DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3...

59
Engineering the Policy–making Life Cycle Document Type: Deliverable Dissemination Level: PU (Public) Editor: Attilio Raimondi Document state: Final version (waiting for EC approval) Document version: 1.0 Contributing Partners: ALL Contributing WPs: WP2 Estimated P/M (if applicable): n.a. Date of Completion: 31 st of December, 2012 Date of Delivery to EC: 31 st of December, 2012 Number of Pages: ABSTRACT This deliverable provides a general overview of the regional plans features that are modelled and supported within the ePolicy framework. In particular, the following aspects have been considered: Objectives, Financial Constraints, Environmental, Social and Economic Impacts, and Implementation Strategies. This document provides a general overview of how the ePolicy approach treats and models these aspects. Deliverable D2.2 “Impacts, constraints, objectives and implementation strategies in Regional Planning: General Aspects” The project is cofunded by the European Community under the Information and Communication Technologies (ICT) theme of the Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/20072013). Grant Agreement n°288147.

Transcript of DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3...

Page 1: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

Engineering  the  Policy–making  Life  Cycle  

 

 

 

Document  Type:   Deliverable  Dissemination  Level:   PU  (Public)  Editor:   Attilio  Raimondi  Document  state:   Final  version  (waiting  for  EC  approval)  Document  version:   1.0  Contributing  Partners:   ALL  Contributing  WPs:   WP2  Estimated  P/M  (if  applicable):   n.a.  Date  of  Completion:   31st  of  December,  2012  Date  of  Delivery  to  EC:   31st  of  December,  2012  Number  of  Pages:    

 

 

ABSTRACT  This  deliverable  provides  a  general  overview  of  the  regional  plans  features  that  are  modelled  and  supported  within   the   ePolicy   framework.   In   particular,   the   following   aspects   have   been   considered:   Objectives,  Financial   Constraints,   Environmental,   Social   and   Economic   Impacts,   and   Implementation   Strategies.   This  document  provides  a  general  overview  of  how  the  ePolicy  approach  treats  and  models  these  aspects.      

Deliverable  D2.2  “Impacts,  constraints,  objectives  and  

implementation  strategies  in  Regional  Planning:  General  Aspects”  

The  project  is  co-­‐‑funded  by  the  European  Community  under  the  Information  and  Communication  Technologies  (ICT)  theme  of  the  Seventh  Framework  Programme  (FP7/2007-­‐‑2013).  Grant  Agreement  n°288147.  

Page 2: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

2  

Authors  of  this  document:  

Attilio  Raimondi1,  Federico  Chesani2,  Tony  Woods3          

1Regione  Emilia-­‐‑Romagna  Email:  [email protected]  

2DISI  –  Università  di  Bologna  Email:  [email protected]

3PPA  Energy  Email:  [email protected]

Reviewers  of  this  document:  

Michela  Milano  University  of  Bologna  

Marco  Gavanelli  University  of  Ferrara  

Tina  Balke  SURREY  

       

   

Copyright  ©  by  the  ePolicy  Consortium  The  ePolicy  Consortium  consists  of  the  following  partners:  University  of  Bologna;  University  College  Cork,  National  University  of  Ireland,  Cork;  University  of   Surrey;   INESC  Porto,   Instituto  de  Engenharia   de   Sistemas   e  Computadores   do  Porto,   Fraunhofer-­‐‑Gesellschaft  zur  Foerderung  der  Angewandten  Forschung  E.V;  Regione  Emila-­‐‑Romagna;  ASTER  –  Società  Consortile  per  Azioni;  Università  degli  Studi  di  Ferrara.  

Possible  inaccuracies  of  information  are  under  the  responsibility  of  the  project  team.  The  text  reflects  solely  the  views  of  its  authors.  The  European  Commission  is  not  liable  for  any  use  that  may  be  made  of  the  information  contained  therein.  

Copyright  ©  by  the  ePolicy  Consortium  The  ePolicy  Consortium  consists  of  the  following  partners:  University  of  Bologna;  University  College  Cork,  National  University  of  Ireland,  Cork;  University  of   Surrey;   INESC  Porto,   Instituto  de  Engenharia   de   Sistemas   e  Computadores   do  Porto,   Fraunhofer-­‐‑Gesellschaft  zur  Foerderung  der  Angewandten  Forschung  E.V;  Regione  Emila-­‐‑Romagna;  ASTER  –  Società  Consortile  per  Azioni;  Università  degli  Studi  di  Ferrara.  

Page 3: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

3  

Contents  

 

1   Introduction  ..............................................................................................................................................  7  

2   Financial  Constraints  ..............................................................................................................................  8  

3   Environmental,  social  and  economic  impacts  ....................................................................................  9  

3.1   Evaluation  of  the  environmental  impacts  ...........................................................................................................................  9  

3.2   Evaluation  of  the  social  impacts  .........................................................................................................................................  10  

3.3   Evaluation  of  economic  impacts  ........................................................................................................................................  11  

4   Objectives  of  a  plan:  dealing  with  multiple  and/or  conflicting  objectives  ...............................  13  

5   Implementation  Strategies  ...................................................................................................................  16  

5.1   Incentives  types  ....................................................................................................................................................................  16  

5.2   Renewable  energy  incentives  in  Italy  ................................................................................................................................  19  

5.2.1   Feed-­‐‑in  tariff  premiums  ..............................................................................................................................................  20  

5.2.2   Feed-­‐‑in  tariff  .................................................................................................................................................................  21  

5.3   Renewable  energy  incentives  in  the  Emilia  Romagna  Region  .......................................................................................  24  

5.3.1   Incentive  mechanisms  in  the  Emilia  Romagna  Region  ..........................................................................................  24  

5.3.2   Grants  ............................................................................................................................................................................  25  

5.3.3   Fiscal  incentives  ............................................................................................................................................................  27  

5.4   Renewable  energy  incentives  in  France  ............................................................................................................................  28  

5.4.1   Political  approach  to  Energy  ......................................................................................................................................  28  

5.4.2   Energy  stakeholders  in  France  ...................................................................................................................................  30  

5.4.3   Energy  markets  ............................................................................................................................................................  31  

5.4.4   Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  (FIT)  .....................................................................................................................................................  33  

5.4.5   Fiscal  incentives  ............................................................................................................................................................  39  

5.4.6   Investment  grants  ........................................................................................................................................................  40  

5.4.7   Tax  exemptions  ............................................................................................................................................................  44  

5.5   UK  Energy  incentives  ..........................................................................................................................................................  46  

5.5.1   Renewable  Obligation  Certificates  (ROC)  ................................................................................................................  47  

5.5.2   Feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  ................................................................................................................................................................  51  

