Dynamics analysis of Cournot triopoly game model with ......Cournot model with linear cost...

11
Dynamics analysis of Cournot triopoly game model with heterogeneous players in exploitation of a renewable resource Hongliang Tu 1,2 1 College of Management and economic Tianjin University Tianjin 300072 China 2 China University of Mining and Technology, Xuzhou 221116 [email protected] Junhai Ma 1 College of Management and economic Tianjin University Tianjin 300072 China China [email protected] Abstract: Based on a dynamical multi-team Cournot game in the exploitation of a renewable resource, a new dynamic Cournot triopoly game model with one bounded rational player and two team players is established to find a renewable resource. By using the theory of bifurcations of dynamical systems, we studied the stability of the system, obtaining a point at which local stable regions reachthe Nash equilibrium. Besides, we analyzed the resulting adjustment speed parameters and the weight parameter of the system, which could otherwise affect the dynamics behaviors of the system. The complexity of the system is demonstrated by means of bifurcation diagram, the Lyapunov exponents, the phase portrait, the time history diagram and the fractal dimension. Furthermore, the linear feedback control method is used to control the chaos of the system. The derived results have very important theoretical and practical significance to the renewable resource firms and market. Key–Words: Complexity; Chaos; Dynamic Cournot triopoly game; Bounded rationality; Team players 1 Introduction Research on the complexity of nonlinear economic systems is a very hot topic in the economic and man- agement area. In recent years, a series of dynamic game models on the output decision (Cournot model) and price decision (Bertrand model) have been studied in the related references. Agiza [1] and Kopel [2] con- sidered bounded rationality and established duopoly Cournot model with linear cost functions. From then on, the model has been extended to multi-oligopolistic market. Bischi et al. [3] suppose that all of the t- wo firms determine their output based on the reaction functions, that is, all of the two players take naive s- trategy. Agliari et al. [4] studied a dynamic triopoly Cournot game with isoelastic demand function, lin- ear cost function and naive players. Agiza and El- sadany [5] investigated a dynamic game model with two-types of players: one is bounded rational play- er, and the other is adaptive expectation player. Elab- basy et al.[6] investigated the dynamics of a nonlin- ear triopoly game with three-types of players which are bounded rational player, adaptive player and naive player. Tramontana [7], and Tramontana and El- sadany [8] studied the period-doubling bifurcations and the Neimark-Sacker bifurcation in a duopoly and triopoly with isoelastic demand function and hetero- geneous players, respectively. Tomasz [9] analyzed the complex dynamics of a Bertrand duopoly game with bounded rational and adaptive players. Elettreby et al.[10] introduced a dynamic multi-team Bertrand four oligarchs game model with bounded rational and naive players, and researched the dynamics and con- trol of this model. Sun and Ma [11] introduced a tri- opoly Bertrand model with nonlinear demand func- tions in Chinese cold rolled steel market, and re- searched the complexity and the control of the mod- el. Matsumoto and Nonaka [12] researched the com- plexity of Cournot duopoly game model with com- plementary goods and naive players. Tramontana et al. [13] studied a piecewise-smooth Cournot duopoly game on the global bifurcations. Agliari [14] analyzed the global bifurcations of basins of a dynamic triopoly game. Yassen and Agiza [15] considered a Cournot duopoly game model with bounded players and the model with delayed bounded rationality, and derived that the model with delay has more possible to sta- ble at the Nash equilibrium state. In these literatures, the vast majority of models suppose that the oligarchs have non-cooperation factor. However, there are few models studied the cooperation factor between the oli- garchs. Based on a dynamical multi-team Cournot game in exploitation of a renewable resource[16], a new dy- namic Cournot triopoly game model with team play- ers in exploitation of a renewable resource is built up. Suppose the inverse demand function is linear form, WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma E-ISSN: 2224-2856 713 Volume 10, 2015

Transcript of Dynamics analysis of Cournot triopoly game model with ......Cournot model with linear cost...

  • Dynamics analysis of Cournot triopoly game model withheterogeneous players in exploitation of a renewable resource

    Hongliang Tu1,21 College of Management and economic

    Tianjin UniversityTianjin 300072 China

    2China University of Mining and Technology, Xuzhou [email protected]

    Junhai Ma1College of Management and economic

    Tianjin UniversityTianjin 300072 China

    [email protected]

    Abstract: Based on a dynamical multi-team Cournot game in the exploitation of a renewable resource, a newdynamic Cournot triopoly game model with one bounded rational player and two team players is established tofind a renewable resource. By using the theory of bifurcations of dynamical systems, we studied the stability ofthe system, obtaining a point at which local stable regions reachthe Nash equilibrium. Besides, we analyzed theresulting adjustment speed parameters and the weight parameter of the system, which could otherwise affect thedynamics behaviors of the system. The complexity of the system is demonstrated by means of bifurcation diagram,the Lyapunov exponents, the phase portrait, the time history diagram and the fractal dimension. Furthermore, thelinear feedback control method is used to control the chaos of the system. The derived results have very importanttheoretical and practical significance to the renewable resource firms and market.

