Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of...

20
Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Author(s): Vivien A. Schmidt Source: Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 3, No. 4 (Dec., 2005), pp. 761-779 Published by: American Political Science Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3688179 Accessed: 22/03/2010 10:34 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=apsa. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Perspectives on Politics. http://www.jstor.org

Transcript of Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of...

Page 1: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European IntegrationAuthor(s): Vivien A. SchmidtSource: Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 3, No. 4 (Dec., 2005), pp. 761-779Published by: American Political Science AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3688179Accessed: 22/03/2010 10:34

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unlessyou have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and youmay use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained athttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=apsa.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toPerspectives on Politics.

http://www.jstor.org

Page 2: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles

Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt

Europeanization has brought radical change to the governance practices of all European Union (EU) member states, and these practices have clashed with traditional ideas about democracy. The degree to which EU member states have been affected is largely a matter of institutional fit. The EU, as a compound supranational polity in which governing activity is highly diffused through multiple authorities, has been more disruptive to simple national polities such as Britain and France, in which governing has tra- ditionally been channeled through a single authority, than to compound national polities such as Germany and Italy, in which it has traditionally also been diffused through multiple authorities.

The main problem for EU member states, however, is that national leaders have generally failed to develop new ideas and dis- courses to reflect Europeanized realities. But here too institutional differences matter. Simple polities are better positioned to address changes because their concentration of authority ensures them a more elaborate communicative discourse with the general public, in which they are able to speak with one voice, than are compound national polities, let alone the EU, given the number of poten- tially authoritative voices with differing messages.

emocracy has become a problem for Europe. The problem is not just at the supranational level of the European Union (EU), where all the talk of the

democratic deficit has been focused, but even more impor- tantly at the national level. This is because Europeaniza- tion, defined here as the top-down impact of the EU on its member states, has brought major change not just to national policies and economies, but also to national pol- ities, that is, to the traditional workings of national democracies.1

Europeanization has disrupted the institutional pat- terns of all of its member states, shifting the focus of gov- ernmental power and authority upward to the EU, moving the locus of interest access and influence from national

capitals to Brussels, and subordinating the expression of

partisan votes and voice to a more consensus-oriented, interest-based politics. But it has affected member states

Vivien A. Schmidt is Jean Monnet Professor of European Integration at Boston University ([email protected]). Her recent books include Policy Change and Discourse in

Europe, coedited with C. Radaelli (2005), and The Futures of European Capitalism (2002). Herforthcoming book Democracy in Europe: The EU and National Polities (2006) explores the impact of the European inte-

gration on national democracies. This article is a revision

of a paper preparedfor presentation to the American Politi- cal Science Association National Meetings in Chicago, September 1-5, 2004.

characterized by more simple polities, in which governing activity has traditionally been channeled through a single authority, more than those with more compound polities, in which activity has traditionally been more diffused

through multiple authorities. Such differential impact is the result of the institutional fit (or lack thereof) between the EU's highly compound institutional arrangements and those of its member states.2

The problems for democracy following from member- state adaptation, however, stem less from the changes in

governance practices per se than from the lack of change in ideas and discourse about democracy. The main problem is that national leaders generally continue to project tra- ditional visions of national democracy rather than to speak to the changes in the traditional workings of their democ- racies. That they choose not to engage their publics in deliberation about the effects of Europeanization on the

polity attests to the difficulties of doing so when the short- term political costs are high and the benefits low. But their failure to do so leaves them open to the censure of their

publics for policies for which they are not fully responsi- ble, over which they often have little control, and to which

they may not even be politically committed. And this is the source of a national democratic deficit, which is more serious regarding questions of political legitimacy than the democratic deficit at the EU level.

But again, member states' institutional differences matter. Europeanization represents a greater challenge to simple polities' ideas about democracy, where legiti- macy is focused on a single authority, than to those of

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 761

Page 3: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles | Democracy

compound polities, where it is inherently more diffused. National leaders in simple pol- - ' ities have a greater capacity to ^ speak to those challenges, since in a system where a restricted . L L , government elite tends to coor- 1 dinate policy construction and communicate its initiatives to the public for deliberation, leaders are better able to project a clear message in a single voice. By contrast, in compound pol- ; . . . ities, which involve a much ? : ..::.?:'. -: ': ; wider range of actors in the .::::;

coordinative discourse, a clear : '

communicative discourse can- not easily emerge, given the number of potentially author- itative yet differing voices. In the compound EU, these prob- "

4 . lems are multiplied, since it has an even greater range of national and EU-level actors involved in coordinative discourse and little communica- tive voice of its own.3 The fact that national leaders have tended not to speak to the democratic challenges, there- fore, is a greater problem in simple polities than in com- pound polities, but a problem nonetheless for all member states, and especially for the EU as a whole. The negative majorities in the French and Dutch referenda in May 2005 on the Constitutional Treaty are the clear and unfortunate illustration of this.

In this paper, I first examine the EU's institutions in comparative perspective (mainly with the United States) and their impact, generally and then differentially, on its member states. I then similarly consider the EU's

organizing principles of democracy and their challenge to those of EU member states. Finally, I analyze the EU's patterns of discourse and their differential effects on national patterns. Throughout, two matched pairs of cases are used in illustration: Britain and France as simple polities, Germany and Italy as compound poli- ties. While these two pairs represent "most different" cases for the purposes of comparison, within each of the pairs, once we control for the overarching institutional similar- ities, we also find "most different" cases; Britain and France, on the one hand, and Germany and Italy, on the other, differ significantly in history, culture, institutional capac- ity, and politics as well as in their responses to Europe. To elucidate the theory, I use a mix of "new institu- tionalist" methods, with soft rational choice assumptions about the interest-based logic of simple and compound polities, historical institutionalist attention to how the actual relationships shape interests in such polities, socio- logical institutionalist awareness of how cultural rules

and norms frame both interests and institutions, and my own discursive institutionalist approach, which adds the dimension of ideas and discourse to illuminate the dynamics of change in interests, institutions, and culture.4

Governance in the EU With its dispersion of activity through multiple authorities at different levels, in different centers, with different forms of governing, the EU's governance system is more highly compound than those of even the most compound of nation-states, such as the United States. Nevertheless, it

greatly resembles the United States in its quasi-federal insti- tutional structures, its semi-pluralist policy formulation processes, and its regulatory implementation processes; it differs from the United States in its consensus-oriented, largely indirect system of political representation (see table 1). The greatest difference occurs with regard to the impact on "subfederal" units. This is because, unlike the American states, EU member states prior to European integration have been highly developed nation-states in their own right, with democracies that evolved differently in terms of structures, policy-making processes, and representation systems.

The EU has greatly affected its member states' govern- ing by federalizing national institutional structures, plu- ralizing national policy-making processes, and depoliticizing national representative politics. But the EU has also differentially affected polities depending upon where countries can be situated along a continuum from simple to compound in their governance (see fig. 1).5

At one end of the spectrum are Germany, Spain, Bel- gium, and Italy-compound polities. Like the EU, they

762 Perspectives on Politics

in Europe

Page 4: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Table 1 Institutional comparisons between the U.S. and EU

Federal Federal structures- structures- Policy Representative

vertical horizontal Policy formulation implementation politics

US Tipped in favour Separation of Open, political, Rule making Politicized, direct of center powers competitive somewhat open, elections for

uniform pres., majoritarian application electoral system

EU Tipped in favour Dynamic Less open, more Rule-making less Depoliticized, of sub-federal confusion of technical and transparent, less consensus- units powers apolitical, open, application oriented, no direct

cooperative more delegated, elections for less uniform president,

proportional and indirect

diffuse power and authority through federal or regional- ized institutional structures and permit a moderate level of interest access and influence through corporatist policy making, in which certain privileged interests-mainly busi- ness and labor-help formulate and implement policy. They also promote compromise-oriented politics through proportional systems of representation, and strive for con- sensus despite partisan patterns of voting and exercising voice.