5.5.3   Grants  ............................................................................................................................................................................  52  

5.5.4   Renewable  Heat  Incentive  (RHI)  ...............................................................................................................................  52  

5.5.5   Renewable  Transport  Fuel  Obligation  (RTFO)  ........................................................................................................  54  

5.6   European  Union  (EU)  Renewable  Generation  Incentives  and  Policy  Instruments  ....................................................  55  

5.6.1   Feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  (FITs)  ....................................................................................................................................................  56  

5.6.2   Feed-­‐‑in  Premium  system  ............................................................................................................................................  57  

5.6.3   Renewable  or  quota  obligations  ................................................................................................................................  57  

Page 4: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

4  

5.6.4   Investments  grants  .......................................................................................................................................................  57  

5.6.5   Tax  incentives  or  exemptions  .....................................................................................................................................  57  

5.6.6   Fiscal  incentives  ............................................................................................................................................................  58  

5.6.7   Tender  ............................................................................................................................................................................  58  

6   References  ...............................................................................................................................................  59  

     

Page 5: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

5  

                 

This  page  has  been  intentionally  left  blank.    

Page 6: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’
Page 7: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

7  

1 Introduction  This   deliverable   provides   a   summarized   description   of   the   general   aspects   that   characterize   the  regional   plans.  Within   the   ePolicy   approach,   a   plan   consists   of   a   set   of   activities   that   should   be  carried  out  to  achieve  some  objectives.  Together  with  the  activities  name,  also  their  magnitude  and  expected   (estimated)   costs  are  provided.  To   the  end  of  aiding   the  policy  maker   to  devise   such  a  plan,  the  policy  model  does  indeed  takes  into  account  the  following  aspects:  

• Objectives.   Regional   plans   usually   tackle   different   aspects   related   to   the   regional  functioning,   infrastructures,   social,   environment,  and  any  other  possible  aspect   for  which  the  public  body  is  entailed  to  provide  directions  and  rules.  To  name  a  few,  typical  regional  plans   can   be   Agriculture,   Forest,   Fishing,   Energy,   Industry,   Transport,   Waste,   Water,  Telecommunication,  Tourism,  Urban  and  Environmental.    For   each   plan,   a   number   of  possible,   different   objectives   are   settled.   When   constructing   the   plan,   the   policy   maker  should  try  to  take  into  account  multiple  objectives  at  the  same  time:  however,  dealing  with  them  is  a  difficult  task,  since  the  objectives  can  be  conflicting  with  each  other.  

• Financial   Constraints.   The   implementation   of   a   plan   is   limited   by   a   set   of   financial  constraints,  typically  provided  in  terms  of  a  budget  available  for  the  plan  implementation,  and  estimated  private  costs.  

• Environmental,  social  and  economic  impacts.  The  implementation  of  a  plan  always  affects  the  environment,  as  well  as  the  society.  Quite  often,  such  impacts  can  be  positive,  negative,  or  both  (by  affecting  different  environmental  aspects).  

• Implementation   strategies.   The   implementation   strategies   are   the   mechanisms   used   to  carry   out   the   activities   devised   within   a   plan.   The   definition   of   the   implementation  strategies   is   a   core   activity   of   the   planning   process,   since   they   have   a   direct   impact   and  feedback  on  the  achievement  of  the  plan  objectives.  

Objectives  and  financial  constraints  are  an  input  of  the  policy  modeling  process,  while  the  various  impacts  are  consequences  of  the  chosen  plan  and  implementation  strategies.  Of  course,  among  the  objectives,   the   policy   maker   can   specify   to   minimize/maximize   the   impact   of   the   plan   towards  some  environmental  receptor,  or  social/economic  indicator.  

Implementation  strategies  are  about  how  to  carry  out  the  activities  that  have  been  identified  within  the  plan.  They  play  a  fundamental  role,  since  they  directly  impact  on  the  allocated  budget,  as  well  as   on   the   private   costs;   they   have   direct   consequences   towards   social,   economical   and  environmental   aspects;   and,   most   important,   implementation   strategies   directly   affect   the  achievement  of  the  objectives.  

This  deliverable  provides  a  general  overview  of  the  regional  plans  features  that  are  modeled  and  supported  within  the  ePolicy  framework.  While  some  aspects  such  as  the  objectives,  the  financial  constraints  and  the  impacts  have  been  already  discussed  in  previous  deliverable  (see  for  example  D2.1   and   D8.1),   implementation   strategies   are   presented   here   for   the   first   time.   Hence,   the  deliverable   is   organized   as   follow:   In   Section   2   the   objectives   of   a   plan,   and   the   techniques  

Page 8: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

8  

exploited  by  ePolicy  are  briefly  recalled  and  summarized.  In  Section  3  some  considerations  about  the  financial  constraints,  public  and  private  costs  are  discussed.  In  Section  4  ePolicy  techniques  and  algorithms   to   evaluate   environmental,   social   and   economic   impacts   are   presented   and  summarized.  Finally,  Section  5  is  devoted  to  provide  an  overview  of  the  implementation  strategies,  w.r.t.  the  renewable  energy  domain.  

 

 

2 Financial  Constraints  The  implementation  of  a  plan  comprises  two  different  types  of  costs:  

a) public  costs,  i.e.  the  costs  that  are  directly  supported  by  the  public  bodies;  b) private   costs,   i.e.   the   costs   that   are   supported   by   private   stakeholders  when   involved   in  

some  of  the  plan-­‐‑related  activities.  

Public   bodies   costs   are  usually   covered  by   the  budget   allocated   for  plan   implementation.   In   the  Emilia-­‐‑Romagna   region   the   budget   is   allocated   through   the   Regional   Operational   Programme  (POR)  [4]  (see  also  [5]  and  [6]  for  examples  related  to  other  italian  regions).  The  POR  programme  comes   under   the   Regional   Competitiveness   and   Employment   EU   objective,   and   it   has   a   total  budget   of   some   347   eM.   The   assistance   provided   by   the   European  Union   through   the   Regional  Development   Fund   (ERDF)   amounts   to   nearly   128   eM,   which   represents   around   0.4%   of   EC  contributions  to  Italy  under  the  cohesion  policy  for  the  current  period  2007-­‐‑2013.  

