. Indeed, we caution

readers that the results cannot be transferred from one setting to the anotherwithout further, careful research to confirm the validity of doing so.Nonetheless, the research findings from these other settings strongly indicatethat Arizonans, as well as Americans in other states, place considerable eco-nomic importance on protecting the intrinsic values of at-risk species,instream flows, and desert landscapes in the Sonoran Desert.

Ecological research further supports the importance of focusing resource con-servation initiatives on protecting lands and waters that have not been sub-stantially altered by human activities. A recent study of eight native troutspecies in the Inland West, for example, found they currently occupy less than5 percent of their former ranges and that the remaining strongholds arestrongly concentrated on roadless areas. This conclusion is especially true forone of the species, the Gila Trout, native to Arizona: it currently occupies only

The research findings from theseother settings strongly indicate thatArizonans, as well as Americans inother states, place considerableeconomic importance on protectingthe intrinsic values of at-riskspecies, instream flows, and desertlandscapes in the Sonoran Desert.

Page 41: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 31

0.7 percent of its historical range and all of the remining strongholds are onroadless areas (Kessler et al., 2001).

Conservation of natural resources in the Sonoran Desert also might maintainor restore natural hydrographs in streams. Relative to developed areas, thesoils of conserved areas might retain more water when it rains, releasing thewater and creating higher stream flows during dry periods. Increases in basestreamflows are valuable for their sustenance of aquatic species and riparian(streamside) habitats for numerous native plants and animals. These areasare especially important ecologically. A recent summary of the relevant litera-ture (Finch et al., 1995) reported:

¥ In the Southwest, the highest richness of bird species and density ofindividuals occurs in riparian ecosystems.

¥ Of 166 bird species in the region from southern Arizona to westTexas, 51 percent were completely dependent and another 20 percentwere partially dependent on riparian habitat.

¥ Loss of riparian habitat in the Southwest could result in the regionalextinction of 47 percent of the 166 bird species that breed in the region.

A study of the Hassayampa River Preserve, near Wickenburg, Arizona, shortlyafter it was established to protect one of ArizonaÕs few remaining cottonwood-willow forests and mesquite bosques, provides some evidence of the economicvalue of protected natural areas (Crandall et al., 1992). The researchers foundthat visitors associated the areaÕs value with the extent of its streamflows. Ifits perennial flows were to deteriorate and become intermittent, the dimin-ished flows plus the resulting shift in riparian vegetation would cause the areato lose 80 percent of its economic value.

RECREATIONAL AND AESTHETIC BENEFITS

Increases in opportunities for recreational use constitute a considerable por-tion of the economic benefits that resource conservation initiatives in theSonoran Desert would generate. Native landscapes in the desert provideuncommon opportunities for recreation, and these opportunities yield directbenefits to users, as well as commercial opportunities for outfitters and otherswho sell goods and services to recreationists.

Researchers from the University of Arizona recently studied the potentialrecreational benefits of resource conservation in Arizona, focusing on tourismrelated to bird-watching in Ramsey Canyon Preserve and the San PedroNational Conservation Area, near the city of Sierra Vista (Leones and Colby,1998). They concluded that nature-based tourism, and especially visitors toRamsey Canyon, generated $1 million in value-added activity in the SierraVista area. Furthermore, nature-based tourists spend about $13 per person,

Page 42: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 32 ECONorthwest

per day more than visitors not oriented toward bird-watching and othernature-based interests.

Additional insight into the value of protecting open space in the SonoranDesert can be obtained from studies elsewhere. The data in Table 1-1, forexample, shows the values associated with different recreational activities onfederal lands in the interior Columbia River Basin. The values per recre-ational userÐday are not transferable to the Sonoran Desert without furtherresearch. Nonetheless, the data indicate the general magnitude of recreationalbenefits that can be obtained from resource conservation initiatives in theWest. The research in the interior Columbia Basin has further interestbecause it showed that unroaded, wild areas generate additional recreationaland other (including intrinsic) values that are roughly double the correspon-ding values of roaded areas. Also important, the research indicates that recre-

ational values are expected to increasesignificantly relative to the values ofextractive and development uses of fed-eral lands (Haynes and Horne, 1997).

Other research confirms the potentialbenefit Americans can derive fromresource conservation initiatives thatsustain wilderness areas, i.e., wild-lands protected from roads, extractive

industry, and development. These studies have analyzed two types of benefits:the enhanced value of future recreational use of the wildlands; and the intrin-sic value of ensuring that the lands would remain accessible to the public butundeveloped.

About two dozen studies have examined the recreation-related benefits ofwilderness in the U.S.13 On average, they indicate that each visitor sees adayÕs visit to a wilderness area as being worth about $40 more than it costs totravel to the area.

Two other studies estimated the combined recreational and intrinsic valuebenefits that would materialize from increasing the amount of wilderness inColorado and Utah.14 They found that increasing the amount of wilderness inColorado by 1.2 million acres and in Utah by 2.7 million acres initially wouldyield benefits worth about $1,250 and $409 per acre, respectively. With theprospect of further expansion of wilderness, the benefits per additional acrewould decline, to about $220 per acre in Colorado and $120 per acre in Utah.

Loomis (2000) focuses on just the intrinsic value of wilderness lands in west-ern states, outside Alaska. Distilling relevant studies, he estimates that theselands typically have an intrinsic value of $168 per acre.

About two dozen studies haveexamined the recreation-relatedbenefits of wilderness in the U.S. Onaverage, they indicate that eachvisitor sees a day’ s visit to awilderness area as being worthabout $40 more than it costs totravel to the area.

13Summarized in Loomis (2000).

14Walsh (1984), and Pope (1990). These and other related studies are summarized in Loomis (2000).