    Key–Words: Complexity; Chaos; Dynamic Cournot triopoly game; Bounded rationality; Team players

    1 IntroductionResearch on the complexity of nonlinear economicsystems is a very hot topic in the economic and man-agement area. In recent years, a series of dynamicgame models on the output decision (Cournot model)and price decision (Bertrand model) have been studiedin the related references. Agiza [1] and Kopel [2] con-sidered bounded rationality and established duopolyCournot model with linear cost functions. From thenon, the model has been extended to multi-oligopolisticmarket. Bischi et al. [3] suppose that all of the t-wo firms determine their output based on the reactionfunctions, that is, all of the two players take naive s-trategy. Agliari et al. [4] studied a dynamic triopolyCournot game with isoelastic demand function, lin-ear cost function and naive players. Agiza and El-sadany [5] investigated a dynamic game model withtwo-types of players: one is bounded rational play-er, and the other is adaptive expectation player. Elab-basy et al.[6] investigated the dynamics of a nonlin-ear triopoly game with three-types of players whichare bounded rational player, adaptive player and naiveplayer. Tramontana [7], and Tramontana and El-sadany [8] studied the period-doubling bifurcationsand the Neimark-Sacker bifurcation in a duopoly andtriopoly with isoelastic demand function and hetero-geneous players, respectively. Tomasz [9] analyzedthe complex dynamics of a Bertrand duopoly game

    with bounded rational and adaptive players. Elettrebyet al.[10] introduced a dynamic multi-team Bertrandfour oligarchs game model with bounded rational andnaive players, and researched the dynamics and con-trol of this model. Sun and Ma [11] introduced a tri-opoly Bertrand model with nonlinear demand func-tions in Chinese cold rolled steel market, and re-searched the complexity and the control of the mod-el. Matsumoto and Nonaka [12] researched the com-plexity of Cournot duopoly game model with com-plementary goods and naive players. Tramontana etal. [13] studied a piecewise-smooth Cournot duopolygame on the global bifurcations. Agliari [14] analyzedthe global bifurcations of basins of a dynamic triopolygame. Yassen and Agiza [15] considered a Cournotduopoly game model with bounded players and themodel with delayed bounded rationality, and derivedthat the model with delay has more possible to sta-ble at the Nash equilibrium state. In these literatures,the vast majority of models suppose that the oligarchshave non-cooperation factor. However, there are fewmodels studied the cooperation factor between the oli-garchs.

    Based on a dynamical multi-team Cournot gamein exploitation of a renewable resource[16], a new dy-namic Cournot triopoly game model with team play-ers in exploitation of a renewable resource is built up.Suppose the inverse demand function is linear form,

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 713 Volume 10, 2015

  • but the cost functions are nonlinear form. In this mod-el, the bounded rational players regulate output speedaccording to marginal profit (or team marginal prof-it), and decide their output. By theoretical analysisand numerical simulation, the stable regions about theoutput adjustment speed parameters are derived. It isshown that the adjustment of the output speed and theweight parameter can change the stability of the sys-tem and even lead chaos to occur. It has an importanttheoretical and applied significance to the complexi-ty research of new nonlinear dynamic Cournot gamemodel in exploitation of renewable resource.

    The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2,the dynamic Cournot triopoly game model with teamplayers in exploitation of a renewable resource is p-resented. In Section 3, the existence and the localstability the Nash equilibrium point are studied, andthe stable regions of the Nash equilibrium point areobtained. In Section 4, we investigate the output ad-justment speed parameters and the weight parameterwhich effect on the dynamics behaviors of the sys-tem. Numerical simulation method is used to showcomplex dynamics of the system by means of the bi-furcation diagram, the Lyapunov exponents, the phaseportrait, the time history diagram and the fractal di-mension. In Section 5, control bifurcation and chaosof the model is considered with the linear feedbackcontrol method. Finally, some conclusions are made.

    2 The modelSuppose that there are three mainly oligopoly enter-prises X1,X2,X3 in exploitation of a renewable re-source. The enterprise Xi (i = 1,2,3) makes theoptimal output decision, and suppose the t-output isqi(t) (i = 1,2,3). At each period t, the price p is de-termined by the total output QT (t) = q1(t)+ q2(t)+q3(t).

    According to Ref. [16], we also propose the re-newable resource market with the linear inverse de-mand function:

    p(t) = a−bQT (t). (1)

    and the cost function of the enterprise Xi (i = 1,2,3)is as follow:

    Ci(t) = ci +diq2i (t)QT (t)

    , (i = 1,2,3). (2)

    where ci (i = 1,2,3) is the fix cost, and di (i =1,2,3) is positive parameter.