At the other end are countries such as Britain, France, or Greece. These are relatively simple polities with a con- centration of power and authority in unitary institutional structures, and minimal interest access and influence

through statist policy-making processes in which the exec- utive has a monopoly on policy formulation but accom- modates interests in implementation. They also share more conflictual politics in majoritarian representation systems with polarized patterns of voting and exercising voice (see table 2). Between the two extremes are a range of coun- tries that do not fit neatly into any one place on the con- tinuum, as one or another institutional element may be more simple-that is, a unitary structure or majoritarian politics-even though the polity as a whole basically func-

tions in a compound manner-for example, because of

corporatist policy-making and consensus-oriented poli- tics-as in the Netherlands and Sweden.6

The EU serves to move all member-states' governing practices toward the compound end of the continuum. However, the EU has had a comparatively greater impact on simple polities than on compound ones because of a lack of institutional fit (see table 2). For simple polities the Europeanization of national governing practices has diffused their traditional concentration of power in the executive through the EU's quasi-federal levels and cen- ters of governance. It has opened up their traditionally limited interest access in policy formulation through semi-

pluralist EU level processes. It has diminished their flex-

ibility in policy implementation through EU demands for regulatory uniformity. And it has subordinated their

polarized, majoritarian politics to the EU's consensus- oriented, interest-based politics. For more compound pol- ities, by contrast, Europeanization has mainly added to their traditional diffusion of power, further opened up interest access while allowing corporatist implementation to stand, and reinforced consensus-oriented (albeit parti- san) politics.

Figure 1 Countries on a continuum from simple to compound polities

UK France Greece Sweden/ Netherlands Italy Spain Germany Belgium

Simple polity Compound polity

December 2005 1 Vol. 3/No. 4 763

4 ol

Page 5: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

I Democracy in Europe

a) ) 0 r0

o >-.-- E 3

003 a

* 11.11 0

03 3

HO - 03 C C

03 , " aI o 0

"0a S5

) C a 0. 1 3 0

.U_ x

Ii

0

i I

O 'x O

nQ L

,vQ 03

0)

u 0 , E: 15 z (2 0

>1 Q.

a)

E CO

CD

Q) -D 0

a) 0 03 co

C) -S

1~5 Co 03, (0)

0Z 0>

0. r

0 (3 0

CO

?I,

:2 T ?- o o - 03 Q :i:: (1

03 15 0N M-~

0)

,a 04)

a3 (I

c- .?

Institutional structures

Although the EU bears a surface resemblance to the United States,7 its institutional structures are more fully multi- level8 and more multicentered.9 The vertical division ofpow- ers between EU federal and subfederal levels is tipped in favor of the subfederal, that is, of the EU member states, more than in the United States. The member states in the EU have more independent powers than America's states both in policy formulation, to shape and veto legislation, and in policy implementation, given their role in transpos- ing and administering EU directives. In addition, the hor- izontal separation of powers in the EU between executive, legislature, and judiciary is a more dynamic confusion of

powers between branches than in the United States. This is because the directly elected European Parliament has a much weaker legislative role than the national executives acting jointly in the formal executive, the Council of Ministers, which itself has much less executive power than the unelected

bureaucracy, the Commission, which takes on most exec- utive functions of initiation and enforcement, while the judi- ciary, the European Court of Justice, overlaps with the executive and legislature in its highly activist role.'0

The development of the EU's quasi-institutional struc- tures has significantly affected all members' structures by altering the traditional power and authority of national

governments. National executives have become EU-level decision makers in exchange for giving up autonomy in national policy making. National legislatures have become

transposers of EU directives and regulators of society as

they have lost traditional legislative powers of initiative and approval. National judiciaries have become interpret- ers of EU law, and subnational units, implementers of EU

regulations, at the same time that both have become more

independent of the national executive.11 But the EU's institutional structures have disrupted

countries with simple institutional structures more than

they have those with already compound institutional struc- tures. Although the executives in all states have lost power and autonomy in the shift of decision making upward to the EU, in unitary states this has been comparatively more significant not only because executives have tradi-

tionally been highly autonomous, but also because national

judiciaries and regions have become more independent of the executive as a result of their EU-related roles (as well as because of internal dynamics related to judiciary activism and devolutionary reforms).12 The loss of exec- utive autonomy has been less significant for more federal states like Germany, given that the executive has always had to share power and authority with other national and subnational units of government. For regionalized Italy, the executive has actually gained.13

Paradoxically, although the diminution in national par- liaments' legislative powers has been potentially of greater significance in federal states, it too has in the end affected

0- CU

cr

a

0 0

E a =1 0 . ? -Y ~ ~ 0

03

0 0 W o 0 o (0

0 o

ao x a X C o .

(D c a

unitary states more profoundly. This is because in federal

764 Perspectives on Politics

Articles

o

n () a)

UJ G) () E o

a a

E

O c-

3I -0 CD

C-

03 0 3?

03 a)

0) 0 0 a,

0)

0~ a

>1 - L

0 n

C3

c o

C

03

03

a el

.,..

o

o C;

coO

og^

u 2

0C -

E)

0 V a C _

)

15- (.

0) (L)

15 0 - . .0

1F5 C)a~ S o

2 S

LO 0 03 ( 03

(n a)

. -

0. o

Q.

n3

0 E 0 0

cl (0 a.

E

__

c 0

Page 6: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

systems in which the executive's greater legislative role in the EU stood to alter the balance in the national division of powers to the detriment of the legislature, parliaments were able to negotiate a new balance of powers with the central executive. In Germany, for example, the opposition- controlled second chamber of the legislature was instru- mental in forcing the issue.14 Belgium and Austria

subsequently followed suit. In unitary states, by contrast, the legislature had no such capacity, given the weakness of the second chamber and control of the first by the executive as representative of the majority party. As a result, for example, the French Parliament's limited

powers have become more limited, despite reforms atten- dant upon the Maastricht Treaty.15 The British Parlia- ment has by comparison retained its traditionally greater powers of oversight, although it too has lost powers of initiative and approval.16 In Italy, a highly regional- ized but technically unitary state, by contrast, the reduc- tion in the parliament's powers of initiative and approval were balanced by greater effectiveness, as the transposi- tion of EU directives made the log-rolling of the past impossible.

The greater independence of the judiciary from the national executive has also been more important for uni-

tary than federal states, even though national courts' loss of autonomy to the European court has been more prob- lematic for federal states. In France, for example, where the courts have traditionally been subordinated to the exec- utive, the courts' increasing independence-the result of internal dynamics more than of their empowerment as an enforcement arm of the EU17--has been particularly unset-

tling to the executive, which is concerned by corruption investigations and is more resistant to applying EU law than either Germany or Britain. In Britain, where the courts have always been relatively independent and the

precedent-setting approach of British common law matches EU practice, the executive found it easier to accept the increased independence of the judiciary, if not the prolif- eration of EU-inspired laws, while the courts bristled at

giving up their prerogatives and have referred fewer ques- tions to the ECJ than have France or Germany.18 In Ger-

many, where the courts are even more independent than

they are in Britain and the importance of law as a regula- tory instrument parallels EU practice, the problem has been neither with the even greater independence of the courts nor with the proliferation of EU laws, but rather with constitutional issues related to the precedence of EU law over German.19 In Italy, where the courts were tradi-

tionally subordinate to the political power, they asserted their independence not just through the EU,20 but through a variety of corruption investigations, which ended the careers of major political and business officials-along with the entire postwar party system.

Finally, the closer links with the EU through regional policies, committees, and funds has been more signifi-

cant for the regions of unitary states, which gained greater independence from national executives than they had in the past, than for the regions of federal and regional- ized states. These always had more independence and stood to lose more as a result of the EU, but for the most part they managed to make up for their losses

through other gains. Any increase in supranational access and funding clearly enhanced independence for the regions of unitary France, which gained some measure of auton-

omy from the executive only in the decentralizing reforms of the 1980s;21 for the more autonomous regions of

formally unitary Italy, which have long had an uneasy truce with the central government; and for the newly emancipated regions of Britain, beneficiaries of the devolution that started in the late 1990s for Scotland, Wales, and Northern Ireland with elected legislatures, but which has yet to begin for the recently created English regions.22 By contrast, in federal Germany, the regions, after an initial loss in power as a result of the executive

deciding at the EU level on policies that had long been their domain, were compensated for the loss with a seat at the table in the EU on issues that affect them. In

regionalized Spain, the regions' rebalancing of power was also negotiated, albeit following greater delay due to the regions' initial resistance to any accommodation with the center.23

Policy making The policy-making processes that infuse these quasi- federal institutional structures also resemble those of the United States-but again with significant differences. The EU's predominant pattern of policy making, often called the Community Method, involves a range of governmen- tal and nongovernmental actors in joint decision making akin to the pluralist process of the United States, in which interests are involved in policy formulation, but excluded from policy implementation, which is mainly regulatory, with an arms' length, uniform application of the rules. In the EU, however, policy formulation is less open in terms of interest access because of EU civil servants' gate- keeping role in deciding which interests to allow into the official consultative fora and committees. Their role is more technical than political, given the apolitical status of EU civil servants who privilege technical and scientific bases for decisions. And it is more cooperative than competitive in style, given the EU's consensual culture.24 In addition, EU regulatory implementation is less transparent in mak-

ing rules, given the expert-dominated "comitology" sys- tem; more delegated, given the role of member states in

transposing and enforcing the rules; and less uniform in

application, given national differences in patterns of enforcement.