Page 43: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 33

One should use these estimates cautiously, recognizing the inherent difficul-ties in applying to the Sonoran Desert values derived elsewhere. Manyunknown variables might make the benefits here higher or lower than thosefound in other ecosystems and economies. The results from these studies do,however, demonstrate that, in general, the recreational and intrinsic valuesassociated with leaving lands in a wilderness status can yield significant eco-nomic benefits. There is no apparent reason why this general finding wouldnot apply to wildlands in the Sonoran Desert. The actual benefits from conser-vation initiatives that would leave individual acreage in a wilderness-like sta-tus could be higher or lower than those found elsewhere, but it is highlyunlikely that they would be zero.

Conservation initiatives resulting in increased streamflows can yield economicbenefits that are surprisingly large. Hansen and Hallam (1990), for example,compared the economic benefits of the additional opportunities for recreationalfishing that would result from leaving water in a stream versus the benefits ofwithdrawing the water to irrigate crops. For central and southern Arizona,they found that an acre-foot of water used for irrigation had essentially a zeroeconomic benefit, that is, the value of the crop produced by the irrigation wasless than the cost of producing it.15 In contrast, leaving the acre-foot of waterin the stream would generate 150 angler-days of recreational fishing, with aneconomic value of about $3,000, in todayÕs dollars. Increases in streamflows

also generally are viewed as beingmore aesthetically attractive, althoughthe attractiveness declines withextremely high flows (Brown andDaniel, 1991).

The results from these studies areimportant not just for evaluatingresource conservation initiatives thatwould shift water from irrigation to

instream flows. They also provide insights into the potential benefits of initia-tives that would increase instream flows by reducing diversions for municipal-industrial use and by preventing land-use activities that alter the naturalhydrograph by accelerating runoff during wet seasons, reducing infiltration,and, hence, curtailing stream flows during dry seasons.

SAVINGS FOR TAXPAYER, UTILITY RATEPAYERS,AND PROPERTY OWNERS

Depending on their scope, design, and location, resource conservation initia-tives in the Sonoran Desert can yield numerous savings for taxpayers, utilityratepayers, and property owners throughout the region. Three common mecha-

These studies demonstrate therecreational and intrinsic valuesassociated with leaving lands in awilderness status can yieldsignificant economic benefits. Thereis no apparent reason why thisgeneral finding would not apply towildlands in the Sonoran Desert.

15An acre-foot of water is the amount that would cover one acre of land one foot deep. It is equal to about329,000 gallons.

Page 44: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 34 ECONorthwest

nisms for producing these benefits are reduced costs for managing at-riskspecies and landscapes, avoiding costs associated with urban sprawl, and cre-ating spillover increases in property values for nearby lands.

BENEFITS FROM PROTECTING VS. RESTORING

AT-RISK SPECIES AND LANDSCAPES

With proper planning, conservation initiatives can be the most cost-effectiveway for residents of the Sonoran Desert to accomplish environmental and eco-nomic goals. Examples of the opportunities are numerous. Acting early to pre-vent the degradation of native habitat for an at-risk species is cheaper thanhesitating, allowing the habitat to be degraded, and then paying to reverse thedegradation. The same is true if communities want to protect lands, such ashilltops, ridgelines, and streamside corridors, that help define the communityÕsaesthetic character.

Despite (or perhaps because of) the obvious nature of the savings that can berealized through anticipatory conservation initiatives, quantification of thepotential savings associated with different types of initiatives is hard, evenimpossible to find. One illustration of the potential savings, however, comesfrom recent assessments of the road system in the nationÕs national forests.With more than 400,000 miles of roads, the national forests now face a backlogof more than $8 billion in maintenance costs, an amount that does not includethe collateral costs, such as risks to human lives and downstream flooding,that could materialize from potential road failures. Taxpayers and nearby,

e.g., downstream, landowners eventu-ally will have to shoulder these costs,unless the roads are decommissionedthrough an appropriately designed con-servation initiative at less cost (PacificRivers Council, 2000).

A more local example comes fromunsustainable pumping of groundwa-ter, which can result in a lowering ofthe water table and land subsidence.16

Lowering of the water table, which hasfallen more than 100 feet in someplaces, increases the costs of further

pumping, and removes water that helps buoy the land above it. The resultingland subsidence currently occurs in more than 3,000 square miles of Arizona,including the Tucson and Phoenix areas, and, in the extreme case, has causedsurface levels to subside 18 feet. Any subsidence can cause damage, especiallywhen it occurs unevenly, scrambling the support for homes, roadways, bridges,

Acting early to prevent thedegradation of native habitat for anat-risk species is cheaper thanhesitating, allowing the habitat to bedegraded, and then paying toreverse the degradation. The sameis true if communities want toprotect lands, such as hilltops,ridgelines, and streamside corridors,that help define the community’ saesthetic character .

16Except where otherwise indicated, the discussion in this paragraph and the next are derived fromPhysicians for Social Responsibility (2001).

Page 45: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 35

natural-gas pipelines, and other infrastructure. Other researchers have notedthat preventing land subsidence by maintaining groundwater levels in theTucson area will yield economic benefits, but those benefits have not beenquantified. As a point of comparison, cost estimates of the damage from 8 feetof land subsidence in CaliforniaÕs Santa Clara Valley ranged from $15 millionto $131 million (Al-Sabbry et al., 2002).

A related example comes from the extension of arroyos, as inappropriate graz-ing and land-use patterns heighten the runoff from rainfall events and chan-nel it into arroyos, where the higher flows accelerate erosion that deepens andwidens the arroyos. The flow of mud downstream worsens flood risks, whilethe deepening arroyos can drain aquifers.