The  strategy  of   the  Operational  Programme  is  based  mainly  on:   (i)   the  regional   issues,   identified  after  an  analysis  of  the  region’s  potential;  and  (ii)  the  EC  and  national  strategic  frameworks,  which  set  out  the  principles  for  the  allocation  of  EC  funding.  The  operational  programme  is  divided  into  five  priorities:  

1. Industrial  research  and  technology  transfer  2. Entrepreneurial  development  and  innovation  3. Improved  energy  and  environmental  efficiency,  and  sustainable  development  4. Enhancing  and  better  exploiting  the  environmental  and  cultural  heritage  5. Technical  assistance  

Financial   constraints   coming   from   the   allocated  budget   are  directly  modelled  within   the   ePolicy  approach   by  means   of   constraints   on   the   foreseen   costs,   computed   on   the   base   of   the   activities  identified  as  being  part  of  the  plan,  together  with  the  costs  of  the  implementation  strategies.  

Private  costs  can  have  a  dramatic  impact  on  the  achievement  of  plan  objectives:  high  private  costs  might   discourage   stakeholders   to   get   involved   into   the   plan   activities,   while   low   private   costs  might  push  to  some  excess  the  stakeholders  involvement.  ePolicy  takes  into  account  the  effects  of  these  costs  by  proper  considering  them  within  the  social  simulation  component.  

Page 9: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

9  

 

3 Environmental,  social  and  economic  impacts  Each   plan   has   environmental,   social   and   economic   impacts.   To   achieve   the   objectives,   a   plan  foresees   the   execution   of   a   number   of   different   activities.  Within   the   expert   of   Emilia-­‐‑Romagna  Region,  we  have  identified  two  different  types  of  activities:  

• Primary  activities  are  those  ones  that  are  directly  related  to  the  achievement  of  one  or  more  plan  objectives.   I.e.,   primary   activities   are   those   that  produce   a  measurable   outcome   that  directly  affects  the  objectives  of  a  plan.  E.g.,  w.r.t.  the  energy  plan  a  primary  activity  is  the  building  of  a  new  power  plant;  w.r.t.  the  transport  plan  a  primary  activity  is  the  building  of  a  new  road.  

• Secondary  activities  are  those  that  do  not  affect  directly  the  objectives,  but  are  mandatory  for   the   implementation   of   primary   activities.   I.e.,   secondary   activities   are   those   that   are  needed  to  support  primary  activities,  but  do  not  produce  a  measurable  outcome  that  affects  the  objectives  of  the  regional  plan.  E.g.,  w.r.t.  the  energy  plan,  secondary  activities  strictly  related  to  the  construction  of  a  new  power  plant  (the  primary  activity)  are  the  building  of  roads  to  reach  the  plant,  and  the  construction  of  aerial  power  lines  and  supports.  

There   is   a   direct   relation   between   primary   and   secondary   activities.   The   ePolicy   model   fully  supports  such  correlation  by  allowing  the  definition  of  such  relation.  In  particular,  domain  experts  can  provide  estimations  of  “how  much”  of  each  secondary  activity  is  indeed  required  to  support  a  “quantity”  of  a  certain  primary  activity.  More  precisely,  the  domain  experts  can  provide  a  function  for   each   couple   of   primary/secondary   activity:   such   function   takes   in   input   the   quantity   of   the  desired  primary  activity,  and  returns  an  estimation  of  the  needed  quantity  of  a  certain  secondary  activity.  

Summing   up,   ePolicy   takes   as   input   a   Na   x   Na   square  matrix   D   (Na   being   the   total   number   of  considered   activities),   where   each   element   dij   is   a   function   that   relates   activity   j   with   activity   i.  Notice  that  the  function  can  be  a  linear  relation,  as  well  as  a  non-­‐‑linear  one.  

 

3.1 Evaluation  of  the  environmental  impacts  Different   solutions   and   tools   have   been  used   to   perform   the   environmental   assessment.  Among  many,   we   consider   here   a   state-­‐‑of-­‐‑the-­‐‑art   methodology   adopted   within   the   region   Emilia-­‐‑Romagna.  This  methodology  is  based  on  coaxial  matrices  [1],  and  it  has  been  developed  from  the  “network   method”   [2].   In   this   methodology,   each   activity   affects   the   environment   in   terms   of  positive   and  negative  pressures:   an   example  of  positive  pressure   is   the   increased  availability  of  energy,  while  a  negative  pressure  is  the  production  of  pollutants.  Pressures  are  themselves  linked  to  environmental   receptors   such  as   the  quality  of   the  air,  or   the  quality  of   the  surface  water.  On  both  pressures  and  receptors,  there  are  constraints:  e.g.,  a  constraint  limits  the  maximum  amount  of  greenhouse  gas  emissions  of  the  overall  plan.  

Page 10: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

10  

A  matrix  M  defines  the  dependencies  between  the  above  mentioned  activities  contained  in  a  plan  and  positive  and  negative  pressures  on  the  environment.  Each  element  mij  of  the  matrix  M  defines  a   qualitative   dependency   between   the   activity   i   and   the   negative   or   positive   impact   j.   The  dependency  can  be  high,  medium,  low  or  null.  

A   second  matrix  N   defines   how   the   impacts/pressures   influence   environmental   receptors.   Each  element   nij   of   the   matrix  N   defines   a   qualitative   dependency   between   the   negative   or   positive  impact  i  and  an  environmental  receptor  j.  Again  the  dependency  can  be  high,  medium,  low  or  null.  

The  impacts  of  a  plan  towards  environmental  receptors  is  computed  starting  from  matrices  M  and  N.  An  example  of  such  computed  impacts,  for  a  specific  plan  is  shown  in  Figure  1.  Note  that  the  activity   “Aerial   Power   Line   Supports!   Has   a   negative   impact   on   receptor   #2   (“Embankments  Stability”),  while  it  has  a  positive  impact  on  receptor  #22  (“Availability  of  productive  resources”).  

 

 

Figure  1  –  How  a  specific  plan  impacts  a  set  of  receptors.  Rows  are  labelled  with  the  whole  set  of  activities  (primary  and  secondary),  while  columns  are  labelled  with  environmental  receptors  (numbered  from  1  up  to  23).  

 

3.2 Evaluation  of  the  social  impacts  Knowing  what  people  think  about  some  process  is  of  key  importance  to  decision-­‐‑making.  People  frequently   express   their   opinions   through   text.   It   is   often   the   case   that   policy  makers   propose   a  participation  process  before   starting  a  planning  activity  by  collecting  opinions   through  meetings  and  workshops  of  all  relevant  stakeholders.  Therefore,  the  first  part  of  the  plan  contains  the  result  of   the   opinions   collected   during   this   participatory   phase.   ePolicy   wants   to   deal   with   opinion  collection  in  an  automatic  way.  

Opinion  mining   and   sentiment   analysis   is   an   area   of   text  mining   that   aims   at   uncovering   these  opinions   from   textual   sources.   This   area   aims   at   developing   computational   tools   that   enable   to  uncover  opinion,  sentiment  and  subjectivity  in  text.  