    We can get the profit of the enterprise Xi (i =

    1,2,3) as follow:

    πi(t)= [a−bQT (t)]qi(t)−ci−diq2i (t)QT (t)

    , (i= 1,2,3).

    (3)Here, it is assumed that the renewable resource

    firms X1,X2 establish a team, then the profit of theteam is:

    π team(t)= θ [(a−bQT (t))q1(t)− c1 − d1q

    21(t)

    QT (t)]

    +(1−θ)[(a−bQT (t))q2(t)− c2 − d2q22(t)

    QT (t)],

    (4)where the θ is the weight parameter of the profit ofrenewable resource firm X1 in the team.

    We propose that the enterprise Xi (i = 1,2,3)takes bounded rational strategy. Since the game be-tween the enterprises is a continuous and long-termrepeated dynamic process, the dynamic adjustment ofthe player in the triopoly game can be expressed asfollow:{

    qi(t +1) = qi(t)+αiqi(t)∂πteam(t)

    ∂qi(t) , (i = 1,2),

    q3(t +1) = q3(t)+α3q3(t)∂π3(t)∂q3(t) ,(5)

    where αi (i = 1,2,3) is the output adjustment speedparameter.

    A new dynamic Cournot triopoly game with het-erogeneous players in exploitation of a renewable re-source is obtained. This map has the following form:

    q1(t +1) = q1(t)+α1q1(t)A,q2(t +1) = q2(t)+α2q2(t)B,q3(t +1) = q3(t)+α3q3(t)C.

    (6)

    whereA = [θ(a − bQT (t)− bq1 − 2d1q1(t)QT (t) +

    d1q21(t)Q2T (t)

    ) + (1 −

    θ)(−bq2(t)+ d2q22(t)

    Q2T (t))]

    B = [θ(−bq1(t) + d1q21(t)

    Q2T (t)) + (1 − θ)(a − bQT (t) −

    bq2 − 2d2q2(t)QT (t) +d2q22(t)Q2T (t)

    )]

    C = [a−bQT (t)−bq3 − 2d3q3(t)QT (t) +d3q23(t)Q2T (t)

    ]

    3 The stability of the systemIn system (6), αi (i = 1,2,3) is taken as bifurca-tion parameter, and the other parameters are as fol-lows: a = 6.29,b = 0.92,d1 = 0.265,d2 = 0.374,d3 =0.436,θ = 0.5.

    Let the marginal profits equal to 0, we can get theNash equilibrium point.The fixed points of system (6)

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 714 Volume 10, 2015

  • satisfy the following equations:

    q1[θ(a−bQT −bq1−2d1q1QT +

    d1q21Q2T

    )+(1−θ)(−bq2 + d2q22

    Q2T)] = 0,

    q2[θ(−bq1 + d1q21

    Q2T)

    +(1−θ)(a−bQT −bq2 − 2d2q2QT +d2q22Q2T

    )] = 0,

    q3(a−bQT −bq3 − 2d3q3QT +d3q23Q2T

    ) = 0.(7)

    The Eqs. (7) are solvedand seven meaningful fixed pointsp1(1.3500,0.9566,2.0933), p2(3.2745,0,0),p3(0,3.2152,0), p4(0,0,3.1815), p5(1.9515,1.3827,0),p6(2.2483,0,2.1201), p7(0,2.1919,2.1461) are ob-tained. Here, we only consider the stability ofthe Nash equilibrium point p1(q∗1 = 1.35,q

    ∗2 =

    0.9566,q∗3 = 2.0933), and denote the total output atthe Nash equilibrium point as Q∗T = q

    ∗1 +q

    ∗2 +q

    ∗3.

    We can calculate the Jacobian matrix of system(6) at the Nash equilibrium point p1

    J =

    1+ j11 j12 j13j21 1+ j22 j23j31 j32 1+ j33

    , (8)where

    j11 = α1q∗1[θ(−2b−2d1Q∗T

    +4d1q∗1Q∗2T

    − 2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T)

    +(1−θ)2d2q∗22

    Q∗3T],

    j12 = α1q∗1[θ(−b+2d1q∗1Q∗2T

    − 2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T)

    +(1−θ)(−b+ 2d2q∗2

    Q∗2T− 2d2q

    ∗22

    Q∗3T)],

    j13 = α1q∗1[θ(−b+2d1q∗1Q∗2T

    − 2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T)− (1−θ)2d2q

    ∗22

    Q∗3T],

    j21 = α2q∗2[θ(−b+2d1q∗1Q∗2T

    − 2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T

    +(1−θ)(−b+ 2d2q∗2

    Q∗2T− 2d2q

    ∗22

    Q∗3T)],

    j22 = α2q∗2[−θ2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T

    +(1−θ)(−2b− 2d2Q∗T +4d2q∗2Q∗2T

    − 2d2q∗22

    Q∗3T)],

    j23 = α2q∗2[−θ2d1q∗21

    Q∗3T+(1−θ)(−b+ 2d2q

    ∗2

    Q∗2T− 2d2q

    ∗22

    Q∗3T)],

    j31 = j32 = α3q∗3(−b+2d3q∗3Q∗2T

    − 2d3q∗23

    Q∗3T),

    j33 = α3q∗3(−2b−2d3Q∗T

    +4d3q∗3Q∗2T

    − 2d3q∗23

    Q∗3T).