BENEFITS FROM REINING IN THE COSTS

OF URBAN SPRAWL

Poorly designed and implemented urban development can increase the overallcosts of providing public services and conducting private-sector commerce.Leapfrog development, for example, can increase the costs of tying togetherdifferent neighborhoods into efficient systems for municipal water, sewagetreatment, stormwater management, public parks, and the like. The net resultis lower levels of service, higher taxes and utility bills, or all three.

Resource conservation initiatives may be able to help curtail these inefficiencies.Conserved native landscapes might serve double duty as parks so a communitycan avoid the costs of converting already developed land into parks. Or theymight serve as an integral element of a region-wide effort to manage stormwater.

At a more fundamental level, conservation initiatives might help shape thepattern of development so that, over time, the overall region can realize costsavings. This outcome might materialize, for example, from an initiative toprotect and enhance the native vegetation in riparian (streamside) zones. Aswe explain above, these areas are critically important to the desertÕs ecosys-

tems and, hence, typically rate a highpriority in conservation proposals. Notincidentally, developers often like tolocate housing and other developmentsin these areas, however, to take advan-tage of their natural attractiveness. It

is not uncommon to see urban sprawl extend outward from urban centersalong these corridors. Unfortunately, development in riparian areas not onlycan cause greater ecological damage it also can alter streamflowsÑe.g., whendevelopers narrow the stream channel, thus causing storm runoff to movefaster and at higher speedsÑand result in greater risks and damage for down-stream landowners and taxpayers. To the extent that a conservation initiativefor protecting the native characteristics of riparian zones would prevent suchdevelopments, it also would reduce the costs of urban sprawl in these areas.

Conservation initiatives might helpshape the pattern of development sothat, over time, the overall regioncan realize cost savings.

Page 46: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 36 ECONorthwest

The extent of the potential benefits from such interactions between conserva-tion initiatives and the costs of sprawl has not been quantified. Pima County,however, has recently issued a series of reports documenting some of thepotential costs that taxpayers will incur if the county is not successful inarresting, or at least slowing, recent patterns of sprawl-like development inunincorporated areas. One of the reports (Distribution of Fiscal Resources) con-cludes, ÒIt does Pima County no good to accommodate population in the ruraland exurban areas where the lack of infrastructure keeps the tax base benefitof development very low, and the service demand that Pima County incurscosts more than the development will ever be able to return in revenue.Ó Thepotential interaction between the countyÕs desire to avoid further sprawl andits efforts to conserve high-priority elements of the Sonoran DesertÕs ecosys-tems have yet to be seen. In concept, though, some elements of the conserva-tion plan might help the county rein in the uncontrolled costs of sprawl andaccomplish its fiscal objectives.

BENEFITS FOR NEARBY PROPERTIES

Location, location, location. This mantra of real estate valuation captures anessential fact: the value of a parcel is strongly influenced by what is around it.Many characteristics of the surrounding properties can be important and theirnatural character can be among the most important. The value of residentialproperties, for example, is higher when they look out on scenic vistas of hill-tops with native vegetation than on industrial activity or on the rooftops and

alleyways of subdivisions. Recent news-paper reports from throughout theWest, for example, have reported con-cerns that industrial activity associatedwith oil/gas development markedlyreduces property values in the areaÑrealtors in Colorado have estimated areduction of 60 percent, according toone account.17

The influence that natural landscapes exert on the value of nearby propertiescan be substantial. For example, a recent study in the Tucson area, describedin the text box on the following page, found that houses within .5 miles of adesert riparian corridor sold at prices 3 to 6 percent higher than other compa-rable houses. One survey of the literature (Brabec, 1992) offers these addi-tional illustrative findings:

¥ A study in Seattle found that houses near a bike/hiking trail sell for 6percent more than more distant, similar houses.

Location, location, location. Thismantra of real estate valuationcaptures an essential fact: the valueof a parcel is strongly influenced bywhat is around it. The naturalcharacteristics of surroundingproperties can be among the mostimportant.

17Scott McMillon. 2002. ÒColorado Real Estate Agents Blame Gas Drilling for Lost Value.Ó BozemanChronicle. 9 January. http://news.mywebpal.com/partners/311/public/news235254.html

Page 47: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 37

¥ A study in Salem, Oregon, found that urban land adjacent to a green-belt was worth $1,200 more per acre than similar land 1,000 feet away.

¥ A study in Boulder, Colorado, found that house prices declined $2.20for each foot of distance from a greenbelt. Houses adjacent to thegreenbelt were valued 32 percent higher than comparable houses3,000 feet away.

¥ A study in Massachusetts found that houses within 20 feet or so of apark were worth $2,675 more than similar houses 2,000 feet away.The relationship was reversed, however, if the park were heavilyused and congested.

As we indicate elsewhere, it would beinappropriate to apply these numbers,without further corroborative research,to estimate the value of open space orother attributes in the Sonoran Desert.The numbers do, however, confirm thatproximity to open space and naturallands can significantly increase thevalue of nearby properties, and, unlessreal estate markets in the SonoranDesert operate in an unforeseen man-ner, a similar relationship undoubtedlyapplies here.

Conservation activities may also affectthe values of nearby properties byreducing erosion associated with agri-cultural, industrial, or urban activities.No study of this relationship has beencompleted for the Sonoran Desert, buta national study completed more thana decade ago indicates the potentialbenefits of reducing erosion can be sub-stantial.

In the study (Ribaudo, 1989) an econo-mist with the Department ofAgriculture found that, within theMountain region that includes Arizona,each ton of sediment prevented fromentering streams generated off-site,i.e., downstream, economic benefits ofabout $1.60 (adjusted to 2000 dollars)that would accrue to landowners andother water users. This amount repre-

A recent study of residential propertyvalues near riparian corridors in onearea of Northeast T ucson found thatriparian areas provide measurableeconomic benefits to nearbylandowners.

• Homes within 1.5 miles of a ripariancorridor commanded higher salesprices than comparable homes.