Here again, EU practices have affected member states. National interests have gained access and influence in

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 765

Page 7: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

an EU policy process that involves a vaster array of actors in a more complex set of interactions with more points of entry than that of any member state.25 Moreover, national administrations have been pressed into more reg- ulatory and legalistic modes of enforcement-where the rules are applied without exception by independent regu- lators and judges-from approaches that often relied instead on administrative discretion, joint regulation, or

self-regulation.26 Adaptation to the EU's policy making processes has

also been particularly difficult for simple member-state

polities, where statist policy formulation traditionally gives little influence to organized interests, but flexible policy implementation allows for their accommodation, either

by making exceptions to the rules as often as not (for example, France) or limiting the number of rules to allow

self-governing arrangements (for example, Britain). In pol- icy formulation, the learning curve for interest groups hop- ing to exert influence at the EU level was perhaps steepest in France, where lobbyists were accustomed to advancing their positions over lunch and relying on political arbitra- tion late in the process, rather than approaching policy makers early with solid technical information-the best way to exert influence in the EU. Now, however, French interests have greater input at the EU level on decisions from which they had been normally excluded at the national level.27 British interests had much less to learn, having honed their lobbying skills in relations with Par- liament and their negotiation skills with the bureaucracy. But they also gained in influence.28

In policy implementation, both countries have had dif- ficulties with the EU requirements to apply the rules with- out exception. In France, where EU requirements go against traditional patterns of administrative discretion, orga- nized interests without access to EU policy formulation find themselves denied past accommodation. They there- fore see no other alternative than to confront national authorities, as in the cases of truck drivers upset about EU-mandated liberalization and public service workers worried about privatization and deregulation.29 In Brit- ain, where the EU's codification of the rules go against traditional preferences for self-regulation and informal

agreements, the problem has been in the increasing num- bers of laws that deny organized interests the voluntary rules and self-governing arrangements of the past, leaving them to complain of the increasing rigidity of the public sphere.30

Adaptation to EU policy processes has been easier for member states with more compound polities, where cor-

poratist processes have traditionally allowed influence in policy formulation and implementation to certain privi- leged interests, mainly business and labor. The EU's open- ness to interests has simply added even more interests into policy formulation, while implementation has not been at issue, since the EU generally allows corporatist implemen-

tation to stand. Germany's interests have readily adapted to the EU's pluralist process, having been schooled in the same kind of cooperative negotiating style and committee work prevalent in the EU, something that has guaranteed their dominion of standard-setting committees.31 None- theless, some corporatist processes have been unbalanced as business has gained greater access than labor in arenas other than labor and social policy,32 and as some busi- nesses have gained greater access than others.33 By com- parison, Italy's organized interests had more to unlearn than to learn, given its clientelistic patterns of influence peddling that are not acceptable at the EU level. In policy implementation, moreover, while Germany's legalistic pat- terns of enforcement largely conform to those of the EU, Italy's problems are potentially even greater than those of France, given that it has traditionally tended to derogate the rules much more.

Politics The EU is most different from the United States in its system of representative politics. In place of a directly elected presidential system with a strong, directly elected legislature and vigorous political parties in a competitive, majoritarian electoral system, it has the indirect represen- tation afforded by national executives through the Coun- cil and the much weaker direct representation of the European Parliament. Unlike the United States, where pol- itics and partisan competition is ever present, in the EU, partisan differences and political contestation have been submerged by the general quest for interest-based consensus.

Again, EU practices have affected member states. National electoral politics have been complicated by vot- ing in European elections, which can become referenda on national elected officials, especially when they occur in the middle of a government's term in office.34 National partisan politics has little outlet in the EU. Most signifi- cantly, national partisan politics has been subordinated, first, to the national interest politics of the Council, as ministers speak more often in the name of the nation than as the representative of the governmental majority; sec- ond, to the public interest politics of the European Parlia- ment, as members of the European Parliament speak for the general good, rather than as representatives of elec- toral majorities; and third, to the organized interest poli- tics of the Commission, as citizens exercise voice more effectively when lobbying in Brussels than voting or pro- testing in national capitals.

As with the Europeanization of institutions and policy making, so with representative politics. Compound polities-where compromise-oriented politics is the norm, given proportional electoral systems with multiple parties and/or two powerful legislative chambers in which con- trol may be divided between government majority and

766 Perspectives on Politics

Page 8: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Table 3 Different challenges depending upon polity type

Compliance with Europeanization T European integraton EU policies

Top-down; I Bottom up; Top-down; Member-state adapts Member-state projects Member-state's

Institutional national practices to national policy capacity to comply fit with EU EU practices preferences on EU with EU policies

Compound polity High Easier to adapt Harder to project Harder to comply with practices preferences policies

Simple polity Low Harder to adapt Easier to project Easier to comply with practices preferences policies

opposition-are a closer match with the EU's quasi- consensual politics than countries with simpler polities- and more conflictual politics.35 In Germany and, to a lesser extent, Italy, the complex negotiations and search for consensus of the EU are not so different from their own politics, since compromise in negotiated settings is a sine qua non of their proportional representation systems, however partisan the politics.36 In simple polities, by con- trast, where majoritarian electoral systems generally pro- vide for stronger governments with less need to negotiate with interests or subnational authorities, the ambiguity of EU-related compromises causes greater disaffection in elec- torates used to more politically demarcated positions. Sup- port for this view can be found in the voting abstention rates, which show a higher margin of disaffection in sim-

ple polities than in compound polities. From the mid 1980s to the late 1990s, abstentionism in national legis- lative elections in France and the UK was up by 14 percent and 16 percent, respectively, from reasonably high levels of 22 and 25 percent; in Germany and Italy it was up by around 7 percent from low levels of around 11 percent.37

Europeanization vs. European integration and policy implementation One caveat, however. Misfit is mainly a problem for sim- ple polities, while fit is an advantage for compound poli- ties when we consider Europeanization as the top-down impact of the EU's governance on its member states. By contrast, in the case of European integration, as the

bottom-up process of projecting national preferences onto the EU, misfit may be an advantage for simple polities and a problem for compound ones. There can be little question that countries like Britain and France, where the executive has hierarchical control of other branches and levels of government, are more effective at the EU level because they can speak with one voice than those where ministries and regions have greater measures of indepen-

dence.38 It follows from this that a more simple institu- tional architecture provides member states an easier time in applying EU policies, since they need not negotiate compliance with subnational regions or corporatist inter- ests, as in many compound polities (see table 3). This said, although compound polities have to negotiate reforms rather than simply impose them, the negotiated outcomes

may work better and to the satisfaction of all.39

Democracy in the EU That national governance has changed in response to Euro-

peanization is not the main problem for EU democracies. Rather, the problem is that their ideas about democracy generally have not changed, leaving questions about the

legitimacy of the new practices and confusion over polit- ical control and accountability-and more so in simple polities where the clash is greater between the new prac- tices and traditional ideas about democracy. To see this

clearly, it is necessary first to consider how democracy in the EU has affected national democracies more generally.

The general impact of EU democracy on national

democracy More ink has been spilt in recent years over the issue of the democratic deficit in the EU than just about any other problem. Democratic theorists have pointed to the lack of

input democracy through political participation and the

impossibility of such given the lack of a collective identity or a common political space.40 Some, however, defend the EU as either providing "output democracy" through effec- tive regulation or as no worse than other democracies, given its checks and balances and delegated authorities.41

Most see the main answer to this problem as the devel- opment of EU-level institutions that are more participa- tory and representative than they are currently-thus the focus on a new Constitutional Treaty intended to strengthen the democratic status of the EU. But this is not so easy.