    Furthermore, we can get the characteristic poly-nomial of system (6) at p1

    f (λ ) = λ 3 +B2λ 2 +B1λ +B0, (9)

    where

    B2 =−(3+ j11 + j22 + j33),B1 =− j12 j21 − j13 j31 − j23 j32 +(1+ j22)(1+ j33)+(1+ j11)(2+ j22 + j33),B0 = j13(1+ j22) j31 − j12 j23 j31 + j12 j21(1+ j33)− j13 j21 j32−(1+ j11)[(1+ j22)(1+ j33)− j23 j32].

    According to the Jury test [17], the necessary andsufficient condition of the local stability of Nash equi-librium is the following four conditions satisfied.

    i) f (1) = B2 +B1 +B0 +1 > 0,

    ii) − f (−1) =−B2 +B1 −B0 +1 > 0,

    iii) |B0|< 1,

    iv) |B20 −1|> |B1 −B2B0|.

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    α1

    α 2

    Bifurcation Curve

    Stable Region

    Figure 1: The stable region of Nash equilibrium pointin the phase plane of (α1,α2), and α3 = 0.12

    The local stable region of Nash equilibrium pointcan be obtained by solving the above equations. Itis a bounded in the region of hyperbolic plane withpositive (α1,α2,α3). If α3 held fixed, the stable re-gion in the phase plane of (α1,α2) can be obtained,such as the stable region (α1,α2) is shown in Fig. 1when α3 = 0.412. The Nash equilibrium is stable forthe values of (α1,α2) inside the stable region. we cananalogously obtain the stable region in the phase planeof (α1,α3) and (α2,α3) in Figs. 2 and 3 when α2 andα1 hold fixed, respectively. The meaning of the stableregion is that all of the three renewable resource firm-s will eventually maintain at Nash equilibrium outputafter finite games whatever initial output are chosenin the local stable region. It is valuable to study thatthe enterprises increase the output adjustment speed

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 715 Volume 10, 2015

  • 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.20

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    α1

    α 3

    Stable Region

    Bifurcation Curve

    Figure 2: The stable region of Nash equilibrium pointin the phase plane of (α1,α3), and α2 = 0.1

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    α2

    α 3

    Bifurcation Curve

    Stable Region

    Figure 3: The stable region of Nash equilibrium pointin the phase plane of (α2,α3), and α1 = 0.46

    in order to get more profit. Though output adjust-ment speed parameters are unrelated to the Nash e-quilibrium point, the system will become unstable andeven fall into chaos if one player adjusts output speedtoo fast and pushes αi(i = 1,2,3) out of the stable re-gion. Numerical simulation method is used to analyzethe characteristics of system (6) with the change ofαi(i = 1,2,3). Numerical results such as bifurcationdiagrams, strange attractors, the Lyapunov exponents,sensitive dependence on initial conditions and fractalstructure will be discussed in the following section.

    4 Dynamic characteristics of the sys-tem

    In this game, the enterprises make the optimal outputdecision to get the maximum profit and adjust their

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5q

    3

    q1

    q2

    Figure 4: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) with α1 ∈(0,1], and (α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.412)

    output based on the last period marginal profit. In theoligopoly market, the players have the driving forceto increase their output in the hope of achieving moreprofits. The renewable resource firms can adjust theiroutput speed to increase their output. So, the outputadjustment speed parameter αi (i = 1,2,3) affects thegame results very much. The effect of output adjust-ment speed parameter αi (i = 1,2,3) on system (6)will be analyzed in the following section.

    4.1 The effect of output adjustment speed onthe system

    The stability of Nash equilibrium point will change ifcompany X1 accelerates output adjustment speed andpushes α1 out of the stable region. Fig. 4 shows aone-parameter bifurcation diagram with respect to α1when (α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.412). For α1 < 0.4615,system (6) at the Nash equilibrium point, that is, theoutput of the three firms are in the equilibrium state.For α1 = 0.4615, system (6) undergoes 2 period dou-bling bifurcation.