• Homes within .5 miles of a ripariancorridor were valued three to sixpercent higher than othercomparable homes, accounting forthe effects of lot and home size andother factors.

• For the 25,560 homes in the areastudied, the property value premiumattributable to the riparian corridoramounted to over $103 million.

• Vacant land near the ripariancorridor was valued 10 to 27 percenthigher than other vacant land.

The researchers attributed theseresults, in part, to landowner benefitsfrom natural amenities associatedwith riparian areas. Birds, wildlife,trees, and other natural vegetationprovide scenic views, open space,opportunities for wildlife viewing anda buffer from urban noise. Riparianareas also provide shade, whichlowers cooling costs, and maintainthe water table, which benefitsexisting well owners.

Page 48: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 38 ECONorthwest

sents several types of benefits, including avoided costs that resulted fromreducing the amount of sediment clogging waterways and causing flood dam-age downstream. The estimate underrepresents the true benefits of preventingsedimentation, insofar as it does not include the on-site benefits of keepingsoils in place, or the benefits associated with protecting at-risk speciesadversely affected by abnormally high sedimentation rates. The estimate alsodoes not reflect increases in the value of preventing soil erosion and protectingwater quality that have materialized since the study was completed. Theseincreases would reflect, for example, subsequent increases in human popula-tions that would be affected by reductions in sedimentation.

STRONGER LOCAL ECONOMY: MORE JOBS &HIGHER INCOMES

Resource conservation initiatives can generate jobs and incomes directly,through expenditures on designing and implementing resource protection andrestoration activities. The extent of this impact has received little attention inthe Sonoran Desert, largely because there has been so little experience withconservation initiatives in this region. Studies of restoration programs else-where, however, indicate that they can generate jobs for thousands of workers(Pacific Rivers Council, 1995; U.S. Environmental Protection Agency and U.S.Army Corps of Engineers, 1994).

More significant impacts on jobs, incomes, and the structure of the economycan materialize indirectly, as the conservation initiatives affect the supply ofresource-related amenities, and hence, amenity-related growth, as well as theefficiency of resource uses.

AMENITY-RELATED GROWTH

As we explain in the previous chapters, a growing body of evidence indicatesthat the protection of a regionÕs environmental amenities can provide animportant stimulus to local economic development. Opportunities for recre-ation in native ecosystems are particularly important. Areas that are currentlyprotected, in national forests and national parks, meet some of this recre-ational demand, but as these protected areas become increasingly congested,the protection of additional public lands becomes increasingly important.

Rudzitis and others (1995) compared the rates of population growth in coun-ties near protected areasÑwilderness areas or national parksÑwith those ofother counties in the West. They found that, during the 1980s, the populationsof counties with wilderness increased nearly twice as fast as other nonmetro-politan counties in the West, and six times faster than the national averagefor nonmetropolitan counties. When recent in-migrants to nonmetropolitancounties with wilderness areas were asked why they moved, the answers over-whelmingly indicated the importance of protected, natural landscapes

Page 49: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 39

(Rudzitis, 1999). Asked to identify one or more reasons for moving to the area,respondents identified the scenery (72 percent), environmental quality (65 per-cent), and opportunities for outdoor recreation (59 percent).

Similar results come from an analysis of state parks (Duffy-Deno, 1997).Looking at 250 non-metropolitan counties in the Intermountan West, thestudy found that, all else constant, a 10 percent higher density of state parklands was, in the long run, correlated with 1.4 and 2.3 percent higher popula-

tions and employment densities. Thisconclusion is reinforced by a study thatsurveyed senior officials of businessesthat had recently been started,expanded, or relocated in Colorado(Crompton et al., 1997). The studyfound that quality of life, representedby recreational opportunities, parks,and open space, was among the mostimportant determinants of business-location decisions.

One cannot say that exactly the sameoutcomes would arise if conservationinitiatives increased the amount ofwilderness area and park lands in theSonoran Desert. It is safe to conclude,

however, that judicious, well-planned protection of unroaded areas in theregion probably would, over time, be associated with more robust economicgrowth. The same is true of initiatives to increase the number of parks. To theextent that these outcomes are considered desirable, then they should be seenas economic benefits of conservation.

BENEFITS FROM MORE EFFICIENT USE

OF RESOURCES

Resource conservation initiatives also can stimulate local economic prosperityby rationalizing the use of scarce resources. As we demonstrate in the previouschapters, mounting evidence indicates that the economic value of native west-ern resources and landscapes is growing, absolutely and relative to traditionalextractive and development uses. The rise in value occurs as consumersÕ pref-erences for natural amenities increases and as the resources become morescarce. Growth in the value is simulated even more when the scarcity becomesextreme, as when species are threatened with extinction.

If market mechanisms were at work, these rising values would automaticallybut inexorably result in greater conservation of resources and landscapes. Forthe most part, though, market mechanisms do not function well in this arena.As a consequence, resources and landscapes tend to get stuck in sub-optimal

“Our natural landscapes no longergenerate new jobs and incomesprimarily by being warehouses fromwhich loggers, farmers, fishermen,and miners extract commercialproducts. In today’ s world theselandscapes often may generatemore new jobs and income byproviding the natural resourceamenities—water and air quality ,recreational opportunities, scenicbeauty , and fish and wildlife—thatmake the [area] an attractive placeto live, work, and do business.”

Power (1995), endorsed by 64 western economists

Page 50: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 40 ECONorthwest

uses. That is, they are used for extrac-tive industries, subjected to urbandevelopment, or simply ignored andallowed while their native characteris-tics are degraded and higher-value con-servation uses are forgone.