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 767

Page 9: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

Table 4 Problems of democracy in a range of governance areas

Mode of governance Democratic mechanism Problem Examples I f

Supranational governance through delegated authorities Monnet method of joint decision-making

Electoral politic

Contentious politics

Governance for the people through effective governing Governance with the people through interest consultation

Participatory democracy by the people

Consultative democracy with the people when the democratic processes of by and with break down

Lack of gov by the people problem where rules no longer accepted Altho Brussels center of process, national interests mostly still organize, pressure, and protest at national level Mismatch between national elections focused on policy issues that can only be decided by EU and EP elections focused on polity issues that can be decided only by national leaders (in concert) Protests vs EU policies target nat'l officials who are accountable for implementation but can't change rules while protests vs national policies find more concern but little capacity from EU officials

ECB Stability and Growth Pact

Immigration agriculture

Elections for national parliaments and European Parliaments

Truckers' protests 'euro-strikes' such as Renault

The central problem has to do with the fragmented nature of democracy in the EU. In national polities, democ- racy tends to be based on four legitimizing mechanisms:

government by the people, through political participation (or input democracy); ofthe people, through citizen rep- resentation; for the people through effective government (or output democracy); and what I call (adding a prepo- sition to the traditional formulation) government with the people, through interest consultation (legitimized in the United States as pluralism). In the EU, only two of these four mechanisms are prominent, effective gover- nance for the people and interest consultation with the

people; government by and ofthe people is left largely to the national level.42

There is no consensus to shift government by and of the people to the EU level through EU-wide parliamen- tary elections-nor would this necessarily help democra- tize the EU, given the lack of a collective identity and will. Democratic reforms of the EU still focus mainly on improving governance for the people, through greater accountability and transparency, and with the people, through more interest-based access and a greater opening to "civil society"-meaning more public interest groups,

along with business, labor, and agricultural interests. This does little to decrease the fragmentation of EU democ- racy as a whole.

The deficiencies of fragmented EU-level democracy put tremendous pressure on national politics. The resulting problems cover a wide range of governance areas (see table 4). In areas of supranational governance in which the Commission, the European Central Bank (ECB), or the European Court of Justice (ECJ) have delegated author- ity, the lack of government by the people makes this kind of governance for the people generally problematic. This is especially so in cases where rules formerly agreed are no longer accepted, given that they are very difficult to reverse.43 In monetary policy, for example, while the ECB's role in monetary policy, together with the restrictive terms of the Stability and Growth Pact, limit national govern- ments' ability to take effective demand-side action in eco- nomic downturn, national constituencies still hold national authorities responsible for the state of the economy. At the same time that the Commission took Chancellor Ger- hard Schr6der to task for risking breaching the 3 percent deficit criterion, the German public blamed him for high unemployment and the declining state of the economy. It

768 Perspectives on Politics

Page 10: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

is no surprise, then, that Germany (and France, for similar reasons) bucked the Stability and Growth Pact when their economies were in a state of downturn, and then sought to amend the rules of the Pact. Where such defiance does not work, as in the UK's response to the EU Commis- sion's decisions on the measures regarding mad cow dis- ease or of France's unwillingness to agree to agricultural concessions in the Uruguay Round, national leaders have

sought to convince the public of a good faith effort to

fight the policy at the EU level while moderating its impact nationally-mainly by buying off the most affected inter- ests. The French government offered subsidies to farmers after the Uruguay Round; the British gained EU recom-

pense for farmers in the mad cow crisis.44

Equally problematic are the effects of Europeanization on input democracy by the people when national govern- ments, elected on a platform at the national level, have to

implement EU policies to which they may not be politi- cally committed. This has been the case for successive French governments' implementation of EU deregulation in electricity, which they had all resisted because of its

potential impact on the public utilities that were seen as a

public service obligation of the Republican state.45 The

problems of participatory democracy by the people also suffers because of a mismatch between national elections, which focus on policy issues that increasingly can only be fully addressed at the EU level, such as immigration, food safety, or economic growth, and European parliamentary elections, which tend to focus on more general polity issues that can only be resolved by nationally based actors, such as how to reform EU institutions.46

Finally, contentious politics, consultative democracy with the people when regular consultation breaks down, have also generated problems for national democracies.47 Pro- tests against EU policies target national officials who are accountable for policy implementation, but who can do little to accommodate protesters' concerns. Yet protests focused on local issues may find more response from EU officials than from national ones. On the one hand, truck- ers' blockades of highways in France and Italy to protest EU-mandated deregulation have had little effect on EU policy, although they have forced national governments to buy off truckers through expensive concessions on fuel taxes and the like. On the other hand, the "euro-strikes" against the closing of French car manufacturer Renault's Belgian plant in Vilvoorde garnered the attention of EU officials, who pledged to strengthen plant-closing legisla- tion, and sanctions by those officials, because the manu- facturer had not given prior notice on the plant-closing.48 Yet they led to no French government action against Renault, despite the fact that the new Socialist govern- ment had promised in its election campaign to sanction the still partially government-owned firm.49

The problem for national leaders is that EU-level deci- sion making largely involves policy withoutpolitics, whereas

national level decision making involves politics withoutpol- icy, that is, national control over policy making. Because national citizens lack a system in which one can "throw the scoundrels out" at the EU level, national politics takes the heat for EU decisions. Until citizens begin to see Brus- sels as an equally important place to voice concerns, apply pressure, and protest, national politics will continue to suffer from the bottleneck caused by national govern- ments being the main focus of national discontent. But while a fuller democracy with the people at the EU level would alleviate problems at the national level, it cannot solve all of them. This is because the EU alters the tradi- tional workings of national institutions and challenges tra- ditional ideas about national democracy.

The differential impact of the EU on national democracies The EU not only poses problems for all member states' democracies, but it has differential effects on member states

depending on whether they are simple or compound. The effects are best elucidated in terms of the challenges to the

organizing principles of national democracies constituted by the EU-related changes in institutions, policy pro- cesses, and representative politics.

To begin with, the EU's federalizing diffusion of power through its multiple authorities reinforces the underlying assumptions in compound polities that democracy by the people is best served by dispersing government power such that citizens' rights are protected from government excess

through vertical and horizontal checks and balances. In Germany, this sits well with a centuries-old history of

regional power and a postwar constitution written to pre- vent any possible return to the excesses of centralized power. By contrast, the EU challenges the traditional assump- tions in simpler polities that democracy is better served by the concentration of governmental power vertically and horizontally such that the government has the sole respon- sibility as well as the capacity to respond to citizens' wants and needs. For France, the EU challenges the country's Jacobin philosophical foundations that concentrate author- ity in the "one and indivisible" Republican state. For Brit- ain it undermines the authority of the executive as the embodiment of parliamentary sovereignty. In Italy the EU reinforces the assumptions underlying the increasingly regionalized practices that disperse power, even as it chal- lenges what is still in principle a unitary state.

Similarly, the EU's pluralizing of member-state policy formulation through increasing interest influence bolsters the views in compound polities that effective governing for the people demands the greatest openness to multiple inputs from intermediate interests through multiple cen- ters of power via consultation with the people. For Ger- many and Italy, the EU only reinforces legitimacy, since it adds a wider range of interests to those traditionally

December 2005 1 Vol. 3/No. 4 769

Page 11: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

involved in corporatist or clientelistic processes. By con- trast, EU-related institutional changes clash with the

assumptions of simple polities that the executive governs most effectively for all the people while ensuring against governmental excess by being closed to interest consulta- tion with the people. For France, open interest consul- tation offends ideas prevalent since the Revolution that see it as illegitimate; in Britain, it clashes with ideas of executive autonomy.

In implementation, moreover, the EU's regulatory model clashes with simple polities' commitment to flexibility. For France, the EU's insistence on applying the rules with- out exceptions reduces the executive's ability to govern effectively for the people in implementation by accommo-

dating minority interests harmed by majority decisions in

policy formulation. For Britain, the problem is rather with the statutes that, by abrogating organized interests' self-

regulatory arrangements, increase the scope and rigidity of the public sphere and thereby encroach on the private sphere. By contrast, the EU again tends to reinforce legit- imacy in compound polities by promoting governing effec- tiveness for the people through regulatory and legalistic processes (which also predominate in Germany), by allow-

ing corporatist processes to continue (in both Germany and Italy), or by substituting regulatory enforcement for a discredited clientelism (in Italy).

Finally, the EU depoliticization of representative poli- tics by way of interest-based, consensus-oriented politics sustains the assumption in compound polities that polit- ical compromise among the plethora of authorities rep- resentative of the people, elected by the people, and open to interest intermediation with the people, is the best

way to express the will of all the people. In Germany, it matches a consensus-oriented political culture that expects compromise among federal and regional governments; government and opposition (when in control of the upper house); and government, business, and labor (on labor- related policies). In Italy, it fits with a conflict-ridden

political culture that accepts the need for compromise among myriad parties in coalition governments, with

regional governments (on regional issues), and with the social partners (on labor-related policies). By contrast, the EU's depoliticzation of representative politics clashes with the expectation in simple polities that political lead-

ership by a single executive, representative of and elected

by the people, requires fulfillment of all political commit- ments made to the electorate. For France and Britain, it undermines conflict-based political cultures which expect the government to impose its electoral program without

compromise-although in France unpopular programs are immediately sanctioned through protest in the streets, whereas in Britain's "elected dictatorship" the main sanc- tions come from elections.

