Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

41
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12

Transcript of Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan Quint

Spring 2010

Lecture 12

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

2

Midterm will be returned at end of lecture

HW2 is online, due in two weeks (Wed Mar 17)

Second midterm Wed Mar 24 Cumulative, through end of contract law

Logistics

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

3

Default rules Why are gaps left in contracts? What rules should be applied to fill those gaps? C&U: use terms most parties would have chosen (efficient terms) Ayres and Gertner: under some conditions, use default rules which

penalize one or both parties for concealing information

Regulations Example: derogation of public policy

Ways to get out of a contract Formation defenses (“no contract exists”) Performance excuses (“circumstances have changed”) One formation defense: incompetence (but not drunkenness)

Last time…

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

4

Another formation defense:dire constraints

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

5

Necessity I’m about to starve, someone offers me a sandwich for $10,000 My boat’s about to sink, someone offers me a ride to shore for

$1,000,000 Contract would not be upheld: I signed it out of necessity

Duress Other party is responsible for situation I’m in Someone makes me an offer I can’t refuse

Dire constraints

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

6

Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 You write him a check Do you have to honor the agreement?

“Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” He did – he wants your $100 You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed

So why not enforce it? Makes muggings more profitable leads to more muggings Tradeoff: don’t enforce Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive

for bad behavior

Friedman on duress

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

7

Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 You write him a check Do you have to honor the agreement?

“Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” He did – he wants your $100 You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed

So why not enforce it? Makes muggings more profitable leads to more muggings Tradeoff: don’t enforce Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive

for bad behavior

Friedman on duress

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

8

Same logic doesn’t work for necessity You get caught in a storm on your $10,000,000 sailboat Tugboat offers to tow you to shore for $9,000,000 (Otherwise he’ll save your life but let your boat sink)

Duress: if we enforce contract, incentive for more crimes Here: if we enforce contract, incentive for more tugboats to be available for

rescues – how is that bad? Social benefit of rescue: value of boat, minus cost of tow Say, $10,000,000 – $10,000 = $9,990,000 If tugboat gets entire value, his private gain = social gain So tugboat captain would invest the efficient amount in being available to

rescue you So what’s the problem?

What about necessity?

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

9

What about your decision: whether to sail that day 1 in 1000 chance of being caught in a storm If so, 1 in 2 that a tugboat will rescue you Private cost of sailing: 1 in 2000 you lose boat, 1 in 2000 you pay

tugboat captain value of boat $10,000,000/2000 + $10,000,000/2000 = $10,000 So you’ll choose to sail if your value is above $10,000 Social cost: 1 in 2000 boat is lost, 1 in 2000 boat is rescued $10,000,000/2000 + $10,000/2000 = $5,005 Efficient to sail when your value is above $5,005 When your value from sailing is between $5,005 and $10,000, you

undersail If the price of being towed was just the marginal cost, you would sail the

efficient amount

What about necessity?

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

10

Same transaction sets incentives on both parties Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other

“Put the incentive where it would do the most good” Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of

a storm!

Friedman’s point

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

11

Same transaction sets incentives on both parties Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other

“Put the incentive where it would do the most good” Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of

a storm! So makes sense for courts to overturn contracts signed under

necessity, replace them with ex-ante optimal terms

Friedman’s point

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

12

Single price can create multiple incentives

Often impossible to set them all efficiently Already saw this with remedy for breach Expectation damages: efficient breach, but inefficient signing Include gains from reliance: overreliance Exclude gains from reliance: inefficient breach

More general point

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

13

Court won’t enforce contracts signed under threat of harm “Give me $100 or I’ll shoot you”

But many negotiations contain threats “Give me a raise, or I’ll quit” “$3,000 is my final offer for the car, take it or I walk”

The difference? Threat of destruction of value versus failure to create value A promise is enforceable if extracted as price of cooperating in

creating value; not if it was extracted by threat to destroy value

Real duress versus fake duress

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

14

Alaska Packers’ Association v Domenico (US Ct App 1902) Captain hires crew in Seattle for fishing expedition to Alaska In Alaska, crew demands higher wages or they’ll quit Captain agrees Back in Seattle, refuses higher wages, claiming duress

Example

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

15

A performance excuse:impossibility

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

16

When performance becomes impossible, should promisor owe damages, or be excused from performing?

A perfect contract would explicitly state who bears each risk

Contract may give clues as to how gaps should be filled

Industry custom might be clear

But in some cases, court must fill gap

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

17

In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach

But there are exceptions Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was

made”

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

18

In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach

But there are exceptions Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was

made”

Efficiency requires assigning liability to the party that can bear the risk at least cost Party that can take precautions to minimize the risk Or can best spread the risk over many transactions

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

19

Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? Also called low-cost avoider Who is in best position to mitigate/reduce a risk, or hedge it, or endure

it?

