ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

23
ECON6021 (Nov 17&19) Information Asymmetry

description

ECON6021 (Nov 17&19). Information Asymmetry. Informational economics. When a person buys medical insurance, the insuring company does not know whether the person is healthy. Nor does it know how well he is going to take care of himself after buying insurance. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Page 1: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Information Asymmetry

Page 2: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Informational economics When a person buys medical insurance, the insuring

company does not know whether the person is healthy. Nor does it know how well he is going to take care of himself after buying insurance.

The former type of asymmetry information is called a hidden type problem, or adverse selection problem.

The latter type of asymmetric information is called a hidden action problem, or moral hazard problem. But the notion of moral hazard has subsequently expanded.

Information economics is the study of decision makings between agents when their information is asymmetric.

Page 3: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Adverse Selection

Page 4: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Why called “Adverse Selection”?

Adverse selection refers to a situation where a selection process (here market) results in a pool of products/individuals with economically undesirable characteristics.

With “hidden type”, either (1) bad products drive out good products or (2) good products subsidize bad products (both receive the same price).

Gresham’s law: bad money drives out good. Or, where two media of exchange come into circulation together the more valuable will tend to disappear.

Page 5: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Adverse selection: Used Cars (Lemons) Market

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Assumption: all of the above is commonly known in the following exercises.

Page 6: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Scenario I: Full Information

Suppose that every buyer and every seller know the type of the car they are negotiating.

Then both good cars and bad cars will be traded.

There are simply two products (good and bad cars).

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Page 7: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Scenario II: No Information

Suppose buyers don’t know the type of the cars they are interested. Also suppose no sellers know the type of the cars they own. Assume all agents are risk neutral.

Expected valuation of a car to buyers= 1/3 * $30K + 2/3 * $20K = $23.33K

Expected valuation of a car to sellers = 1/3 * $25K + 2/3 * $10K = $15K

Both good cars and bad cars will be traded!

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Page 8: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Scenario III: Asymmetric (Unequal) Information

Sellers know the types of cars they own. But buyers don’t know the types of cars they are going to buy.

Is a buyer willing to pay at a price greater than $25K (say $26K)?

No, because there is 2/3 of probability that the car is bad, and the expected valuation to the buyer=1/3*$30K + 2/3*$20K= $23.33K < the price

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Page 9: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Scenario III: Asymmetric (Unequal) Information

Is a buyer willing to pay a price of $22K to buy a car? No, at such a low price, only bad cars owners will sell

their cars. But bad cars are worth only $20K to the buyer. $22K is too high a price.

The market price is even lower, at $20K or somewhat lower. Only bad cars will be traded. Good cars don’t find a buyer!!!

Remark: What matters is not the amount of information.

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Page 10: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Scenario III: Asymmetric Information

Good cars may still find a buyer, if the probability of bad cars in the pool is low.

Let p be such prob. A buyer is willing to pay $25K if (1-p)x$30K + px$20K>$25K, or p<0.5.

Good cars of 2-3 years old will easily find a buyer, while good cars of 10 years old don’t find a buyer

good cars bad carsbuyers' valuation $30K $20Ksellers' valuation $25K $10Knumber of cars 100 200number of buyers infinite

Page 11: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Solving the Problems:Guarantees & WarrantiesLiability LawsReputation of a store or the manufacturerExperts--a disinterested partyStandards & Certificationssignaling by the party who has more

information [education, money burning, etc.]

Page 12: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral HazardRecap:

When a person buys medical insurance, the insuring company does not know whether the person is healthy. Nor does it know how well he is going to take care of himself after buying insurance.

The latter type of asymmetric information is called a hidden action problem, or moral hazard problem. That is, when people are insured by medical insurance, they tend to exert less effort to take care of themselves than the case they are uninsured.

Why called moral hazard? People buy insurance for their houses, and then burn them and claim for compensation greater than the value of the houses.

Page 13: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Some knowledge about decisions under uncertainty Expected value of a gamble=EV=p1v1+p2v2+…+pnvn where pi is

the probability for the prize vi and p1+…+pn=1 A gamble (game, or lottery) is fair if its expected value is zero. St. Petersburg paradox:

a coin is flipped until a head appears. If the head first appears on the nth flip, the player is paid $2n. How much are you willing to pay to play the game?

EV of the game =(1/2)x$2+(1/4)x$4+…(1/2n)x$2n+… = But rarely are we willing to pay a few thousand dollars for such a

game!! This is because people are generally risk averse! One prefers

$1,000 to 1/2 probability of $2,000 and 1/2 probability of $0.