    Furthermore, when (α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562),with output adjustment speed α1 increasing, the out-put evolution of duopoly starts with 2 period orbit-s, through period doubling and ends with chaotic s-tate. From the bifurcation diagram Fig. 5 and thecorresponding Lyapunov exponents diagram Fig. 6,we can see α1 ∈ (0,0.3636] is the domain of 2 pe-riod orbits of system (6), α1 ∈ (0.3636,0.4825] isthe domain of 4 period orbits of system (6), α1 ∈(0.4825,0.5175] is the domain of 8 period orbit-s of system (6), α1 ∈ (0.7343,0.7552) is the do-main of period orbits window of system (6), forα1 ∈ (0.5175,0.7343]∪ (0.7552,1], system (6) is ina chaotic state. Calculation of the Lyapunov expo-nent is used to analyze the quantitative characteris-

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 716 Volume 10, 2015

  • 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    α1

    q 2,q

    1,q 3

    Figure 5: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) with α1 ∈(0,1], and (α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562)

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1−1.6

    −1.4

    −1.2

    −1

    −0.8

    −0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    α1

    Lyap

    unov

    Exp

    onen

    ts

    Figure 6: The corresponding Lyapunov exponents di-agram with α1 ∈ (0,1], and (α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562)

    0.81

    1.21.4

    1.6

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    20

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    q1

    q2

    q 3

    Figure 7: Chaos attractors of system (6) for (α1 =0.729,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562)

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    α2

    q3

    q1

    q2

    Figure 8: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) with α2 ∈(0,1], and (α1 = 0.468,α3 = 0.412)

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    α2

    q 2,q

    1,q 3

    Figure 9: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) with α2 ∈(0,1], and (α1 = 0.468,α3 = 0.562)

    tics of the dynamic system. The system is in chaot-ic state if the largest Lyapunov exponent is positive.In addition, the positive Lyapunov exponent is larger,the system is more obviously in chaotic state. Fig.7 show the chaos attractors of system (6) at initialpoint (q10 = 0.957,q20 = 1.36,q30 = 1.78) for (α1 =0.729,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562).

    Similarly, when (α1 = 0.468,α3 = 412) and withthe output α2 output adjustment speed increasing, Fig.8 shows the bifurcation diagram of system (6). Wecan see that for α2 < 0.4615, system (6) is stable atthe Nash equilibrium point, for α1 > 0.4615, system(6) undergoes 2 period doubling bifurcation.

    Furthermore, the bifurcation diagram Fig. 9 andthe corresponding Lyapunov exponents diagram Fig.10 show a one-parameter bifurcation diagram with re-spect to α2 when (α1 = 0.468,α3 = 0.562). We cansee α2 ∈ (0,0.3357] is the domain of 2 period orbitsof system (6), α2 ∈ (0.3357,0.50350] is the domain of4 period orbits of system (6), α2 ∈ (0.50350,0.5455] is the domain of 8 period orbits of system

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 717 Volume 10, 2015

  • 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1−1.6

    −1.4

    −1.2

    −1

    −0.8

    −0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0

    0.2

    α2

    Lyap

    unov

    Exp

    onen

    ts

    Figure 10: The corresponding Lyapunov exponentsdiagram with α2 ∈ (0,1], and (α1 = 0.468,α3 =0.562)

    1.41.6

    1.82

    2.2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    10.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    q 3

    q1

    q2

    Figure 11: Chaos attractors of system (6) for (α1 =0.468,α2 = 0.792,α3 = 0.562)

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.60

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    α3

    q3

    q1

    q2

    Figure 12: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) withα3 ∈ (0,0.6601], and (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476)

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6−1.6

    −1.4

    −1.2

    −1

    −0.8

    −0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    α3

    Lyap

    unov

    Exp

    onen

    ts

    Figure 13: The corresponding Lyapunov exponentsdiagram with α3 ∈ (0,0.6601], and (α1 = 0.468,α2 =0.476)

    0 50 100 150 2000.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    2.6

    t

    q1

    q2

    q3

    Figure 14: For (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.397),the time course diagram of system (6)

    11.2

    1.41.6

    1.82

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.40

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    q1

    q2

    q 3

    Figure 15: Chaos attractors of system (6) for (α1 =0.468,α2 = 476,α3 = 0.659)

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 718 Volume 10, 2015

  • (6), α2 ∈ (0.5455,0.5594) ∪ (0.6643,0.6713] is thedomain of period orbits window of system (6), forα2 ∈ (0.5594,0.6643]∪ (0.6713,1], system (6) is ina chaotic state. Fig. 11 show the representativechaos attractors at initial point (q10 = 0.957,q20 =1.36,q30 = 1.78) for (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.792,α3 =0.562).

    Likewise, the bifurcation diagram Fig. 12 andthe corresponding Lyapunov exponents diagram Fig.13 show a one-parameter bifurcation diagram withrespect to α3 when (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 476). Onecan observe that Nash equilibrium point is asymp-totically stable for 0 < α3 < 0.4108, for example,the time course diagram of system (6) shows in Fig.12 for (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.397). Forα3 ∈ (0.4108,0.5401] is a area of 2-cycle output fluc-tuation. α3 ∈ (0.5401,0.5678] is a area of 4-cyclearea of output fluctuation. α3 ∈ (0.5678,0.5724]is a area of 8-cycle output fluctuation. For α2 ∈(0.5724,0.6601], system (6) becomes into a chaotic s-tate. Figs. 11 show the representative chaos attractorsat initial point (q10 = 0.957,q20 = 1.36,q30 = 1.78)for (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 476,α3 = 0.659).