Such outcomes leave an area less pros-perous than it would have been withappropriately designed conservation.This adverse outcome also materializesin more practical terms. As resourcesand landscapes are used suboptimally,and advocates of conservation can find

no effective market mechanisms to promote their interests, they look for alter-natives. In most instances, they must turn to the political arena and, in sodoing they distract the political system from addressing other problems. Theadoption of an appropriately designed conservation initiative can bring actualland uses more in line with the optimum, lessen the pressure on the politicalsystem, and allow the system to turn its attention to other things. The netresult can be a substantial improvement not just in the efficient allocation ofnatural resources and landscapes but also in the functioning of public agencies.

REINFORCEMENT OF EFFORTS TO ACCOMPLISH

OTHER IMPORTANT GOALS

The preceding discussion documents many of the ways in which the naturalresources of the Sonoran Desert are interconnected with the local economy. Itis not surprising, then, that resource conservation initiatives would reinforceefforts to accomplish goals that, at first blush, might not seem related to con-servation. We discuss two of these reinforcing interactions: improvements inpublic health and increases in the social cohesion of local communities.

PUBLIC HEALTH BENEFITS

Resource conservation initiatives can be good for your health. This conclusionis supported by several recent studies, and, though none of them focuses solelyon the Sonoran Desert, it seems safe to say that appropriately designed con-servation initiatives in this region could yield improvements in the health oflocal residents. Among the recent reports are these:

¥ A recent study found that living near natural habitats yields measur-able mental-health benefits for children.18

If market mechanisms were at work,the rising value of native resourcesand landscapes would result ingreater conservation. For the mostpart, though, market mechanisms donot function well in this arena. As aconsequence, resources andlandscapes tend to get stuck in sub-optimal uses, and resourceconservation initiatives are neededto correct the innefficiencies andboost the local economy .

18Reported at www.ens.lycos.com, viewed December 7, 2001.

Page 51: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 41

¥ Obesity has been rising rapidly in the U.S. and more than one-fifth ofadult Americans are now obese (Economist, December 15, 2001, pg.80). Walking more would help reduce obesity, but walking in conven-tionally designed urban areas can entail dangerous exposure to auto-mobile traffic. Among the most dangerous areas for walkers arewestern communities.

¥ More than 50 percent of the outbreaks of waterborne diseases in theU.S. from 1948 to 1994 were preceded by extreme rainfall events.Conventional urban-development patterns can exacerbate theextreme character of rainfall, as the amount of stormwater washingoff a one-acre parking lot is 16 times greater than that of a compara-ble-size grassy area (Jackson and Kochtitzky, 2001).

¥ Conventional urban-development patterns also can exacerbate thehealth effects of poor air quality. For example, in 1996, when Atlantaarea authorities implemented traffic-reduction plans for the summerOlympics, weekday morning traffic counts decreased by 22.5 percent,and asthma emergency medical events decreased by 41.6 percent,although non-asthma medical events did not drop during the sameperiod (Jackson and Kochtitzky, 2001).

Resource conservation initiatives cannot resolve these and other health prob-lems, but they potentially can make a significant contribution. By protectingnatural landscapes visible and/or readily accessible from urban areas, they canhelp residents maintain contact with natural environments that are importantto mental health. By providing safe opportunities for recreational walking andhiking, they can help residents combat the cultural pressures that induce obe-sity and related problems. By reinforcing efforts to rein in urban sprawl, theycan simultaneously help prevent automobile-based threats to air quality.

SOCIAL-COHESION BENEFITS

Well-planned resource conservation initiatives also can influence the degree ofsocial cohesion among different groups within the local community. A jointeffort to protect, clean up, and restore a waterway, for example, might besomething that all groups within a community might support, and create asense of shared community pride and accomplishment. Upon this foundation,the community might then be better prepared to address other challenges.

Several cities in the West, including Boise, Idaho, and San Antonio, Texas,have focused on natural resource conservation to build social cohesion, andmuch can be learned from their experience. Not all conservation targets aregood candidates for building social cohesion, of course, for some of them areaccompanied by cacophonous disharmony. The discord in some instancesshould not blind a community to searching for others that can bring differentgroups together, recognizing their shared interests as neighbors.

Page 52: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 42 ECONorthwest

REFLECTIONS

There can be no doubt that resource conservation initiatives in the SonoranDesert can yield substantial, even priceless economic benefits. In this chapterwe discuss the benefits that appear especially significant at this point in time.Others almost certainly will emerge in the future as more people learn morethings about the desert, and the desertÕs native characteristics more stronglycome to represent life in southern Arizona. Even within the immediate timehorizon, however, we readily acknowledge that resource conservation initia-tives may yield economic benefits other than those we discuss hereÑcontribu-tions to ecological research and protection of cultural heritage linked to thenatural landscape are but just two. Our failure to discusses these and others isnot intended to diminish them, but reflects our concern about keeping thereport readable for an audience with limited patience for economics.

Why discuss the potential economic benefits of conservation at all? There aretwo parts to the answer. The first is that many people and public officials arenot familiar with the emerging relationships between natural resources andeconomic well-being. The lack of familiarity is enhanced further because manyof the economic benefits from conservation lie outside the mechanisms andanalytical frameworks of markets and dollar-denominated prices. Hence, weanticipate that describing the benefits in some detail helps make the relation-ships more easily understandable. In particular, we emphasize that the dis-connect between conservation benefits and markets does not diminish theirimportance in any way and, in many respects, augments it.

The second is that the demand for conservation is rising, making it moreimperative than ever before that the public and its elected officials have a goodunderstanding of the underlying economic issues. By their nature, many of thebenefits of conservation will be less visible than the costs. Besides lying out-side market mechanisms, many of the benefits will not materialize immedi-ately, but only as residents of and visitors to the desert come to appreciatemore fully the interactions between the ecosystem and the economy. Moreover,most people may not be accustomed to recognizing how rapidly the benefits ofconservation can rise, as growth in the human population exerts added, cumu-lative pressures on an often fragile ecosystem, tightening the scarcity of nativespecies, habitats, and landscapes. Against this background, making good con-servation decisions today will be even more important tomorrow.