Page 14: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Contracting between a risk neutral and risk averse agent In the absence of moral hazard, the risk neutral agent should

bear all risk. Suppose there are only two states: good and bad (each with 1/2

probability), and a joint venture between a risk neutral agent (N) and a risk averse agent (R) have a revenue of 150 and 100 under the two states.

Consider any contract stipulates that the agent get x at the good state and y at the bad state. N’s expected income is (150-x)/2+(100-y)/2=125-(x+y)/2. R’s expected income is (x+y)/2.

Consider another contract with a sure payment of (x+y)/2 at each state. The each party’s expected income remains unchanged. While N is indifferent to the change, R is strictly better off because risk is eliminated.

Page 15: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Principal-Agent Problem & Insurance A risk neutral principal hires a risk averse agent to help him on a

task. Suppose the agent’s effort affects the profits non-deterministically (e.g. farming).

Without moral hazard, the optimal contract is to let the principal bear all the risk and the agent get a fixed income. [Optimal risk sharing]

But in the presence of moral hazard, such a contract is infeasible in the sense that the agent will shirk. A tradeoff is to have a contract stipulating a bonus positively related to the profits generated.

The above analysis can be extended to insurance. In the absence of moral hazard, the optimal insurance contract is a full insurance.

In the presence of moral hazard, full insurance is no longer feasible. Insurance can only be partial [deductible, etc.]

Page 16: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral hazard as a verification problemEven if actions are observable, as long as

they are not verifiable to a third party, then a contract made contingent on these actions is not enforceable.

The following insurance contract is not enforceable. “If you take good care of yourself, I’ll pay you $5,000 in case of a loss; otherwise, I won’t pay you any in case of a loss.”

Hence, moral hazard may well be a result of incomplete contracts, rather than asymmetric information.

Page 17: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral hazard as a commitment problem The idea of moral hazard has subsequently

expanded to account for related phenomena. The most discussed are commitment or time

(in)consistency problem. Actions are observable and even verifiable and

hence contractible. However, when the undesirable action takes

place, both parties of the contract will choose not to enforce it. Instead, they renegotiate the contract.

Page 18: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

A Contract between Mother and Son A contract between mother and son: “If the son goes to sleep

by 10pm, he’ll receive no penalty; otherwise, he will be shot to death.”

Ex ante, the mom wishes the contract enforceable so that, foreseeing the death penalty, the son will go to bed on time.

Suppose HK law allows this contract to be legal. Suppose they can arrange videotaping so that the court can

verify when the son goes to bed. However, ex post in case the son doesn’t go to bed by 10pm, it

would be in both parties’ interest to renegotiate the contract (no one likes to see the son die anyway).-->a time inconsistency problem (or commitment problem)

The son knows this and hence does not go to bed by 10pm.

Page 19: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral hazard & Government Policy Moral hazard as a time consistency problem is

closely related to government policy, where government is one party of a contract and citizens (or firms) are another party.

An interesting quote: “There are two types of countries in the world; those with deposit insurance, and those not knowing they have deposit insurance.”

Page 20: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral hazard in a natural disaster Suppose residents near Yellow River are more vulnerable

to attack of typhoons. Two states of nature: good state and bad state with

probability 0.9 and 0.1. In good state: loss =0 In bad state: loss = $1m Residency elsewhere no loss moving cost = $50k<expected loss=0.1x$1m=100k in case of bad state, the government can step in to reduce

the resident’s loss to $200k at a cost of $500k

Page 21: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Moral hazard in a natural disaster

Scenario govern-ment'scost

resident'sloss

totalcost

1st best (not helping atbad state andhence,foreseeing this)moving out

0 moving cost= $50k

$50k

3rd best not moving &not helping atbad state

0 0.1*$1m=$100k

$100k

2nd

bestnot moving &helping at badstate

0.1*$500k=$50k

0.1*$200k=$20k

$70k

The efficient outcome is to have the resident move out. But the government cannot commit not to rescue the resident at the bad state (a benevolent government should rescue). Knowing this, the resident will not move out!

Page 22: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Remedies for moral hazard as a commitment problem

Mandatory insuranceCoercion (force the resident to move at

the outset)divided government makes discretion less

likelyIn general, don’t postpone! Solve the

problem now!!

Page 23: ECON6021 (Nov 17&19)

Further Applications Why unemployment can be an equilibrium

outcome Why there is equilibrium credit rationing Why debt financing and equity financing are

different Why firms exist and what explains their

boundaries (holdup problem) Why currency attack occurs even when the

fundamentals are sound