Page 11: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

11  

ePolicy   considers   social   impacts   in   terms   of   social   acceptance,   by   mining   the   free   web   and  extracting  the  sentiment.  We  have  decided  to  have  for  each  relevant  message  a  five  ranked  scale:  from  -­‐‑2  which  means  a  very  negative  opinion  to  +2  meaning  a  very  positive  opinion.    

Unfortunately,  there  is  not  much  generality  in  this  process.  First  because  the  collection  of  relevant  web  sites  depends  on  the  type  of  plan.  Second,  because  the  model  we  learn  with  opinion  mining  is  topic  dependent.    

 

3.3 Evaluation  of  economic  impacts  In   the   ePolicy   framework   economic   impacts   are   evaluated   through   the   techniques   and  methods  developed   within   the   project   RAMEA   [3],   one   of   the   16   cooperation   projects   financed   by   the  INTERREG   IIIC   Program   2005-­‐‑2007   under   GROW,   the   Regional   Framework   Operation   (RFO)  which  main  topic  is  to  help  European  regions  in  adopting  strategies  coherent  with  the  Lisbon  and  Gothenburg  Agendas  goals.  RAMEA  project  started   in  May  2006,  with   the   involvement  of  seven  institutes  from  four  EU  regions.  

RAMEA   is   an   environmental   accounting   system   useful   to   evaluate   the   economic   and  environmental  performance  of  regions  and  to  inform  regional  policies/strategies  about  sustainable  development,  coherently  with  the  tools  developed  at  national  level  (NAMEA).  The  main  objectives  of  these  synergic  studies  have  been  aimed  at  defining  helpful  accounting  tools  to:  

• link  the  economic  knowledge  on  production  and  consumption  activities  to  the  emissions  in  air  exerted  on  the  environment;    

• build  a  tool  useful  for  reports,  studies,  scenarios,  regional  planning;    • provide   useful   indicators   for   the   policy   makers   to   measure,   control   and   forecast   key  

regional  performances;  • identify   how   a   region   could   develop   economically   and   socially   without   causing  

environmental  damages.  Moreover,   RAMEA   could   be   used   for   different   kinds   of   analyses,   to   explore   some   of   the  possibilities  that  this  type  of  tool  offer  to  the  regional  planning/reporting,  e.g.:  monitoring  regional  air   emissions   and   eco-­‐‑efficiency,   comparing   regional   eco-­‐‑efficiency  with   the   national   one   (Shift-­‐‑Share  analysis)  and  understanding  the  effects  and  responsibilities  of  production  and  consumption  chains  on  the  environment.  

 

Page 12: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

12  

 

Figure  2  –  General  tables  provided  by  the  RAMEA  project  

For   this   purpose,   we   report   here   a   table   linking   industrial   sectors   taken   from   the   NACE  classification  plus  households  with  economic  and  environmental  parameters:  In  detail  we  have:  

• 27   industries   (NACE   rev.   1.1   classification)   and   2   household   categories   (COICOP   07  Transports  plus  Other  consumptions);    

• 5   economic   variables   (Output,   Value   Added,   Intermediate   Consumption,   Final  Consumption  and  Employment);    

• 9  air  emissions  (CO2,  N2O,  CH4,  NOX,  SOX,  NH3,  NMVOC,  CO,  PM)  plus  2  aggregated  impact  categories  (Global  Warming  Potential  and  Acidification).    

 

As   an   example   of   RAMEA   table   applied   to   the   specific   case   of   the   Emilia   Romagna   region,  we  report  in  Figure  3.  

6

Malopolska Region, Poland) SEEDA (South East England Development Agency, UK), SEERA (South East England Regional Assembly, UK), SCPnet (Sustainable Consumption and Production Network, UK) Cambridge Econometrics (UK) and TELOS (Noord Brabant Centre for Sustainable Development, the Netherlands).

The project partners shared a common path to develop four Regional NAMEA matrices

(RAMEA), environmental accounting systems useful to evaluate the economic and environmental performance of regions involved and to inform regional policies/strategies about sustainable development. Indeed, linking environmental and economic indicators encourages and facilitates the involvement of the decision makers, who are likely to be more familiar with socio-economic concepts (such as GDP), but who are having to pay an increasing amount of attention to the effects of economic activities on the environment.

RAMEA is based on an international accepted methodology (UN, Eurostat), reliable data

(official statistical accounts) and standardized systems (SEEA2003, SNA1993, ESA19951): these conditions assure its coherency with similar tools at national level (NAMEA) and allow benchmarking between regions/nations. A RAMEA could be compiled in a relatively inexpensive way, deriving its numbers from national and regional accounts.

The Figure 3 shows the framework chosen by project partners. The main characteristics of

this common framework are: x 27 industries (NACE rev. 1.1 classification) and 2 household categories (COICOP 07

Transports plus Other consumptions); x 5 economic variables (Output, Value Added, Intermediate Consumption, Final

Consumption and Employment); x 9 air emissions (CO2, N2O, CH4, NOX, SOX, NH3, NMVOC, CO, PM) plus 2

aggregated impact categories (Global Warming Potential and Acidification).

ftes/n. jobs

Output Value Added

Intermed. Consumpt.

Final Consumpt. Output Value

AddedIntermed.

Consumpt.Final

Consumpt. Employment

NACE rev. 1.1 industry

classification (27 codes)

HouseholdTotal

RAMCurrent Prices (Millions of euros) Costant Prices (Millions of euros)

CO2 N2O CH4 CO2 eq NOX SOx NH3 H+ eq NMVOC CO PMNACE rev. 1.1

industry classification (27

codes)Household

Total

GHG emissions (Mg) Acidification (Mg) Local air quality (Mg)

EA

Figure 3 - RAMEA: common framework

Because application to policies is a fundamental requisite for environmental accounting

tools that aspire to more than just mere compilation of data, RAMEA has been thought as a Decision Support System for Regional Sustainable Development. In particular:

1 ESA - European System of Accounts

Page 13: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

13  

 

Figure  3  -­‐‑  Ramea  table  instantiated  to  the  Emilia  Romagna  Region.  