    Form the above analysis, we can find that the sta-bility of system (6) will be changed and even the com-plex dynamic behaviors occur with increasing of theoutput adjustment speed αi (i = 1,2,3).

    4.2 The weight parameter θ affects on thesystem

    In this section, we study the weight parameter θ whichaffects the dynamic behaviors of system (6). Simi-larly, the bifurcation diagram Fig. 16 and the corre-sponding Lyapunov exponents diagram Fig. 17 showa one-parameter bifurcation diagram with respect to θwhen (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.394). One cansee that for 0.454545 < θ < 0.559441 system (6) isstable at different Nash equilibrium points, that is tosay, the triopoly renewable resource firms are in dif-ferent equilibrium states. The output q3 changes onlya little, but the output q1,q2 change very large. In bothsides of the stable domain, system (6) undergoes peri-od bifurcations to chaos with the weight parameter θdecreasing and increasing, which have only dynamicsmeaning, but they don’t have economic meaning.

    For θ ∈ (0,0.041958], the output q1 = 0, butoutput the q2,q3 are in chaotic state. For θ ∈(0.041958,0.059440], the output q1 = 0, but out-put the q2,q3 have 8-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.059440,0.115385], the output q1 = 0, but out-put the q2,q3 have 4-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.115385,0.454545], the output q1 = 0, but out-put the q2,q3 have 2-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.559441,0.884615], the output q2 = 0, but out-

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    θ

    q1

    q2

    q3

    Figure 16: Bifurcation diagram of system (6) with θ ∈(0,1], and (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.394)

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1−2

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0

    0.5

    θ

    Lyap

    unov

    Exp

    onen

    ts

    Figure 17: The corresponding Lyapunov exponentsdiagram with θ ∈ (0,1], and (α1 = 0.468,α2 =0.476,α3 = 0.394)

    0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    2.6

    2.8

    q2

    q 3

    Figure 18: Chaos attractors of system (6) for θ =0.0298

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 719 Volume 10, 2015

  • 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 31

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    2.6

    2.8

    q1

    q 3

    Figure 19: Chaos attractors of system (6) for θ =0.985

    put the q1,q3 have 2-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.884615,0.937063], the output q2 = 0, but out-put the q1,q3 have 4-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.937063,0.958042], the output q2 = 0, but out-put the q1,q3 have 8-cycle output orbits. For θ ∈(0.958042,1], the output q2 = 0, but output the q1,q3are in chaotic state.

    Figs. 18 and 19 show the representative chaos at-tractors at initial point (q10 = 0.957,q20 = 1.36,q30 =1.78) when (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.394),θ = 0.0298 and θ = 0.985, respectively.

    Through the above analysis, we can see that theweight parameter θ not only affects on the stability ofsystem (6) but also change the Nash equilibrium point.In both sides of the stable domain, system (6) under-goes period bifurcations to chaos with the weight pa-rameter θ decreasing and increasing, which have noeconomic meaning.

    4.3 Sensitive dependence on initial condi-tions

    One of the most important characteristics of the chaosis extremely sensitive dependence on initial condi-tions. Figs. 20, 21, 22 respectively show the d-ifference of the output q1,q2,q3 with the change oftime when system (6) has different initial condition-s. We can see that there is almost no distinction be-tween them in the beginning, but the difference be-tween them is huge with the number of game increas-ing. It implies that a slight difference between initialvalues can lead to a great effect on the game result-s. For (α1 = 0.625,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.562,θ = 0.5),(α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.792,α3 = 0.562,θ = 0.5) and(α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.615,θ = 0.5), it fur-ther proves that system (6) is in a chaotic state. Whenthe system in a chaotic state, the market will be de-

    0 20 40 60 80 100 120

    −0.25

    −0.2

    −0.15

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    t

    ∆ q 1

    Figure 20: For (α1 = 0.625,α2 = 0.476,α3 =0.562,θ = 0.5), and the initial conditions are (0.957,1.36, 1.78) and (0.9571, 1.36, 1.78), difference of theoutput q1 with the change of time

    0 20 40 60 80 100 120−0.2

    −0.15

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    0.3

    t

    ∆ q 2

    Figure 21: For (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.792,α3 =0.562,θ = 0.5), and the initial conditions are (0.957,1.36, 1.78) and (0.957, 1.3601, 1.78), difference of theoutput q2 with the change of time

    stroyed and it is difficult for the renewable resourcecompanies to make long-term plan. So, every ac-tion from the renewable resource companies can causegreat loss.