In short, even though EU legitimacy may be increasing with the development of EU institutions, national legiti-

macy suffers from the effects of EU governance on national democracies more so for simple polities, where legitimacy is focused on a single authority than for compound poli- ties, where it rides on the system as a whole. Thus although national publics generally hold their own politicians accountable, the public of simple polities hold their poli- ticians more accountable because they see them as more fully responsible for and more politically committed to all decisions, whether or not EU-related, than the public of more compound polities, who know that their politicians are never fully in control of any decisions, even those they are committed to politically. Questions of democratic legit- imacy therefore come up more frequently in simple poli- ties, since they can arise in response to any unpopular policy, than in compound polities, where democratic legit- imacy is at issue when the people lose trust in the system as a whole.

Other problems for national democracy There are limits to the significance of institutional fit with

regard to ideas about democracy. The organizing princi- ples of democracy are not the only ideas that affect responses to Europeanization; so do other historically and culturally grounded values and interests-political, social, and eco- nomic (see fig. 2).

In simple polities, for example, consideration of polit- ical, social, and economic values can elucidate how coun- tries mediate the clash between the EU and their democratic

organizing principles-for example, why the French, with their ideas about a civilizing cultural mission and the uni- versal rights of man, have embraced Europeanization despite its potential impact on the powers of the Repub- lican state, whereas the British have kept Europe more at arms' length because it threatens ideas about the rights of

Englishmen and parliamentary sovereignty. In compound polities, social and political values show how the fit with democratic organizing principles was enhanced, with

Germany's embracing Europe as a way to submerge national

identity in a larger whole; Italy's, a way to rescue the nation- state; and Spain's (like Greece's, despite its "simpler" pol- ity), a way to reinforce democracy.

National values can also help explain responses to the EU policy issues. Sweden and Denmark, for example, resisted becoming part of the European Monetary Union because they were concerned about its impact on social

justice in the social democratic welfare state, while Ger-

many embraced the EMU because it fit with notions of economic order and the stability, despite the public's qualms about giving up the Deutschmark and problems related to its exchange rate value. In addition, although the French and the Germans have both on the whole been pro- European, when EU policies threaten Germany's eco- nomic order-through decisions against the lending practices of the regional banks-or the French state's social

770 Perspectives on Politics

Page 12: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Figure 2 National responses to EU-related changes in governance practices

A

Organizing principles

of democracy

Political, social, and economic

values

Interests

Germany -- Germany (submerge identity) .-OGermany (economic prosperity)

Complement

EU-Related Changes in Governance Practices

Clash

Italy

Spain

Denmark Sweden

Germany

France

UK

-+ Italy (rescue pride and nation-state)

Italy (overcome paralysis)

Spain (reinforce democracy) -- Spain (economic prosperity, Germany manage externalities)

iGermany (reinforce democracy) Fae (civiliing missn . France (lead politically)

* France (civilizing mission,- . universal rights of man) Sweden (manage economy

I/ / Denmark externalities) Y /

Sweden (social justice, Denmark identity)

UK (rights of Englishmen, parliamentary sovereignty)

............ U.,..(prQm.. te.. eeon..Qmi.c ? interests)

v

service mission-through liberalization of public utilities- the responses are as negative as the British or the Swedes on the euro. What is more, the French no vote in the referendum on the Constitutional Treaty made clear that policy issues related to the euro's impact on the welfare state or liberalization on the services publics go to the heart of the left's social justice concerns, while the impact of enlargement and immigration on national identity was the major concern on the right. The same concerns explain the Dutch no vote, although the euro's alleged inflation- ary impact was also an issue.

Interests also matter, of course. One cannot understand the push for European integration without recognizing

the economic, political, and social interests that enabled countries to overcome ideational obstacles to change- the French desire to lead politically in Europe; the Ger- man interest in economic growth and social stability; the British willingness to follow economic interest despite polit- ical reticence; the Italian hope to overcome the hazards of state paralysis; or the need for small states such as Den- mark, Sweden, and Austria to be part of a larger political entity in order better to manage economic externalities.

Experiences of European integration or policy imple- mentation may also affect perceptions of the EU. Thus, for example, success in projecting national preferences onto the EU can offset concerns about the impact of the EU on

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 771

Compound

Simple

t I

i i w

Page 13: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

national democratic practices and ideas. In France, lead-

ership in the EU has long served to obscure the state's real loss of power. By contrast, success in policy implementa- tion may only increase concerns about the impact of the EU, as in Britain, whose stellar compliance record has

only meant that it has felt the effects of Europeanization more, thereby adding to the clash with national ideas.

Finally, Britain's experience of better economic perfor- mance outside the eurozone than France's, Germany's, or

Italy's within it, also helps explain its continued reluctance to join the European Monetary Union.

The Real Democratic Deficit That democracy in the EU regional state is fragmented and does not match the democracy of any nation-state, by emphasizing democracy for and with the people over and above democracy by and of the people, is not the problem for democracy in the EU. Moreover, even the fact that EU-level democracy has challenged national ideas about

democracy is not the problem, or that those challenges are

greater for simple than compound polities. The problem for democracy is that national leaders and publics have failed to come to terms with the changes to the traditional

workings of their democracies. While national governance has changed dramatically in

the process of Europeanization, leaders have not only not

generated new ideas to legitimize the new practices, but

they have also persisted in speaking about Europeaniza- tion as if the old ideas about democracy still applied, as if little has changed, though everything has. Although EU policy issues are often at the forefront of national discourse, as politicians blame the EU for unpopular pol- icies or take credit for popular ones, issues related to the

changes in governance practices take a back seat except at certain defining moments-times of treaty referenda or accession agreements. Even though this is understandable-

politicians, after all, are not likely to use their scarce polit- ical resources to speak about changes that are complicated and difficult to sell, and there are no electoral incentives to do so-it adds to the problems of the democratic deficit. These problems have been dramatized most recently by the fiasco of the ratification of the Constitutional Treaty.

In France, for example, national leaders ignore the impact of the EU on the national polity, focusing instead on France's impact on the EU. Thus they still speak as if the state were unitary, despite the federalizing trends related not only to the EU but also to internal reforms, as in the case of Corsica. France continues to insist that it remains a leader in Europe, despite the faltering of the Franco- German partnership and the fact that it has followed much more than led in the 1990s, and sometimes reluctantly, as in the liberalization of the public services industries50 or in its change in immigration policy.51 The failures of this kind of discourse came home to roost with the referen-

dum on the Constitutional Treaty in 2005. Mainstream leaders in the yes campaign, who spoke mainly about EU-level institutional reforms and the need for continued French leadership in Europe, were drowned out by voices for the no vote, which focused on the national-level impact of EU policies related to liberalization, enlargement, and

immigration-when they were not more simply voting against the government leadership and decisions taken with- out consultation.

In Britain, by contrast, leaders have often highlighted the EU's negative impact on national practices. Prime Min- ister Margaret Thatcher engaged in polemical diatribes

against ambitious integration plans that challenged national

sovereignty and excess regulations that reduced the private sphere while rigidifying the public sphere. John Major did the same through a quieter, but equally negative, dis- course. Tony Blair, by contrast, has largely remained silent, in particular over possible entry into the eurozone, which has been portrayed as a strictly economic problem- leaving Fleet Street to continue the negative polity dis- course. The result is that the public has been made

maximally aware of the drawbacks to Europeanization and told few of the benefits, such that any government that moves toward greater integration risks being seen as under-

mining British democracy. The referendum on the Con- stitutional Treaty tentatively scheduled for the end of 2006 would have been very hard to win, even if Blair couched it as a question of Britain being in or out of Europe- pitting current economic interests against old political val- ues. As it turns out, the no votes in France and the Netherlands let Blair off the hook.

Neither Germany nor Italy has had problems as seri- ous as those of France and Britain with regard to the

changes in governance, given their better fit with the EU as compound democracies. Thus the discourse of national leaders about the EU's national impact has been mostly positive. For Italy, the problems with governance prac- tices may come when it is forced to implement the EU rules. For Germany, problems are more likely when EU

policies are seen to challenge its social market economy (of which decision by the Competition Commission

against the regional state-owned savings and loan banks was a foretaste), because it is seen as fundamental to citizens' economic and social rights. Moreover, because both countries had parliamentary votes ratifying the Con- stitutional Treaty, there were no public debates of the kind that occurred in France and the Netherlands.