The  RAMEA  project  however  could  not  only  be  considered  as  a  data  collection  project  aimed  at  filling  in  the  tables  above.  It  also  aims  at  providing:  

• a  monitoring  system,  RAMEA  allows  analyzing   the  pressures  placed  on   the  environment  by   the   economic   sectors   and   households,   helps   identifying   the   “hot   spots”   in   terms   of  environmental  pressures  and  potential  decoupling  patterns,  and  allows  the  construction  of  eco-­‐‑efficiency  indexes:  we  can  understand,  as  an  example,  the  regional  key  sectors  for  CO2  emissions,   establish   a   direct   link   with   their   economic   performances,   see   if   a  positive/negative   relation   exists   between   economic   growth   and   environmental   pollution  and  develop  eco-­‐‑efficiency  indexes;    

• as   a   forecasting   tool,   RAMEA,   together   with   the   help   of   environmental   input-­‐‑output  analysis,   allows  Scenario   analysis:   e.g.   after  having   identified   the  key   sectors   for  CO2  we  may  evaluate  and  quantify  the  effects  of  different  regional  policies/strategies  aiming  to  the  reduction  of  emissions,  including  the  baseline  scenario  (no  action).  

• as  a  benchmarking  tool  RAMEA  gives  the  possibility  of  comparisons  between  regions:  the  partners  compared  the  performances  of  the  four  regions  (and  of  the  four  nations  of  which  regions   are   part)   in   term   of   eco-­‐‑efficiency   of   eight  macro   economic   sectors   (Agriculture,  Mining/Quarrying,   Manufacturing   activities,   Electricity,   Construction,   Commerce,  Transport,  Other  services).  

4 Objectives  of  a  plan:  dealing  with  multiple  and/or  conflicting  objectives  

The  definition  of  the  objectives  of  a  plan  is  a  process  that  takes  into  account  many  different  sources  of  information.  Primarily,  the  EC  and  the  national  operational  programs,  which  identify  objectives  

8

economic structure of the region. Moreover, only emission whose source is anthropic is taken into account, excluding all emissions related to natural phenomena. The application of this approach to Emilia-Romagna could benefit from previous pilots of regional NAMEA for two Italian regions, Toscana and Lazio (Bertini et al. 2007, ISTAT 2006a-b), together with the compilation of national NAMEA for Italy (De Lauretis et al. 2002, Tudini and Vetrella 2003, Tudini and Vetrella 2004).

In addition to the common framework agreed, RAMEA for Emilia-Romagna includes an

Input-Output matrix which form the basis of the NAM part (and gives the possibility to highlight sustainable consumption and production patterns) and data on nine heavy metals emissions (As, Hg, Pb, Zn, Cd, Cr, Se, Cu and Ni). Table 2 shows a simplified scheme of RAMEA, in which four economic aggregates and five environmental themes are presented.

Table 2 - RAMEA for Emilia-Romagna - aggregated version (2000, %)

RAM EA Emilia-Romagna 2000

Economic aggregates GHG Acidification Local air quality (Mg)

NACE Industries Output Value Added

Final Cons.

Labour input CO2 eq H+ eq NMVOC CO PM

A,B Agriculture, hunting, forestry, fishing 2,6% 3,5% 6,2% 12,2% 47,0% 4,6% 9,8% 24,2%

C Mining/quarrying 0,1% 0,2% 0,1% 0,1% 0,1% 0,2% 0,0% 0,2%

D Manufacturing activities 39,6% 26,6% 27,4% 31,5% 21,2% 30,7% 2,4% 31,3%

E Electricity, gas, water supply 1,5% 1,3% 0,5% 14,3% 10,2% 3,2% 0,5% 4,6%

F Construction 5,4% 4,9% 5,8% 0,2% 0,1% 3,9% 0,1% 2,2%

G,H Wholesale, retail trade, hotels, restaurants

14,4% 17,2% 21,4% 2,0% 0,7% 1,7% 0,5% 0,9%

I Transport, storage, communication 6,2% 6,8% 5,8% 7,0% 7,5% 6,9% 5,6% 13,2%

J-Q Other services 30,1% 39,5% 32,8% 6,2% 1,9% 1,3% 2,1% 2,1%

COICOP Households

07 Transport 12,7% 12,3% 9,1% 34,1% 70,3% 13,3%

- Other consumptions 87,3% 14,2% 2,1% 13,3% 8,7% 8,0%

Total - Industries 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 73,5% 88,8% 52,6% 21,0% 78,7%

Total - Households 100,0% 26,5% 11,2% 47,4% 79,0% 21,3%

Total 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0%

The above version of RAMEA highlights the different contribution of economic sectors

and households to the economy and the environment as a percentage of total, facilitating a simple but interesting analysis of the data:

x Manufacturing (D) is the sector with the higher contribution to the regional output (39.6%) and the second for the employment (27.4%), but has also a high impact on the environment (GHG 31.5%, acidification 21.2% and PM 31.3%);

x Electricity sector (E) makes a very little contribution to the regional output and value added (1.5% and 1.3% respectively) and employment (0.5%) but makes a significant environmental impact in terms of GHG (14.3%) and acidification (10.2%);

x Agriculture and fishing (A+B) sector makes little contribution to the regional output (2.6%) and value added (3.5%), but is relatively important in term of GHG (12.2%) and PM (24.2%) and is the highest for acidification (47%);

x Households have an impact on environment that can not be overlooked, particularly for emissions such as CO2 (31%) PM (21%), NMVOC (47%) and CO (79%)

Page 14: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

14  

and  intervention  fields  at  a  very  general   level.  Secondly,   the  specific  needs  of   the  region:  generic  goals   are   tailored   into   more   detailed   objectives   that   fit   the   local   situation.   Within   this   phase,  political   choices   play   an   important   role   in   determining   the   objectives,   as   well   as   citizen   and  stakeholder   public   opinions.   Thirdly,   previous   plans   and   the   achieved   results   influence   the  determination  of  the  objectives  for  the  new  plan.  

As  a  consequence,  each  plan  is  equipped  with  a  number  of  different  objectives.  The  policy  maker  has  to  take  into  account  all  the  objectives,  thus  requiring  the  merge  of  multiple  objective  functions.  Moreover,   the   objectives   can   conflict   each   other.   This   in   turn   calls   for   multiple   optimization  criteria.  

When   a   problem  presents   a   single   criteria   to   select   among  different   solutions,  we   have   a   single  optimal   value   (that   may   correspond   to   many   equivalent   solutions).   On   the   other   hand,   when  several   objectives   are   considered  we  have  many  Pareto  optimal   solutions,   i.e.,   solutions   that   are  non   dominated   by   other   solution.   A   solution   x   is   non   dominated   with   respect   to   a   number   of  objective  functions  (f1,  f2,  …fn)  by  other  solutions  if  there  does  not  exist  any  solution  that  improves  on  x  on  at  least  one  objective  function  and  is  the  same  on  the  other.  

In  general  regional  plants  have  a  number  of  objectives  to  respect.  One  could  be  the  cost  of  the  plan.  With   cost,   we   consider   both   public   and   private  money.   Public  money   is   invested   both   into   the  realization  of  the  plan  and  into  implementation  strategies  described  later.  