The 2000 census found that ArizonaÕs population grew 40 percent during theprevious decade, and similar growth is expected into the foreseeable future.Now is the time to ensure that the economic benefits of resource conservationinitiatives for the Sonoran Desert receive full, unbiased consideration.

Page 53: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 43

REFERENCES

Al-Sabbry, M.M., D. Harris, and R. Fox. 2002. ÒAn Economic Assessment ofGround Water Recharge in the Tucson Basin.Ó Journal of the American WaterResources Association 38 (1): 119-131.

Baskin, Y. 1997. The Work of Nature: How the Diversity of Life Sustains Us.Washington, D.C.: Island Press.

Baumol, W.J. and W.E. Oates. 1988. The Theory of Environmental Policy,Second Edition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Beeson, P.E. 1991. ÒAmenities and Regional Differences in Returns to WorkerCharacteristics.Ó Journal of Urban Economics 30: 224-241.

Berger, M.C. and G.C. Blomquist. 1992. ÒMobility and Destination inMigration Decisions: The Roles of Earnings, Quality of Life, and HousingPrices.Ó Journal of Housing Economics 2: 37-59.

Bergland, O. and W.G. Brown. 1988. Multiple Site Travel-Cost Models andConsumer Surplus: Valuation of Oregon Sport-Caught Salmon. Oregon StateUniversity, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. May 20.

Bernton, H. 1997. ÒLumber Market Reaches New Equilibrium.Ó Portland:Oregonian, September 8. Page E1.

Berrens, R.P., A.K. Bohara, H. Jenkins-Smith, C.L. Silva, P. Ganderton, andD. Brookshire. 1998. ÒA Joint Investigation of Public Support and PublicValues: Case of Instream Flows in New Mexico.Ó Ecological Economics 27: 189-203.

Berrens, R.P., P. Ganderton, and C. Silva. 1995. Valuing the Protection ofMinimum Instream Flows in New Mexico. Presented at the annual conferenceof the New Mexico Riparian Council, September 18, 1995, in Albuquerque.

Blomquist, G.C., M.C. Berger, and J.P. Hoehn. 1988. ÒNew Estimates ofQuality of Life in Urban Areas.Ó American Economic Review 78 (1): 89-107.

Brabec, Elizabeth. 1992. On the Value of Open Spaces. Scenic America.

Brady, P. 1995. Interregional Compensating Differentials and Incentives toMigrate: A Study of Locational Decisions by Young Adults. University ofWisconsin-Madison, Department of Economics. November 8.

Bray, L.G. 1980. ÒA Model of Local Sector Growth in the South.Ó Ph.D.Dissertation. University of Tennessee.

Page 54: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 44 ECONorthwest

Brown, G. and R. Mendelsohn. 1982. The Hedonic-Travel Cost Method.Department of Economics, University of Washington. October.

Brown, R.J. 1994. ÒDo Locational Amenities Equalize Utility Across States?ÓThe Journal of Economics XX (1): 25-30.

Brown, T.C. and D. Binkley. 1994. Effect of Management on Water Quality inNorth American Forests. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service,Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. General TechnicalReport RM-248. June.

Brown, T.C. and T.C. Daniel. 1991. ÒLandscape Aesthetics of RiparianEnvironments: Relationship of Flow Quantity to Scenic Quality Along a Wildand Scenic River.Ó Water Resources Research 27 (8): 1787-1795.

Browne, L.E. 1984. ÒHow Different Are Regional Wages? A Second Look.Ó NewEngland Economic Review (March/April): 40-47.

Colby, B. and S. Wishart. 2002. Riparian Areas Generate Property ValuePremium for Landowners. College of Agriculture and Life Sciences. January.

Cooper, J.M.R. 1994. ÒMigration and Market Wage Risk.Ó Journal of RegionalScience 34 (4): 563-582.

Courant, P.N., E. Niemi, and W.E Whitelaw. 1997. An Analytic Typology forExamining the Economic Effects of Ecosystem Management. University ofMichigan, School of Public Policy.http://www.spp.umich.edu/spp/papers/courant/index.html. #407.

Courant, P.N., E. Niemi, and W.E. Whitelaw. 1997b. The Ecosystem-EconomyRelationship: Insights from Six Forested LTER Sites. ECONorthwest. A Reportto the National Science Foundation. Grant No. DEB-9416809. November.

Crandall, K., B. Colby, and K. Rait. 1992. ÒValuing Riparian Areas: ASouthwestern Case Study.Ó Rivers 3 (2): 88-98.

Cromartie, J.B. 1998. ÒNet Migration in the Great Plains Increasingly Linkedto Natural Amenities and Suburbanization.Ó Rural Development Perspectives13 (1): 27-34.

Cromartie, John and John Wardwell. 1999. ÒMigrants Settling Far and Widein the Rural West.Ó Rural Development Perspectives 14 (2): 2-8.

Crompton, J.L., L.L. Love, and T.A. More. 1997. ÒAn Empirical Study of theRole of Recreation, Parks and Open Space in CompaniesÕ (Re)LocationDecisions.Ó Journal of Park and Recreation Administration 15 (1): 37-58.

Page 55: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 45

Cropper, M.L. and W.E. Oates. 1992. ÒEnvironmental Economics: A Survey.ÓJournal of Economic Literature 30 (2): 675-740.

Cushing, B.J. 1987. ÒLocation-Specific Amenities, Topography, and PopulationMigration.Ó The Annals of Regional Science XXI (2): 74-85.

DiVall, Linda and Tony Onorato. 2000. Heritage Forests Campaign NationalSurvey. American Viewpoint, Inc. March 21.