The referenda saying no to Europe were a wake-up call to national leaders that the democratic deficit they were

trying to remedy at the EU level through the Constitu- tional Treaty was felt more intensely at the national level. The referenda were in fact all about politics-the lack of

government by the people at the EU level and national electorates' desire to make their views heard on the EU as a whole as well as on particular policies over which they

772 Perspectives on Politics

Page 14: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

have had very little say. Ironi- Figure 3 cally the no vote in the refer- Discourse interactions i] enda stopped the EU-level institutional reforms that

might have introduced more

politics into the EU policy pro- Compound cess and thereby made it pos- National Polity sible for voters' policy concerns to be addressed.

Moreover, the political fall- out from the Constitutional

Treaty referendum has increas-

ingly split mainstream politi- cal parties down the middle- oordinative into pro and anti-Europeans- with policy leaving an opening on both sides of the political spectrum for extremes to exploit. Increas- C ing polarization has gone hand in hand with citizens' loss of trust in both national govern- ments and EU institutions,52 \ with rampant cynicism and

growing political apathy appar- ent in ever higher rates of elec- toral abstentionism-with the

exception of the no votes in the referenda.53 \j \j

The democratic deficit, in Interest Group short, is a problem at the Constituencies national level. And it will remain a problem as long as national leaders and citizens in the member states do not reevaluate what they mean by national democracy today, even before they decide how to democratize the EU for tomorrow. The EU is no longer an elite project supported by a permissive consensus. But it is not yet a peoples' project grounded in a democratic consensus.

How can leaders build democratic consensus? To answer this, we need to consider the patterns of discourse in Euro-

pean democracy at both EU and national levels, which also differ in simple and compound polities.

Patterns and Problems of Discourse in Europe The new EU governance has generated new patterns of discourse which have differentially affected simple and com-

pound polities. Discourse, after all, is not just about what you say, but also about who talks to whom while con-

structing new policies and communicating them to the public.54 Thus there are two forms of discursive inter- action: a coordinative discourse of policy construction and a communicative discourse of political legitimization.55

n simple and compound national polities

Simple National Polity

In the domain of coordinative discourse, the main inter- locutors are policy actors-experts, organized interests, civil servants, elected officials, and public figures-who coordi- nate agreement often using ideas conveyed by policy entre-

preneurs and/or developed in discursive communities- whether policy networks based on the exchange of ideas, epistemic communities united by shared ideas, ad-

vocacy coalitions sharing ideas and access to policy mak-

ing, or strong publics that critically deliberate about

policies.56 In the domain of the communicative discourse, the key interlocutors are political actors-politicians, spin doctors, campaign managers, government spokespersons, party activists-who communicate the ideas developed through coordinative discourse to the public-including the general public of citizens, the informed publics of orga- nized private persons, and policy forums of community lead- ers, activists, experts, organized interests, the media-for deliberation and, ideally, modification.57

Most important for our study, polities differ in their emphasis on the coordinative or communicative dis- course, largely as a result of institutional context (see fig. 3).

December 2005 1 Vol. 3/No. 4 773

Page 15: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

In compound polities, the dis- Figure 4

persion of power, widespread Discourse interactions i interest consultation, and con- sensus-oriented politics ensure that the coordinative discourse is elaborate and the communi- cative discourse thin. Here, the

large number of policy actors EU c

making decisions must delib- erate extensively as well as come to terms with their own con- stituencies; while leaders are

expected to communicate with the general public only in vague Com d terms, since detailed discussion coordinative risks unraveling compromises discourse reached in private. By contrast, in simple polities, the concen- Col tration of power, the restricted comn nature of interest consultation, dis and the polarization of politics ensures that the coordinative discourse is thin and the com- municative discourse elaborate. In the absence of widespread policy coordination and in the face of certain opposition from IntJes- grjg

i . . * * * constituenbids other parties and minority in- cons terests, political actors have

greater need to legitimate new ideas directly with the general public.58

In the EU, the discursive

pattern of compound polities is even more pronounced. The EU's coordinative dis- course involves a wide range of policy actors at both national and EU levels. Policies are generated, for exam-

ple, by the ideas of the "epistemic communities" of central bankers, economists, and financial reporters tied to EMU; by the discursive policy networks of EU, national, and

regional actors; or by advocacy coalitions.59 Moreover, pol- icies are debated in the supranational deliberative democ-

racy or directly-deliberative polyarchy of the EU-anointed national experts, government representatives, and inter- ests meeting in "comitology" committees; they are cri-

tiqued through the strong publics constituted by the Parliament; and they are decided in the arenas of the Coun- cil and Commission.60

By contrast, the EU's communicative discourse has very few actors capable of speaking for the EU as a whole and no single public to address. This is not only for want of a common European language, media, political parties, and public opinion-let alone a European citizenry or directly elected president. It is also because the institutional design of the EU provides for no strong central voice; the Com-

in the EU

mission president is the most visible (and audible) spokes- person, but authority relies heavily on the force of his or her personality. (Constitutional reforms might have helped remedy this situation, with proposals for a new foreign minister and nonrotating president of the Council in addi- tion to the Commission.)

All in all, while the EU benefits from the most elabo- rate of coordinative discourses, it suffers from the thinnest of communicative discourses, with policy ideas conveyed mostly indirectly by national political actors in national contexts.61 As such, it has had a differential impact on countries with simple and compound discursive patterns (see fig. 4).

In simple polities, national political leaders can speak clearly and in one voice to the changes in national prac- tices and Europeanization's challenges to traditional ideas about democracy. But rather than addressing these issues, political leaders' communicative discourses have increas-

ingly focused on purely national issues, whether public services in Blair's second term or the 35-hour work week in Lionel Jospin's prime ministership, leaving the impact

774 Perspectives on Politics

Page 16: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

of Europeanization open to exploitation by political extrem- ists. A consequence of this has been the "no" vote in the French referendum.

Compound polities confront a different set of prob- lems since political leaders are schooled in communicat-

ing only in vague terms on the agreements reached among the actors involved in the coordinative discourse of policy construction. Here, it is good that Europeanization has been less of a challenge to compound polities' organizing principles of democracy, since the general poverty of the communicative discourse makes for a cacophony of voices where there is no consensus. This was clearly the problem in the Dutch referendum, which was made worse by national leaders' inability to articulate any clear message in the communicative discourse-this having been the first time they had ever had a referendum on any issue, let alone on the EU.

Europeanization, in short, is problematic to its mem- ber states not so much because of the changes in national

practices as because of the lack of new ideas and discourse to address those changes. For simple polities like Britain and France, the challenge is to change ideas about the

polity. The strong communicative discourse exists to make that a possibility, if only leaders were willing to try. For

Germany and Italy, it is good that the polity issues are not as serious, since they would have a much harder time

projecting a successful communicative discourse. As it is, policy issues that challenge deep-seated values do need to be addressed-and this is where potential problems lie.

Notes 1 There is a debate about how to define Europeaniza-

tion (Olsen 2002; Radaelli 2003). Some scholars define it as I do, as a top-down process of EU impact on its member states (for example, Ladrech 1994; Radaelli 2003; B6rzel and Risse 2000; Schmidt 2002a). Others focus only on the bottom-up process of what I call European integration, as the projection of member-state preferences onto the EU (Caporaso and Jupille 1999). Yet others include both top-down and bottom-up processes (Cowles, Caporaso, and Risse 2001). I find the distinction useful for analytic pur- poses, although the two are part of the same overall dynamic, with feedback effects going in both directions.

2 Schmidt 2004. 3 Schmidt 2002a, chap. 5; Schmidt 2004. 4 Schmidt 2002a; Schmidt and Radaelli 2004. 5 Although this distinction between simple and com-

pound polities owes much to Lijphart's (1984) dichotomy of majoritarian and consensus democra- cies, it differs in its focus on three dimensions- structures, processes, and politics-instead ofLijphart's two, federal-unitary and executive-parties. His first dimension of federal-unitary fits my "structures" cat-

egory perfectly but his second dimension of executive-

parties collapses into one my two categories of "politics" (containing majoritarian and proportional rep- resentation systems) and "processes." Within the lat- ter, he also collapses into two, pluralist and corporatist, my three categories of pluralist, corporatist, and statist.