Other  interesting  objectives  are  environmental  receptors.  A  receptor  is  an  indicator  of  the  quality  of   a   given   environmental   aspect.   We   have   previously   described   the   Strategic   Environmental  assessment  providing  us  with  22  receptors:  

• Subsidence  limitation    • Embankments  stability  •  Stability  of  coasts  or  seafloor    • Stability  of  river  banks  and  beds    • Soil  quality  • Quality  of  sea  water  • Quality  of  inland  surface  waters    • Groundwater  quality    • Air  quality  • Quality  of  climate    • Wellness  of  terrestrial  vegetation    • Wellness  of  wildlife    • Wellness  of  aquatic  plants    • Wellness  and  health  of  mankind    • Quality  of  sensitive  landscapes    • Cultural/historical  heritage  value    • Recreation  resources  accessibility    • Water  availability    • Availability  of  agricultural  fertile  land    • Lithoid  resource  availability    

Page 15: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

15  

• Energy  availability  •  Availability  of  productive  resources    • Value  of  material  goods  

 

Clearly,   depending   on   the   region,   the   regional   plan   might   take   into   account   a   different  combination  of  receptor  to  optimize.  For  example  in  Emilia  Romagna,  the  air  quality  in  general  is  very   poor   being   the   region   a   flat   area   called   Pianura   Padana   with   Alps   on   the   North   and  Appennins   on   the   South   and   therefore   having   limited  ways   of   dissipating   pollutant   emissions.  Therefore   for   the   Emilia   Romagna   one   receptor   that   is   usually   considered   is   the   Air   quality.  However,  in  the  same  region  we  have  the  Po  river  delta.  In  that  area  the  water  quality  is  extremely  important.    

So,   we   might   have   a   plan   minimizing   the   cost   and   maximizing   the   air   quality.   Having   two  objective   functions,   we   could   visualize   on   a   Cartesian   diagram   alternative   plans   that   are   non  dominated.  In  Figure  4  we  show  the  Pareto  optimal  curve  containing  non  dominated  plans.    

 

 

Figure  4:  Pareto  Optimal  frontier  for  energy  plans  and  two  objective  functions  

 

   

Page 16: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

16  

5 Implementation  Strategies  Many  different  implementation  strategies  are  available  in  the  literature.  Reviewing  all  the  possible  strategies  for  any  possible  plan  is  out  of  the  scope  of  this  deliverable.  However,  to  better  assess  the  possible  strategies   that  have  been  used  within   the  energy-­‐‑related  field,  an  extensive  study  of   the  incentive  mechanism  has  been  conducted  by  considering  several  different  countries.  In  particular,  incentives  methods  utilised  to  promote  renewable  energy  have  been  taken  into  account,  w.r.t.  UK,  Italy   (with   particular   reference   to   the   Emilia   Romagna   region),   France,   more   generally   in   the  European  Union,  South  Africa  and  in  the  US   (with  a  more  detailed  examination  of   the  states  of  California  and  Florida).  

The   complete   list   of   incentive  mechanisms   is   available   as   the   project   internal   report   “Report   on  Incentive   Mechanisms   for   Renewable   Energy   Generation   and   related   topics”,   available   to   all  partners.  Here  we  report  only  the  results  that  can  be  directly  referred  to  EU  coutries.  

 

5.1 Incentives  types  The  forms  of  incentive  mechanisms  that  have  been  identified  are  as  follows    

• Feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   -­‐‑   A   feed-­‐‑in   tariff   is   a   fixed   and   guaranteed   price   paid   to   the   eligible  producers  of  electricity  from  renewable  sources,  for  the  power  they  feed  into  the  grid.  

• Premium  -­‐‑  In  a  feed-­‐‑in  premium  system,  a  guaranteed  premium  is  paid  in  addition  to  the  income  producers   receive   for   the  electricity   from  renewable   sources   that   is  being  sold  on  the  electricity  market.  

• Quota   obligation   -­‐‑   Quota   obligations   create   a   market   for   the   renewable   property   of  electricity.   The   government   creates   a   demand   through   imposing   an   obligation   on  consumers   or   suppliers   to   source   a   certain  percentage  of   their   electricity   from   renewable  sources.  

• Investment  Grant  -­‐‑  grants  for  renewable  generation  are  often  devised  to  stimulate  the  take-­‐‑up  of  less  mature  technologies  such  as  photo-­‐‑voltaic.  

• Tax  exemptions  -­‐‑  Some  countries  provide  tax  incentives  related  to  investments  (including  income   tax   deductions   or   credits   for   some   fraction   of   the   capital   investment   made   in  renewable  energy  projects,  or  accelerated  depreciation).    Other  approaches  are  production  tax   incentives   that   provide   income   tax   deduction   or   credits   at   a   set   rate   per   unit   of  produced  renewable  electricity,  thereby  reducing  operational  costs.  

• Fiscal  Incentives  –  This  category  includes  soft  –  or  low-­‐‑interest  -­‐‑  loans  that  are  loans  with  a  rate   below   the  market   rate   of   interest.   Soft   loans  may   also   provide   other   concessions   to  borrowers,  including  longer  repayment  periods  or  interest  holidays.  

• Compulsion  –  A  more  radical  approach  would  involve  an  element  of  compulsion.    Whilst  no  examples  of  this  have  been  directly  identified  in  the  renewable  generation  market,  some  similar  circumstances  have  been  established.    For  example  in  at   least  some  urban  parts  of  Scandinavia  it  is  a  legal  obligation  for  new  constructed  homes  to  be  connected  to  the  local  heat  network.  

Page 17: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

17  

• Green  Power  marketing  –  Under  this  arrangement,  electricity  customers  can  choose  to  buy  electricity  which  is  sourced  partially  or  wholly  from  renewable  sources.    Typically  they  pay  a   premium   compared   to   other   tariffs   that   may   be   available.   This   can   be   used   in   both  competitive   and   regulated  markets.     Sometimes   standards   need   to   be   set   to   ensure   that  sufficient  and  appropriate  renewable  generation  is  supporting  the  product.  

It   should   also   be   noted   that   the   various   categories   listed   above   are   not   necessarily   mutually  exclusive  so   that,   in  some   jurisdictions,  more   than  one  policy   instrument  or  approach  may  be   in  use  at  the  same  time.  