Doppelt, B., M. Scurlock, C. Frissell, and J. Karr. 1993. Entering theWatershed: A New Approach to Save AmericaÕs River Ecosystems. Island Press.

Duffy-Deno, Kevin. 1997. ÒThe Effect of State Parks on County Economies ofthe West.Ó Journal of Leisure Research 29 (2): 201-224.

Eberle, W.D. and F.G. Hayden. 1991. ÒCritique of Contingent Valuation andTravel Cost Methods for Valuing Natural Resources and Ecosystems.Ó Journalof Economic Issues XXV (September): 649-683.

ECONorthwest. 1996. The Potential Economic Consequences of DesignatingCritical Habitat for the Marbled Murrelet: Final Report. US Fish and WildlifeService, Portland Field Office. May.

Ekstrand, E.R. and J. Loomis. 1998. ÒIncorporating Respondent UncertaintyWhen Estimating Willingness to Pay for Protecting Critical Habitat forThreatened and Endangered Fish.Ó Water Resources Research 34 (11): 3149-3155.

Englin, J. and R. Mendelsohn. 1991. ÒA Hedonic Travel Cost Analysis forValuation of Multiple Components of Site Quality: The Recreation Value ofForest Management.Ó Journal of Environmental Economics and Management21: 275-290.

Figlio, D.N. 1996. A Suggestion for an Amenity-Constant Inter-City Cost ofLiving Adjustment. Department of Economics, University of Oregon. February.

Finch, D.M., G.L. Wolters, and W. Yong. 1995. ÒPlants, Arthropods, and Birdsof the Rio Grande.Ó In Ecology, Diversity, and Sustainability on the Middle RioGrande Basin. Edited by D.M. Finch and J.A. Tainter. Fort Collins, CO: U.S.Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and RangeExperiment Station. Pgs. 133-164.

Gabriel, S. A., J. P. Mattey, and W. L. Wascher. 1996. CompensatingDifferentials and Evolution of the Quality of Life Among States. FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco. Working Paper. June.

Gottlieb, P.D. 1994. ÒAmenities As an Economic Development Tool: Is ThereEnough Evidence?Ó Economic Development Quarterly 8 (3): 270-285.

Page 56: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 46 ECONorthwest

Greenwood, M.J., G.L. Hunt, D.S. Rickman, and G.I. Treyz. 1991. Estimates ofthe Determinants of Location Based on Interstate Migration Flows From 1970-1987. University of Colorado at Boulder. Working Paper.

Hagen, D.A., J.W. Vincent, and P.G. Welle. 1992. ÒBenefits of Preserving Old-Growth Forests and the Spotted Owl.Ó Contemporary Policy Issues X (April):13-26.

Hansen, L.T. and A. Hallam. 1990. Water Allocation Tradeoffs:Irrigation andRecreation. United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural EconomicReport Number 634. June 1990.

Hansen, L.T. and A. Hallam. 1991. ÒNational Estimates of the RecreationalValue of Streamflow.Ó Water Resources Research 27 (2): 167-175.

Haynes, R.W. and A.L. Horne. 1997. ÒChapter 6: Economic Assessment of theBasin.Ó In An Assessment of Ecosystem Components in the Interior ColumbiaBasin and Portions of the Klamath and Great Basins, Volume IV. Edited byT.M. Quigley and S.J. Arbelbide. General Technical Report PNW-GTR-405.Portland, OR: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, PacificNorthwest Research Station. June. Pgs. 1715-1869.

Helvoigt, Ted. 1999. Ò1998 In-Migration Study: Quality of Life.Ó Oregon LaborTrends (March): 11-12.

Helwig, R.T. 2001. ÒWorker Displacement in a Strong Labor Market.Ó MonthlyLabor Review 124 (6): 13-28.

Ilg, R.E. 1996. ÒThe Nature of Employment Growth, 1989-95.Ó U.S.Department of Labor Monthly Labor Review June: 29-36.

Jackson, R.J. and C. Kochtitzky. 2001. Creating a Healthy Environment: TheImpact of the Built Environment on Public Health. Sprawl Watch.

Kessler, J., J. Wood, C. Bradley, and J. Rhodes. 2001. Imperiled Western Troutand the Importance of Roadless Areas. Western Native Trout Campaign(Center for Biological Diversity, Pacific Rivers Council, and BiodiversityAssociates). November.

Knapp, T.A. and P.E. Graves. 1989. ÒOn the Role of Amenities in Models ofMigration and Regional Development.Ó Journal of Regional Science 29 (1): 71-87.

Krikelas, A.C. 1992. ÒWhy Regions Grow: A Review of Research on theEconomic Base Model.Ó Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of AtlantaJuly/August: 16-29.

Page 57: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 47

Leones, J. and B. Colby. 1998. ÒTracking Expenditures of the Elusive NatureTourists of Southeastern Arizona.Ó Journal of Travel Research 36 (3): 56-64.

Leven, C.L. 1986. ÒAnalysis and Policy Implications of Regional Decline.ÓAmerican Economic Review 76 (2): 308-312.

Loomis, J. and E. Ekstrand. 1997. ÒEconomic Benefits of Critical Habitat forthe Mexican Spotted Owl: A Scope Test Using a Multiple-Bounded ContingentValuation Survey.Ó Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 22 (2):356-366.

Loomis, J.B. 2000. ÒEconomic Values of Wilderness Recreation and PassiveUse: What We Think We Know at the Begining of the 21st Century.Ó InWilderness Science in a Time of Change ConferenceÑ Volume 2: WildernessWithin the Context of Larger Systems. U.S. Department of Agriculture, ForestService, Rocky Mountain Research Station.

Mathur, V.K. 1993. ÒThe Role of Amenities in a General Equilibrium Model ofRegional Migration and Growth.Ó Southern Economic Journal 59 (3 January):394-409.