    4.4 Fractal dimensionFractal dimension can be used as another criterion tojudge whether the system is in a chaotic state or not.There are many specific definitions of fractal dimen-sion, but none of them can be taken as the universalone. According to Ref. [18], the following definitionof fractal dimension is adopted in this paper.

    d = j− ∑j1 λi

    λ j+1, (10)

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 720 Volume 10, 2015

  • 0 20 40 60 80 100 120−2

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    t

    ∆ q 3

    Figure 22: For (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 =0.615,θ = 0.5), and the initial conditions are (0.957,1.36, 1.78) and (0.957, 1.36, 1.7801), the differenceof the output q3 with the change of time

    where λ1 > λ2 >,...,λn are the Lyapunov expo-nents, and j is the maximum integer for which satis-fies ∑ j1 λi > 0 and ∑

    j+11 λi < 0. If λi ≥ 0, i = 1,2, ...,n,

    the d = n. If λi < 0, i = 1,2, ...,n, then d = 0.The Lyapunov exponents of system (6) are

    λ1 = 0.2127,λ2 = −0.0607,λ3 = −1.0576 for (α1 =0.468,α2 = 0.792,α3 = 0.562). System (6) is in achaotic state because the largest Lyapunov exponen-t λ1 is positive. Fractal dimension demonstrates thatthe chaotic motion has self-similar structure, which isan important difference between the chaotic motionand the stochastic motion. The fractal dimension ofsystem (6) is d = 2− λ1+λ2λ3 ≈ 2.1437. The fractal di-mension also reflects the space density of the chaoticattractor. The larger the dimension of the chaotic at-tractor is, the larger the occupied space is. Thus, thestructure of the chaotic attractor is more compact, andthe system is more complexity and vice versa. Thefractal dimension of the 3D discrete system(6) is morethan 2, so the occupied space is big and the structureis tight, which can be seen in Fig. 11.

    5 Chaos controlOne can see that system (6) becomes unstable andeventually falls into chaos if the output adjustmentspeed parameter exceeds a critical value. All of thethree renewable resource firms will be harmed andthe market will become irregular when chaos occurs.Therefor, no one is able to make good strategies anddecide reasonable output. To avert risk, it is good ide-al for the triopoly renewable resource firms to stay atNash equilibrium output.

    In this section, the linear feedback control method

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.20

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2.5

    3

    k

    q1

    q2q

    3

    Figure 23: Bifurcation diagram of system (11) withk ∈ (0,1.25], (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.659)

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2−1.6

    −1.4

    −1.2

    −1

    −0.8

    −0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    k

    Lyap

    unov

    Exp

    onen

    ts

    Figure 24: The corresponding Lyapunov exponentswith k ∈ (0,1.25], (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 =0.659)

    is used to control the effect of parameters α3 on sys-tem (6). The system under controlled is as follows:

    q1(t +1) = q1(t)+α1q1(t)A,q2(t +1) = q2(t)+α2q2(t)B,q3(t +1) = q3(t)+α3q3(t)C− kq3(t).

    (11)

    whereA = [θ(a − bQT (t)− bq1 − 2d1q1(t)QT (t) +

    d1q21(t)Q2T (t)

    ) + (1 −

    θ)(−bq2(t)+ d2q22(t)

    Q2T (t))]

    B = [θ(−bq1(t) + d1q21(t)

    Q2T (t)) + (1 − θ)(a − bQT (t) −

    bq2 − 2d2q2(t)QT (t) +d2q22(t)Q2T (t)

    )]

    C = [a−bQT (t)−bq3 − 2d3q3(t)QT (t) +d3q23(t)Q2T (t)

    ]

    where k > 0 is an adjustment parameter and other pa-rameters are the same as above.

    It can be seen from the bifurcation diagram Fig.

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 721 Volume 10, 2015

  • 23 and the corresponding Lyapunov exponents pathFig. 24, for (α1 = 0.468,α2 = 0.476,α3 = 0.659),controlled system (11) stabilized at Nash equilibriumpoint for k > 0.9090. It reveals that chaos control ofthe system (6) can realize through adding a negativelinear feedback.

    The purpose of system control is to take effec-tive measures to regulate market behaviors for avoid-ing the occurrence of chaos. The linear feedback con-trol method can make the system to regain equilibriumwhile the system (6) in a chaotic state, and effective-ly control the bifurcation and chaos behaviors of thesystem. This method can ensure that the renewableresource market orderly develop, and the renewableresource firms rationally and healthily compete.