These  various  incentive  schemes  can  also  generally  be  characterised  as  either    

• Production-­‐‑based   incentives   –  where   the   benefit   of   the   scheme   is   broadly   related   to   the  amount   of   energy   generated.     This   includes   feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   and   quota   obligations.   The  features  of  such  arrangements  may  include  the  following:  

o Technological   differentiation   –   as   different   renewable   technologies   are   at   varying  levels  of  development  and  cost  levels  in  relation  to  existing  market  prices  there  is  a  risk  of  “free  riding”  (i.e.  a  potential  ongoing  windfall  benefit)  for  technologies  that  are   close   to  being  economic   in   the   absence  of   subsidy   if   only  one   support   level   is  provided   to   all   technologies.     Thus   increasingly   technological   differentiation   has  been  introduced  into  the  support  mechanisms  used.  

o Inflation  adjustment  –  the  level  of  support  (i.e.  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  price)    may  vary  in  line  with  inflation.  

o Digression  –   the   level  and  availability  of  support  may  be  varied  according   to   take-­‐‑up.    Thus   if   such   take-­‐‑up   is   large   then   the   support  may  be   curtailed.    Whilst   this  sometimes   happens   by   unexpected   Government   decisions,   arrangements   are  increasingly  being  established  during  the  design  of  the  incentive  mechanism.  

o Own-­‐‑use  arrangements  –   for  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs   there  may  be  differences   in  the  rate  paid  for   electricity   used   on   the   premises  where   the   electricity   is   generated   rather   than  that   feed   into   the   distribution   network.     This   also   raises   questions   in   regard   to  metering  or  the  assumptions  made  about  the  proportion  of  the  electricity  generated  used  for  each  purpose.  

• Investment-­‐‑based   incentives   –   these   schemes   tend   to   provide   support   for   the   initial  investment  irrespective  of  the  amount  of  electricity  that  is  actually  generated.    Examples  of  such  arrangements  include:  

o loans  (either  interest  free  or  at  rates  below  the  market  level)    o loan  guarantees  (where  the  repayment  of  the  loan  may  be  guaranteed  by  an  external  

agency,  such  as  national  or  regional  government)  which  has  the  effect  of  facilitating  both  the  availability  of  loan  finance  and  reducing  its  cost  

o tax  benefits  –  such  as  VAT  exemption  or  reduction  or  reduced  corporate  taxation  via  accelerated   depreciation   or   improved   capital   allowances,   although   this   will   only  provide  advantages  to  profit  making  companies  

Page 18: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

18  

Although  not  an  incentive  mechanism  as  such,  it  is  also  vital  that  a  robust  and  reliable  legal  framework  is  in  place  to  reassure  investors  and  users.    The  elements  of  such  a  framework  include:-­‐‑  

• A  simple  and  predictable  planning  process.  • What  priority  do  local  authorities  give  to  renewable  energy?    Will  such  authorities  support  

or  oppose  installations?    This  will  have  a  significant  impact  on  the  chances  of  gaining  approval  and  the  related  time  and  costs.  

• Building  Regulation  including  the  approval  processes  and  the  extent  to  which  the  use  of  renewable  energy  may  be  mandated  (although  in  reality  this  may  be  a  matter  of  negotiation  between  a  developer  and  the  relevant  authority).  

It   is   also   important   that   there   is   clarity   about   the   role   of   transmission   and   distribution   utility  companies  and  organisations.    These  need  to  be  suitably  incentivised  to  support  the  connection  of  renewable  generation  and  encouraged  to  contribute  to  the  demolition  of  any  barriers  that  may  be  inhibiting  it  both  within  their  own  organisations  and  elsewhere.  

Whilst   each   of   the   mechanisms   outlined   above   have   their   advantages   and   disadvantages   it   is  interesting   to   consider   which   are   the   most   effective   and   efficient   at   promoting   renewable  generation.  There  is  some  evidence  that  a  greater  effect  at  lower  cost  may  be  achieved  by  a  stable  feed-­‐‑in   tariff   regime  that   is  sustained  over  a  significant  period.  For  example,   in  2009  on  average,  countries  with  fixed  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  had  tended  to  either  be  growing  at  a  faster  rate  and/or  have  a  much  larger  renewable  energy  base  than  countries  using  other  approaches.  In  addition  fixed  tariffs  also   appear   to   be   more   efficient.   As   an   example   prices   paid   for   wind   energy   in   UK   and   Italy  (without   fixed   tariffs   at   that   time)   were   higher   than   the   fixed   tariffs.   For   instance,   the   UK  was  paying  about  a  third  more  for  its  wind  energy  than  Germany.  There  are  many  potential  reasons  for  this   difference   but   an   element   of   it  may   be  due   to   the  price  uncertainty   surrounding   renewable  certificates.  However   it   is   not   clear   that   this   trend  will   persist   over   time  or  may  be  different   for  different  technologies  or  scale  of  investment.  

 

   

Page 19: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

19  

5.2 Renewable  energy  incentives  in  Italy  Italy   in   general   and   Emilia-­‐‑Romagna   region   in   particular   has   been   selected   to   carry   out   a   case  study   for   the   ePolicy   project.     The   Italy’s   electricity   sector,   historically   dominated   by   Enel,  was  unbundled   in   2005.     Despite   government   measures   to   reduce   the   dominance   of   Enel   in   the  generation  market,   it  remains  Italy'ʹs   largest  power  generator  (with  21%  of  the  company  in  direct  government   ownership   and   10%   indirectly).   The   retail   electricity   market   in   Italy   was   fully  liberalised  in  2007.    Electricity  prices  remain  among  the  highest  in  the  EU.    Prices  are  formulated  on   the   basis   of  wholesale   prices,   bilateral   contracts,   transmission   and   distribution   tariffs   (where  relevant)  and  taxation.  

In   2011   about   24%   of   total   energy   production  was   from   renewable   sources.     The   total   installed  renewable  capacity  was  812  MW  and  84  GWh  was  produced  from  renewable  energy  sources  (see  Figure  39).  

 

Figure  5:  Renewable  sources  in  Italy  (2011)  

   

The   Italian   National   Renewable   Energy   Action   Plan   has   a   target   to   reach   the   total   share   of  renewable  energy  of  26%  -­‐‑  39%  in  the  electricity  sector,  17%  in  the  heating/cooling  sector  and  14%  in  the  transport  sector  by  2020.  

Italy  has  a  well-­‐‑developed  system  of  incentives  for  renewable  energy  generated  from  solar,  wind  and  biomass.   In  particular,   the  Renewable  Energy  Decree,  which  entered   into   force  on  29  March  2011,   revises   the   system   of   incentives   for   the   production   of   electricity   from   renewable   sources  (described  under  ‘Operating  Subsidies’)  and  simplifies  the  authorization  process  for  building  new  plants.  