6 Certain policy sectors may function in more simple or compound manner, despite a country's overall

pattern. In security and defense policy and monetary policy, for example, most countries operate as more

"simple" polities. 7 There is actually a closer resemblance to German fed-

eralism than American (Scharpf 1988; Sbragia 1993). 8 Marks, Hooghe, and Blank 1996; Hooghe and

Marks 2001. 9 Nicolaides 2001.

10 Schmidt 1999a. 11 On legislatures, see Duina and Oliver 2004 and

Norton 1996a. On the courts, see Stone Sweet 2000; Burley and Mattli 1993; Weiler 1994. On subnational authorities, see Hooghe 1996 and Keat-

ing and Jones 1995. 12 Schmidt 1999a. 13 Jeffery 1999; Fabbrini 2003. 14 Saalfeld 1996. 15 Rizzuto 1996. 16 Norton 1996b. 17 Stone 1992. 18 Conant 2001. 19 Stone Sweet 2000. 20 Stone Sweet 2000. 21 Schmidt 1990. 22 Loughlin et al. 2001. 23 Borzel 2002. 24 Schmidt 1999b. 25 Greenwood 2003. 26 Majone 1996. 27 Schmidt 1996; Schmidt 1999b. 28 Greenwood 2003. 29 Schmidt 1996. 30 Schmidt 1999b; Schmidt 2001. 31 Egan 2001, 144-45. 32 Falkner 1998. 33 Cowles 2001. 34 Gabel 2001; van der Eijk and Franklin 1996. 35 Lijphart 1984. 36 Italy lately has been more complicated, since under

Berlusconi we see increased polarization and less compromise.

37 Brechon 2002, 103. 38 Other factors are of course also at work, such as

relative size and economic weight (with bigger coun- tries having greater sway than smaller), strategic position (for example, when a country has the presi- dency of the European Council), or good ideas and

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 775

Page 17: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

innovative practices (for example, Germany with

regard to European Monetary Union, with all that it entailed in terms of monetary stability and indepen- dent central banks).

39 Although institutional "fit" is the primary factor with regard to the impact of EU institutions on national ones, it is only one of a number with regard to the impact of EU policies on national ones. See Schmidt 2001; Schmidt 2002a; Scharpf 2000b; Heritier 2000.

40 Scharpf 2000b; Weiler 1995; Grimm 1995, Haber- mas 1996; Greven 2000.

41 Majone 1998; Moravcsik 2002. 42 Schmidt 2004. 43 Scharpf 2000b. 44 Bush and Simi 2001. 45 Eising and Jabko 2001. 46 Mair 2001. 47 Imig and Tarrow 200 la. 48 Imig and Tarrow 200 lb. 49 Schmidt 2002a, 284. 50 Eising and Jabko 2001. 51 Geddes and Guiraudon 2004 52 Reynie and Cautres 2001, 243-44; Brechon 2002,

103. 53 Klingemann 1999; Pharr and Putnam 2000. 54 One question that always comes up in analyzing

discourse is that people always talk, so when does it matter and when does it not? This depends upon how good or persuasive the ideas are-such that

people change their minds in response to "arguing" rather than just remaining in a "bargaining" mode (Risse 1998) and reconceptualize interests rather than just reify them. The causal influence of dis- course can be demonstrated through studies that

engage in process-tracing of ideas to show how they led actors to different policy choices (Berman 1998; Blyth 2002); studies that show how speakers "en- trap" their publics through "rhetorical action"

(Schimmelfennig 2001); or studies that take matched pairs of cases where everything is controlled for but the discourse (Schmidt 2002c; see discussion in Schmidt 2002a).

55 See Schmidt 2002a, chaps. 5 and 6. 56 Kohler-Koch 2002; Haas 1992; Sabatier 1998;

Eriksen and Fossum 2002. 57 Eriksen and Fossum 2002; Habermas 1989; Rein

and Sch6n 1994. 58 Schmidt 2002a, chap. 5. Institutional context also

makes for a difference in where to test for the causal influence of discourse. In simple polities, where the communicative discourse is most elaborate, causal influence is most likely to be evidenced in public responses, whether acceptance through quiescence and positive election results or rejection through

protest or positive or negative election results, opin- ion polls, and surveys. In compound polities, where the coordinative discourse is most elaborate, causal influence is more likely to be evident in whether

policy actors reach agreement or not, with empirical investigation focused on interviews with and reports of the policy actors themselves.

59 Haas 1992; Verdun 2000; Kohler-Koch 2002; Sa- batier 1998.

60 Joerges 1999; Gerstenberg and Sable 2000; Eriksen and Fossum 2002; Jobert 2001.

61 Schmidt 2004.

References Berman, Sheri. 1998. The social democratic moment:

Ideas and politics in the making of interwar Europe. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Blyth, Mark. 2002. Great transformations: Economic ideas and institutional change in the twentieth century. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Borzel, Tanja, and Thomas Risse. 2000. When Europe hits home: Europeanization and domestic change. European Integration Online Papers (EIOP) 4 (15): 1-24.

2002. States and regions in the European Union: Institutional adaptation in Germany and Spain. Cam-

bridge: Cambridge University Press. Brechon, Pierre. 2002. Des valeurs politiques entre

perennite et changement. Futuribles 277: 92-128.

Burley, Anne-Marie, and Walter Mattli. 1993. Europe before the court: A political theory of legal integra- tion. International Organization 47 (1): 41-76.

Bush, Evelyn, and Pete Simi. 2001. European farmers and their protests. In Contentious Europeans: Protest

andpolitics in an emergingpolity, ed. Douglas Imig and Sidney Tarrow, 97-124. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield.

Caporaso, James, and Joseph Jupille. 1999. Institu- tionalism and the EU: Beyond IR and comparatives politics. Annual Review of Political Science 2: 429-444.

Conant, Lisa. 2001. Contested legal boundaries and institutional adaptations: The Europeanization of the law in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom. In

Transforming Europe: Europeanization and domestic

change, ed. Maria Green Cowles, James Caporaso, and Thomas Risse, 97-115. Ithaca, NY: Cornell

University Press. .2002. Justice contained: Law andpolitics in the

European Union. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Cowles, Maria Green. 2001. The transatlantic business

dialogue. In Transforming Europe, ed. Maria Green Cowles, James Caporaso, and Thomas Risse, 159-79. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

776 Perspectives on Politics

Page 18: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Cowles, Maria Green, James Caporaso, and Thomas Risse, eds. 2001. Transforming Europe: Europeaniza- tion and domestic change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univer-

sity Press. Duina, Francesco, and Michael J. Oliver. 2004. Na-

tional parliaments in the European Union: Are there

any benefits to integration? Paper presented at the American Political Science Association National

Meetings, Chicago, September 1-5.

Egan, Michelle. 2001. Constructing a European market: Trade barriers, regulatory strategies and corporate re-

sponses. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Eising, Rainer, and Nicolas Jabko. 2001. Moving tar-

gets: Institutional embeddedness and domestic poli- tics in the liberalization of EU electricity markets.

Comparative Political Studies 34 (7): 742-67. Eriksen, Erik 0., and John Erik Fossum. 2002. Democ-

racy through strong publics in the European Union? Journal of Common Market Studies 40 (3): 401-24.

Fabbrini, Sergio, ed. 2003. L'Europeizzazione dell'Italia:

L'impatto dell'Unione Europea sulle istituzioni e le

politiche italiane. Rome: Laterza. Falkner, Gerda. 1998. EU social policy in the 1990s:

Towards a corporatist policy community. London:

Routledge. Gabel, Matthew. 2001. European integration, voters,

and national politics. In Europeanisedpolitics, ed. Klaus Goetz and Simon Hix, 52-73. London: Frank Cass.

Geddes, Andrew and Virginie Guiraudon. 2004. Brit- ain, France, and EU anti-discrimination policy: The

emergence of a EU paradigm. West European Politics 27 (2): 334-53.

Gerstenberg, 0., and C. Sable. 2000. Directly-deliberative polyarchy: An institutional ideal for Europe? www2.

law.columbia.edu/sabel/papers/gerst-sabel 1029.doc Greenwood, Justin. 2003. Interest representation in the

European Union. Basingstoke: Palgrave/Macmillan. Greven, Michael T. 2000. Can the European Union

finally become a democracy? In Democracy beyond the state? The European dilemma and the emerging global order, ed. Michael T. Greven and Louis W. Pauly, 35-62. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield.