We already saw this question with efficient default rules When a contract leaves a gap, an efficient contract would have

allocated each risk to low-cost avoider Construction company building a house, completion is delayed

Family might be efficient risk-bearer, because it’s cheaper for them to stay with friends than for construction company to pay for hotel

Cost of raw materials goes up, increasing cost of construction Construction company might be efficient risk-bearer, because they can buy

materials early or change design plans

Important general concept

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

20

Contracts based onbad information

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

21

Four doctrines for invalidating a contract based on faulty information Fraud Failure to disclose Frustration of purpose Mutual mistake

Misinformation

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

22

Fraud violates “negative duty” not to misinform

In some circumstances, positive duty to disclose certain information Civil law: contract may be voided if you did not supply information

you should have (“failure to disclose”) Common law: seller is not forced to disclose everything he knows

Must warn about hidden dangers Need not share information that makes product less valuable but not

dangerous But, new products come with “implied warranty of fitness”

Fraud and Failure to Disclose

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

23

Both parties based a contract on the same bad information contract may be voided due to frustration of purpose

Coronation Cases Rooms rented out with view of new king’s coronation parade Parade was postponed, owners still tried to collect rent Courts ruled change in circumstance had frustrated the purpose of

the original contracts, which were therefore void

“When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to the party who can bear the risk at least cost”

Frustration of Purpose

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

24

Frustration of purpose: circumstances changed after the contract was signed

Mutual mistake: circumstances changed before the contract was signed, but the parties didn’t know about it

Enforcing the contract would be like forcing involuntary exchange Coase: we expect voluntary exchange to be efficient But involuntary exchange may not be

Mutual Mistake

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

25

Hadley v Baxendale (miller and shipper) Hadley knew shipment was time-critical But Baxendale was deciding how to ship crankshaft (boat or train)

A general principle about information: efficiency generally requires uniting knowledge and control Contracts that unite knowledge and control are generally efficient,

should be upheld Contracts that separate knowledge and control may be inefficient,

should more often be set aside

Another principle: knowledge and control

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

26

Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control

Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless You sell it to me at a low price

Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld

Unilateral mistake

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

27

Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control

Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless You sell it to me at a low price

Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld Contracts based on unilateral mistake generally unite knowledge and

control And this creates an incentive to gather information

Unilateral mistake

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

28

War of 1812: British blockaded port of New Orleans Price of tobacco fell, since it couldn’t be exported

Organ (tobacco buyer) learned the war was over Immediately negotiated with Laidlaw firm to buy a bunch of tobacco

at the depressed wartime price

Next day, news broke the war had ended, price of tobacco went up, Laidlaw sued Supreme Court ruled that Organ was not required to communicate

his information

Unilateral mistake: Laidlaw v Organ (U.S. Supreme Court, 1815)

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

29

Productive information: information that can be used to produce more wealth

Redistributive information: information that can be used to redistribute wealth in favor of informed party

Cooter and Ulen Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of productive information –

especially if that knowledge was the result of active investment – should be enforced

Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of purely redistributive information or fortuitously acquired information should not be enforced

Unilateral mistake: productive versus redistributive information

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

30

Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety risks

Common law does not generally require disclosure of other types of information

But… Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent

further damage Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose Sale did not unite knowledge and control

More on duty to disclose

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

31

Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety risks

Common law does not generally require disclosure of other types of information

But… Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent further

damage Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose Sale did not unite knowledge and control Many states require used car dealers to reveal major repairs done,

sellers of homes to reveal certain types of defects…

More on duty to disclose

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

32

Other reasons a contract may not be enforced

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

33

Courts will generally not enforce contract terms that are overly vague

Can be thought of as a penalty default

But some exceptions Parties may commit to renegotiating the contract “in good faith”

under certain contingencies

Vague contract terms

Page 34: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

34

Bargain theory: courts ask only whether a contract was part of a bargain, not whether that bargain was fair Hamer v Sidway (drinking and smoking)

But two common law doctrines to get out of extremely one-sided contracts Adhesion Unconscionability

Fairness

Page 35: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

35

Adhesion: standardized “take-it-or-leave-it” contracts Friedman calls it “bogus duress”

Adhesion and unconscionability

Page 36: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

36

Adhesion: standardized “take-it-or-leave-it” contracts Friedman calls it “bogus duress”

Unconscionability Overly one-sided contract may not be enforced Terms “such that no man in his senses and not under delusion would

make on the one hand, and as no honest and fair man would accept on the other”

When “the sum total of its provisions drives too hard a bargain for a court of conscience to assist”

Terms which would “shock the conscience of the court” Similar concept in civil law: lesion

Adhesion and unconscionability

Page 37: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

37

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 38: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

38

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 39: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

39

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Not normal monopoly cases but “situational monopolies” Think of Ploof v Putnam (sailboat in a storm)

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 40: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

40

Midterms

Page 41: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12.

41

Overall pretty good

Mean 82, median 84, std dev 14

Not actually assigning letter grades till after final

But to have an approximate idea of where you stand…

90s roughly AB or A

80s roughly B

70s roughly BC

high 50s/60s roughly C

Midterm

A-H Q-ZI-P