    6 Conclusions

    A new dynamics of a nonlinear triopoly game withone bounded rational player and two team playersin exploitation of renewable resource is built up inthis paper. The stability of the Nash equilibriumpoint, the bifurcation and chaotic behaviors of thedynamic system are investigated. We found thatbifurcation and chaos occur as the output adjustmentspeed parameter αi (i = 1,2,3) increases and theweight parameter θ changes. The weight parameterθ not only affects the stability of system (6) but alsochanges the Nash equilibrium point. The oligopolymarket may become unstable and even fall into chaoswhen the output adjustment speed parameters leavethe stable region. The linear feedback control methodis used to control the complexity of the system, whichmakes the system to regain stable states. It has a verytheoretical and practical significance to research thecomplexity of new nonlinear dynamical system. Asthe traditional energy is non-renewable, it will bedepleted in a few couple of years. In this way, thedevelopment of renewable resource is an inevitablechoice. This paper also shows a guidance for therenewable resource companies to make strategies oftheir output and exploit the renewable resource, andit is helpful for the government to formulate relevantpolicies to manage the renewable resource market.

    Acknowledgements: The research was supported bythe National Natural Science Foundation of China(No. 61273231), Doctoral Fund of Ministry ofEducation of China (Grant No. 20130032110073)

    References:

    [1] H. N. Agiza, ”On the analysis of stability, b-ifurcation, chaos and chaos control of Kopelmap”, Chaos Solitons & Fractals, vol. 10, No.11, 1999, pp. 1909-1916.

    [2] M. Kopel, ”Simple and complex adjustmen-t dynamics in Cournot duopoly models”, ChaosSolitons & Fractals, vol. 7, No. 12, 1996, p-p. 2031-2048.

    [3] G. I. Bischi, C. Mammana, and L. Gardini,”Multistability and cyclic attractors in duopolygames”, Chaos Solitons & Fractals, vol.11, No.4, 2000, pp. 543-564.

    [4] Agliari, A., Gardini, L., Puu, T.:, ”The dynamicsof a triopoly Cournot game”, Chaos Solitons &Fractals, vol.11, No.15, 2000, pp. 2531–2560.

    [5] H. N. Agiza and A. A. Elsadany, ”Chaotic dy-namics in nonlinear duopoly game with hetero-geneous players”, Appl. Math. Comput., vol.149,No.3, 2004, pp. 843-860.

    [6] Elabbasy, E. M., Agiza, H. N., Elsadany, A.A.:, ”Analysis of nonlinear triopoly game withheterogeneous players”, Comput. Math. Appl,vol.57, No.3, 2009, pp. 488–499.

    [7] Tramontana, F.:, ”Heterogeneous duopoly withisoelastic demand function”, Economic Mod-elling, vol.27, No.1, 2010, pp. 350–357.

    [8] Tramontana, F., Elsadany, A. E. A.:, ”Heteroge-neous triopoly with isoelastic demand function”,Nonlinear Dyn, vol.68, No.1-2, 2012, pp. 187–193.

    [9] Tomasz, D. T.:, ”Complex dynamics in aBertrand duopoly game with heterogeneousplayers”, Central Europ. J. Econ. Modelling E-con, 2010, pp. 95–116.

    [10] Elettreby, M. F., Mashat, D. S., Zenkour, A. M.:,”Multi-team Bertrand game with heterogeneousplayers”, Appl. Math, Vol. 2, No. 9, 2011, p-p. 1182–1190.

    [11] Sun, Z., Ma, J.:, ”Complexity of triopoly pricegame in Chinese cold rolled steel market”, Non-linear Dyn, Vol.67, No.3, 2012, pp. 2001–2008.

    [12] Matsumoto, A., Nonaka, Y, ”Statistical dynam-ics in a chaotic Cournot model with complemen-tary goods”, J. Econ. Behav. Organ, 2006, p-p. 769–783.

    [13] Tramontana, F., Gardini, L., Puu, T., ”Glob-al bifurcations in a piecewise-smooth Cournotduopoly game”, Chaos Solitons & Fractals,Vol.10, 2010, pp. 15–24.

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 722 Volume 10, 2015

  • [14] Agliari, A., Gardini, L., Puu, T., ”Global bi-furcations of basins in a triopoly game”, Int. J.Bifurc. Chaos, Vol.12, No.10, 2002, pp. 2175–2207.

    [15] Yassen, M. T., Agiza, H. N., ”Analysis of aduopoly game with delayed bounded rationali-ty”, Appl. Math. Comput, Vol.138, No.2-3, 2003,pp. 387–402.

    [16] Asker, S. S., ”On dynamical multi-team Cournotgame in exploitation of a renewable resource”,Chaos Solitons Fractals, Vol.132, No.1, 264–268 (2007)

    [17] Edelstein-Kashet, L., ”Mathematical Models inBiology”, Random House, New York, 1992.

    [18] Kaplan, J. L., Yorke, Y. A., ”A regime observedin a muid mow model of Lorenz”, Commun.Math. Phys, 1979, pp. 93–108.

    WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hongliang Tu, Junhai Ma

    E-ISSN: 2224-2856 723 Volume 10, 2015