Grimm, Dieter. 1995. Does Europe need a constitution? European Law Journal 1 (3): 282-302.

Haas, Peter M. 1992. Introduction: Epistemic commu- nities and international policy coordination. Inter- national Organization 46 (1): 1-35.

Habermas, Jiirgen. 1989. The structural transformation of the public sphere. Tr. T. Burger and F Lawrence. Cam- bridge: MIT Press.

. 1996. Between facts and norms: Contributions to a discourse theory. London: Polity Press.

Hertier, Adrienne. 2000. Differential Europe: National administrative responses to community policy. In

Europeanization and domestic change, eds. Maria Green Cowles, James Caporaso, and Thomas Tisse. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Hooghe, Liesbeth, ed. 1996. Cohesion policy, the Euro-

pean Community and subnational government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks. 2001. Multi-level

governance and European integration. Lanham, Mary- land: Rowman and Littlefield.

Imig, Douglas, and Simon Tarrow, eds.. 2001a. Conten- tious Europeans. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

. 2001b. Political contention in a Europeanising polity. In Europeanisedpolitics, ed. Klaus Goetz and Simon Hix, 73-93. London: Frank Cass.

Jeffery, Charlie. 1999. Recasting German federalism. London: Pinter.

Jobert, Bruno. 2001. Europe and the reshaping of na- tional forums: The French case. Paper prepared for

presentation at the conference Ideas, Discourse and

European Integration, European Union Center, Har- vard University, May 11-12.

Joerges, Christian. 1999. Good governance through comitology? In EU committees: Social regulation, law, andpolitics, ed. Christian Joerges and Ellen Vos, 311-38. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

Keating, Michael, and Brian Jones. 1995. The European Union and the regions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. 1999. Mapping political support in the 1990s. In Critical citizens, ed. P. Nor- ris. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Kohler-Koch, Beate. 2002. European networks and ideas: Changing national policies? European Integra- tion Online Papers 6 (6).

Kohler-Koch, Beate, and Rainer Eising, eds. 1999. The

transformation ofgovernance in the European Union. London: Routledge.

Ladrech, Robert. 1994. The Europeanization of domes- tic politics: The case of France. Journal of Common Market Studies 32 (1): 69-88.

Lijphart, Arend. 1984. Democracies: Patterns of majori- tarian and consensus government in twenty-one coun- tries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Loughlin, John, Eliseo Aja, Udo Bullmann, Frank Hen- driks, and Anders Lidstrom. 2001. Subnational de- mocracy in the European Union: Challenges and opportunities. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Mair, Peter. 2001. The limited impact of Europe on national party systems. In Europeanisedpolitics, ed. Klaus Goetz and Simon Hix, 27-51. London: Frank Cass.

Majone, Giandomenico. 1998. Europe's democratic deficit. European Law Journal4 (1): 5-28.

,ed. 1996. Regulating Europe. London and New York: Routledge.

December 2005 I Vol. 3/No. 4 777

Page 19: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Articles I Democracy in Europe

Marks, Gary, Liesbeth Hooghe, and Kermit Blank. 1996. European integration since the 1980s: State- centric versus multi-level governance. Journal of Com- mon Market Studies 34 (3): 341-78.

Moravcsik, A. 2002. Reassessing legitimacy in the Euro-

pean Union. Journal of Common Market Studies 40 (4): 603-24.

Nicolaides, Kalypso. 2001. Conclusion: The federal vision beyond the nation-state. In The federal vision, ed. Kalypso Nicolaides and Robert Howse, 439-82. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Norton, Philip. 1996a. The United Kingdom: Political conflict, parliamentary scrutiny. In Nationalparlia- ments and the European Union, ed. Philip Norton. London: Frank Cass.

, ed. 1996b. National parliaments and the Euro-

pean Union. London: Frank Cass. Olsen, Johan. 2002. The many faces of Europeanization.

ARENA Working Papers WP 02/2. http://www. arena. uio.no/publications/wp02_2.htm.

Pharr, Susan J., and Robert D. Putnam, eds. 2000. Dis-

affected democracies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Radaelli, Claudio M. 2003. The Europeanisation of

public policy. In The politics of Europeanisation, ed. Kevin Featherstone and Claudio M. Radaelli, 27-56. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Radaelli, Claudio M., and Vivien A. Schmidt. 2004.

Mapping the scope of discourse, learning, and Euro-

peanisation in policy change. West European Politics 27 (2): 183-210.

Rein, M., and Schon, D. A. 1994. Frame reflection: Toward the resolution of intractable policy controver- sies. New York: BasicBooks.

Reynie, Dominique, and Bruno Cautres. 2001.

L'opinion europeenne. Paris: Presses de Sciences Po.

Risse, Thomas. 1998. "Let's argue!" Communicative action in world politics. International Organization 54 (1): 1-39.

Rizzuto, Franco. 1996. The French parliament and the EU: Loosening the constitutional straitjacket. In

Nationalparliaments and the European Union, ed.

Philip Norton. London: Frank Cass. Saalfeld, Thomas. 1996. The German houses of parlia-

ment and European legislation. In Nationalparlia- ments and the European Union, ed. Philip Norton. London: Frank Cass.

Sabatier, Paul A. 1998. The advocacy coalition frame- work: Revisions and relevance for Europe. Journal of European Public Policy 5 (1): 98-130.

Sbragia, Alberta. 1993. The European community: A

balancing act. Publius 23 (3): 23-38.

Scharpf, Fritz W. 1988. The joint decision trap: Lessons from German federalism and European integration. Public Administration 66 (3): 239-78.

.2000a. Economic changes, vulnerabilities, and institutional capabilities. In Welfare and work in the

open economy. Vol. 1, From vulnerability to competi- tiveness, ed. Fritz Scharpf and Vivien A. Schmidt, 21-124. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

.2000b. Governing in Europe. Oxford: Oxford

University Press. .2002a. Concepualizing democratic accountability

beyond the state: The European Union. Unpublished manuscript. (June).

Schimmelfennig, Frank. 2001. The community trap: Liberal norms, rhetorical action, and the eastern

enlargement of the European Union. International

Organization 55 (1): 47-80. Schmidt, Vivien A. 1990. Democratizing France: The

political and administrative history of decentralization.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. . 1996. From state to market? The transformation

of French business and government. New York and London: Cambridge University Press.

. 1999a. European "federalism" and its encroach- ments on national institutions. Publius 29 (1): 19-44.

. 1999b. National patterns of governance under

siege: The impact of European integration. In The

transformation ofgovernance in the European Union, ed. Beate Kohler-Koch and Rainer Eising, 155-172. London: Routledge.

.2001. Federalism and state governance in the EU and the US: An institutional perspective. In The

federal vision: Legitimacy and levels ofgoverance in the U.S. and the European Union, ed. K. Nicholaides and R. Howse. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

. 2002a. The futures of European capitalism. Ox- ford: Oxford University Press.

.2002b. Does discourse matter in the politics of welfare state adjustment? Comparative Political Studies 35 (2): 168-93.

.2004. The European Union: Democratic legiti- macy in a regional state? Journal of Common Market Studies 42 (4): 975-98.

Schmidt, Vivien A., and Claudio Radaelli. 2004. Con-

ceptual and methodological issues in policy change in

Europe. Introduction to Symposium issue of West

European Politics 27 (4): 1-28. Stone, Alec. 1992. The birth of judicial politics: The

constitutional council in comparative perspective. New York: Oxford University Press.

Stone Sweet, Alec. 2000. Governing with judges: Consti-

tutionalpolitics in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Van der Eijk, Cees, and Mark N. Franklin. 1996. Choos-

ing Europe? The European electorate and nationalpoli- ties in theface of union. Ann Arbor, MI: University of

Michigan Press.

778 Perspectives on Politics

Page 20: Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration · Democracy in Europe: The Impact of European Integration Vivien A. Schmidt Europeanization has brought radical change to

Verdun, Amy. 2000. European responses to globalization and financial market integration: Perceptions of Euro-

pean Monetary Union in Britain, France, and Ger-

many. Basingstoke: Macmillan. Weiler, J. H. H. 1994. A quiet revolution: The Euro-

pean Court of Justice and its interlocutors. Compara- tive Political Studies 26 (4): 510-34.

1995. The state "iiber alles": Demos, telos and the German Maastricht decision. Jean Monnet Work-

ing Paper Series 6/95. Cambridge: Harvard Law School.

1999. The constitution of Europe: "Do the new clothes have an emperor?" and other essays on European integration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

December 2005 1 Vol. 3/No. 4 779