Mendelsohn, R., W.D. Nordhaus, and D. Shaw. 1994. ÒThe Impact of GlobalWarming on Agriculture: A Ricardian Analysis.Ó The American EconomicReview 84 (4): 753-771.

Miller, R.K., J.E. Enote, and C.L. Martinez. 1996. ÒTribal Experiences andLessons Learned in Riparian Ecosystem Restoration.Ó In Desired FutureConditions for Southwestern Riparian Ecosystems: Bringins Interests andConcerns Together. Edited by D.W. Shaw and D.M. Finch. U.S. Forest Service,Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. Pgs. 198-202.

Mueser, P.R. and P.E. Graves. 1995. ÒExamining the Role of EconomicOpportunity and Amenities in Explaining Population Redistribution.Ó Journalof Urban Economics 37: 176-200.

Niemi, E. and A. Fifield. 2000. Seeing the Forests for their Green: EconomicBenefits of Forest Protection, Recreation and Restoration. ECONorthwest forthe Sierra Club. August.

Niemi, E., E.W. Whitelaw, and A. Johnston. 1999. The Sky Did NOT Fall: ThePacific NorthwestÕs Response to Logging Reductions. ECONorthwest. preparedfor Earthlife Canada Foundation and the Sierra Club of British Columbia.April.

Pacific Rivers Council, Inc. 1995. The Urgent Need for Watershed Protectionand Restoration in the Sierra Nevada. Pacific Rivers Council. September.

Pacific Rivers Council. 2000. National Forest Roads Briefing Materials. March.

Page 58: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

Page 48 ECONorthwest

Physicians for Social Responsibility. 2001. Death by Degrees: The HealthThreats of Climate Change in Arizona. September.

Pope, C.A. and J.W. Jones. 1990. ÒValue of Wilderness Designation in Utah.ÓJournal of Environmental Management 39: 157-174.

Power, T.M. 1996. Lost Landscapes and Failed Economies: The Search for aValue of Place. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.

Power, T.M. and R. N. Barrett. 2001. Post-Cowboy Economics: Pay andProsperity in the New American West. Island Press.

Power, T.M., editor. 1995. Economic Well-Being and Environmental Protectionin the Pacific Northwest: A Consensus Report by Pacific Northwest Economists.Economics Department, University of Montana. December.

Ribaudo, M.C. 1989. Water Quality Benefits from the Conservation ReserveProgram. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service.Agricultural Economic Report. 606. February.

Richer, J. 1995. ÒWillingness to Pay for Desert Protection.Ó ContemporaryEconomic Policy XIII (October): 93-104.

Roback, J. 1982. ÒWages, Rents, and the Quality of Life.Ó Journal of PoliticalEconomy 90 (6): 1257-1278.

Rosen, S. 1979. ÒWage-Based Indexes of Urban Quality of Life.Ó In CurrentIssues in Urban Economics. Edited by P. Mieszkowski and M. Straszheim.Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. Pgs. 74-104.

Rudzitis, G. and R. Johnson. 2000. ÒThe Impact of Wilderness and OtherWildlands on Local Economies and Regional Development Trends.Ó InWilderness Science in a Time of Change ConferenceÑVolume 2: WildernessWithin the Context of Larger Systems. U.S. Department of Agriculture, ForestService, Rocky Mountain Research Station.

Rudzitis, G., J. Hintz, and C. Watrous. 1995. Snapshots of a ChangingNorthwest. University of Idaho, Department of Geography. Working Paper ofthe Migration, Regional Development and the American West Project.

Rudzitis, Gundars. 1999. ÒAmenIties Increasingly Draw People to the RuralWest.Ó Rural Development Perspectives 14 (2): 9-13.

Sherwood-Call, C. 1994. The 1980s Divergence in Per Capita Personal Incomes:What Does It Tell Us? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. August 15.

Page 59: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran

ECONorthwest Page 49

Southwick Associates. 2000. Historical Economic Performance of Oregon andEastern Counties Associated with Roadless and Wilderness Areas. OregonNatural Resources Council and World Wildlife Fund. August 15.

Stewart, S.I. and D.J. Stynes. 1994. ÒToward a Dynamic Model of ComplexTourism Choices: The Seasonal Home Location Decision.Ó In EconomicPsychology of Travel and Tourism. Edited by J.C. Crotts and W.F. van Raaij.Binghamton, New York: Haworth Press, Inc. Pgs. pp.69-88.

Tiebout, C. M. 1956. ÒExports and Regional Economic Growth.Ó Journal ofPolitical Economy 64 (2): 160-164.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service. 1995. The Forest ServiceProgram for Forest and Rangeland Resources: A Long-Term Strategic Plan.U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service. Draft 1995 RPA Program.October.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency and U.S. Army Corps of Engineers.1994. Analyzing Employment Effects of Stream Restoration Investments. IWRReport 94-FIS-18. November.

Uysal, M. and J.L. Crompton. 1985. ÒAn Overview of Approaches Used toForecast Tourism Demand.Ó Journal of Travel Research XXIII (4): 7-15.

Vias, Alexander. 1999. ÒJobs Follow People in the Rural Rocky MountainWest.Ó Rural Development Perspectives 14 (2): 14-23.

Walsh, R.G., J.B. Loomis, and R.A. Gillman. 1984. ÒValuing Option, Existence,and Bequest Demands for Wilderness.Ó Land Economics 60 (1): 14-29.

Whitelaw, W.E. and E. Niemi. 1989. ÒThe Greening of the Economy.Ó OldOregon 68 (3): 26-27.

Page 60: Economic Benefits of Protecting Natural Resources in the ... · years regarding conservation of Sonoran Desert lands. The most recent, and by far the most comprehensive, is the Sonoran