Dynamic Inputs and Resource (Mis)Allocation John Asker ...

35
Dynamic Inputs and Resource (Mis)Allocation John Asker, Allan Collard Wexler and Jan De Loecker NYU, Princeton & NBER September 23, 2013 CMU 1. Introduction 2. Model 3. Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion Dynamic Inputs

Transcript of Dynamic Inputs and Resource (Mis)Allocation John Asker ...

Dynamic Inputs and Resource (Mis)Allocation

John Asker, Allan Collard Wexler and Jan De Loecker NYU, Princeton & NBER

September 23, 2013

CMU

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Research Question:

‘To what extent do dynamic production inputs (e.g. capital) and adjustment shocks shape dispersion of static MRPK (“capital misallocation”) at the industry/country level?’

•  Approach: Build a model, and evaluate the reduced form and structurally estimated predictions on a bunch of different data sets

- ‘Macro-style’ IO

•  Why is this interesting? 1.  Get a sense of what can drive cross-industry and country MRPK

(and productivity) differences 2.  Particularly second moments (Macro/Development literatures)

- e.g. Restuccia & Rogerson (2008), Hsieh & Klenow (2009), Midrigan and Xu (2013)

3.  Persistent challenge in IO: Relate cross sectional patterns to time series behavior

4.  Alternate framework for judging policy responses

Research question

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Think of an industry in which: •  firms face some adjustment cost when changing capital stock, and; •  face an AR(1) process on firms specific productivity.

Punchline:

Model

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Think of an industry in which: •  firms face some adjustment cost when changing capital stock, and; •  face an AR(1) process on firms specific productivity.

Punchline:

Industry Data

(US Census)

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

39% drop

•  Think of an industry in which: •  firms face some adjustment cost when changing capital stock, and; •  face an AR(1) process on firms specific productivity.

Punchline:

Industry Data

(US Census)

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Think of an industry in which: •  firms face some adjustment cost when changing capital stock, and; •  face an AR(1) process on firms specific productivity.

Punchline:

Country Data

(WBES)

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Indonesia

Morocco

47% drop

•  Think of an industry in which: •  firms face some adjustment cost when changing capital stock, and; •  face an AR(1) process on firms specific productivity.

Punchline:

Country Data

(WBES)

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Firm with: •  Cobb-Douglas technology

•  Constant elasticity demand (e = - 4)

•  Sales Generating Function:

(Beta’s sum to 0.75)

•  Which gives the MRPK in a static world as:

Model:

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Firm with: •  Adjustment costs introduce dynamics in capital choice

•  financial cost •  one period time to build

•  very standard AR(1) on log TFP introduces transitions in states

+ a one period time to build

Model:

Dynamics

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Analysis done via computation. •  Parameter values either standard, or from ranges seen in data sets •  Theorem establishes that everything is robust to a firm specific constant in the productivity process

Model:

Comparative Statics

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Lots of data sets •  Each have their issues, which is why we use lots of them •  For presentation, I’ll focus on US and WBES

Data:

Data and Measurement

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Measurement of productivity:

•  Recall that

•  Where beta’s sum to 0.75

•  (log) TFPR is

•  to get coeffs use

•  and use the adding up constraint to get capital coeff

Data:

Data and Measurement

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Measurement of productivity:

•  Recall that

•  Where beta’s sum to 0.75

•  (log) TFPR is

•  to get coeffs use

•  and use the adding up constraint to get capital coeff

•  (and if you hate this, for Slovenia we use OLS estimates from Jan’s earlier work)

Data:

Data and Measurement

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Basic reduced form is that MPRK dispersion should be positively correlated with productivity volatility

•  Hence:

Std(MRPK)

=

Constant +

Std( Δtfpr ) +

Year Dummies

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

(same table, just bigger)

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

US only

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

Robustness

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

Robustness

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Reduced Form

Robustness

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Why capital?

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Objective: to see how much of the differences in dispersion the model is capable of capturing

•  What we need: •  AR(1) on productivity process •  Adjustment Costs •  Sales generating function coeffs •  discount rates, and depreciation rates which we lift from existing literature

•  To get the AR(1) we estimate is from the productivity data, for each industry •  Volatility is the sigma parameter

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Objective: to see how much of the differences in dispersion the model is capable of capturing

•  What we need: •  AR(1) on productivity process •  Adjustment Costs •  Sales generating function coeffs •  discount rates, and depreciation rates which we lift from existing literature

•  To get the adjustment costs we fit the model to the following moments (using GMM approach)

•  proportion of firms with less than 5% y-o-y change in capital •  proportion of firms with more than 20% y-o-y change in capital •  Std(y-o-y change in log capital)

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

US adj costs X US avg prod. coeffs X Only 1 period TTB 2x US adj costs

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

US adj costs X US avg prod. coeffs X Only 1 period TTB 2x US adj costs

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

US adj costs X X US avg prod. coeffs X Only 1 period TTB 2x US adj costs

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

US adj costs X X US avg prod. coeffs X Only 1 period TTB 2x US adj costs X

Industry Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

US adj costs X X US avg prod. coeffs X Only 1 period TTB X 2x US adj costs X

Country Level Analysis:

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Objective: to see how much of the differences in dispersion the model is capable of capturing at a cross-country level

•  Basically the same analysis, but need a data set with a lot of countries

•  Use the World Bank Enterprise Survey. •  Good coverage of countries (33 we can use, all LDCs) •  Small sample sizes in some countries

•  we throw out anything with less than 25 obs, largest has just over 700 obs (Brazil)

•  Time series created by asking managers “what was it like last year?”

•  First, assess data quality (and model) by making sure it can replicate the reduced form analysis

•  Then, do structural analysis

•  Then look to see if AR(1) is related to anything observable

Country Level Analysis:

Reduced form

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Country Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Estimating the adjustment costs on all countries would be computationally expensive, and previous evidence from industry analysis suggests little or no return

•  Hence we use the US adjustment costs.

Country Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Estimating the adjustment costs on all countries would be computationally expensive, and previous evidence from industry analysis suggests little or no return

•  Hence we use the US adjustment costs.

•  S^2 = .80 for WBES, S^2 = 0.9 for Tier 1

Country Level Analysis:

Structural

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Country Level Analysis:

What might generate productivity shocks?

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

Conclusion

1.  Introduction 2.  Model 3.  Reduced Form 4. Structural 5. Cross-Country 6. Conclusion

Dynamic Inputs

•  Dynamic nature of inputs capable of rationalizing the dispersion in MRPK

•  How to interpret the dispersion differences?

•  Welfare irrelevant? •  if shock process is exogenous then firms acting much as the social planner would like them to

•  Forget about distortions in capital allocations? •  still room for static frictions to mess things up •  IO guy is never going to claim that static frictions are not worthy of a policy intervention •  less clear whether active reallocation is the answer

•  Think carefully about policies that affect the shock process? •  likely some room here for further thinking •  evidence that firms respond to the predictability of their environment •  to the extent that government can influence this, then it seems worth thinking about •  note that the development literature (and others) have made progress here in micro studies