 

Capacity  (MW) Energy  (GWh)2010 2011 2010 2011

hydro 17.8 17.9 51.1 46.3Wind 5.8 6.8 9.1 10.1Solar 3.4 12.7 1.9 10.7Geothermal 772 772 5.3 5.6Bioenergy 2.35 3 9.4 11.3Total 801.35 812.4 76.8 84

Gross  domestic  consumption  GWh 342 344Percentage  Renewable/Gross  domestic  consumption 22% 24%

Page 20: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

20  

5.2.1 Feed-­‐‑in  tariff  premiums  

5.2.1.1 Feed-­‐‑In  premium  for  photovoltaic  systems  The   Ministerial   Decree   of   19   February   2007   introduced   in   Italy   a   new   version   of   the   feed-­‐‑in  premium   scheme   applied   to   photovoltaic   plants   connected   to   the   grid  with   a   nominal   capacity  higher   than   1   kWp   installed   by   individuals,   registered   companies,   condominiums   and   public  bodies.  The   current  EU  driver   for   this  policy   is   the  EU  Directive  on   the  promotion  of   the  use  of  energy   from   renewable   sources   (2009/28/EC).     The   decree   provided   a   set   of   tariffs,   valid   for   a  period  of  20  years,  with  a  bonus  in  cases  where  there  is  a  high  degree  of  photovoltaic  integration  in  the  buildings.    Three  types  of  systems  are  considered:    

• not  integrated,    • partially  integrated  and    • fully  integrated.    

For   2010   the   premium   for   building   integration   of   the   systems   varies,   from   a   minimum   of  €0.346/kWh  (for  un-­‐‑integrated  plants  with  capacity  less  than  20  kW)  to  a  maximum  of€0.471/kWh  (for  fully  integrated  plants  with  capacity  between  1  and  3  MW).  

A  tariff  bonus  of  5%  is  provided  for:  

• energy  self-­‐‑producers,  as  defined  by  the  Decree  79/1999;  • public  schools  and  public  health  centres;  • installations  integrated  to  building  substituting  asbestos  roofs;  • municipalities  with  less  than  5  000  inhabitants.  

Plants  with  a  capacity  lower  than  20  kWp  can  further  benefit  from  on  the  “spot  trading  service”.  Producers   receive,   in   addition   to   the  premium,   the  price  of   the   electricity   they   sell   either  on   the  market  or  through  bilateral  contracts.    (International  Energy  Agency,  2012)  (GSE,  2012).  

 

5.2.1.2 Feed-­‐‑In  Tariff  for  Solar  Thermodynamic  Energy  The  Decree  of  11  April  2008  lays  down  the  criteria  to  stimulate  the  production  of  electricity  from  solar  thermodynamic  plants;  including  hybrid  ones,  connected  to  the  electricity  grid,  and  built  in  Italy.    Plants  must  be  equipped  with  thermal  accumulation  systems.  

The   current  EU  driver   for   this  policy   is   the  EU  Directive  on   the  promotion  of   the  use  of   energy  from   renewable   sources   (2009/28/EC).     On   top   of   the   selling   price,   net   electricity   produced   by  thermodynamic  solar  plants  commissioned  after  18  July  2008  can  obtain  a  feed-­‐‑in  premium  for  25  years.     Up   to   2012   the   bonus   varies   from   €0.22   to   €0.28   per   kWh   depending   on   the   level   of  integration  of  the  plants.    In  the  case  of  hybrid  plants,  the  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  decreases  depending  on  the  ratio   between   the   amount   of   energy   not   produced   by   a   solar   energy   source   and   the   amount  produced  by  a  solar  energy  source.  

Page 21: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

21  

The   maximum   cumulative   power   of   all   solar   thermodynamic   plants   eligible   for   the   incentives  corresponds   to   1.5   million   square   meters   of   cumulative   surface.   The   national   objective   of   total  power  to  be  installed  by  2016  corresponds  to  2  million  square  meters  of  cumulative  surface.  

During   2013-­‐‑2014,   such   bonus   values  will   be   reduced   by   2%   a   year;   from   2014   onward   special  Ministerial  Decree  will  define  further  cuts.  (GSE,  2012)  (International  Energy  Agency,  2012).  

 

Solar  plants  that  started  to  operate  before  31  May  2011:  

According  to  the  Ministerial  Decree  of  6  August  2010  (the  “Third  Energy  Incentive”)  there  is  a  fixed  premium  (a  bonus  on  top  of  the  market  price  of  electricity)  The  size  of  the  premium  depends  on:  

• the  type  of  plant    • its  nominal  output    • when  the  plant  started  to  operate.    

The  premium  ranges  from  €0.251  to  €0.402  per  kWh.    The  premium  will  be  paid  for  20  years  after  the  plant  starts  operating.  For  thermodynamic  plants,  the  premium  will  be  paid  for  25  years.    

 

Solar  plants  which  started  operating  between  31  May  2011  and  31  December  2012.    

According   to   the   Ministerial   Decree   of   5   May   2011   (the   “Fourth   Energy   Incentive”)   a   fixed  premium  computed  on  the  basis  of  the  type  and  the  nominal  power  of  the  plant  is  available  up  to  31  December   2012.     In   the   first   six  months  of   2012   the  premium  ranges   from  €0.148  per  kWh   to  €0.274  per   kWh  and   in   the   second   six  months   of   2012   the  premium  will   range   from     €0.133  per  kWh   to     €0.252   per   kWh.   This   type   of   subsidy   will   expire   on   31   December   2012   and   will   be  replaced  by  a  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  system    

The   Central   government   set   the   maximum   amount   of   public   expenditure   for   this   incentive  program  for  plants  with  a  production  power   that  exceeds  certain   levels  at  €580  million   for  2012.    The  premium  will  be  paid  for  20  years  after  the  plant  starts  operating,  as  long  as  it  does  so  by  31  December  2016.    For  thermodynamic  plants,  the  premium  will  be  paid  for  25  years.  

 

5.2.2 Feed-­‐‑in  tariff  

5.2.2.1 Solar  plants  Feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   apply   to   solar   plants   that   started   operating   between   31  May   2011   and   1   January  2013.    According  to  the  Ministerial  Decree  of  5  May  2011  (Fourth  Energy  Incentive),  a  feed-­‐‑in  tariff,  including  a  premium  based  on  the  type  of  plant  and  its  nominal  output,  will  be  available  until  31  

Page 22: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

22  

December  2016.  In  the  first  six  months  of  2013  the  feed-­‐‑in  tariff,  including  the  premium,  will  range  from  €0.121  per  kWh  to  €0.375.    per  kWh.  

 

5.2.2.2 Wind  plants  The  incentive  scheme  for  wind  plants  is  based  on  the  two-­‐‑fold  mechanism  of  an  all-­‐‑inclusive  tariff  (“Tariffa  Onnicomprensiva”)   for  micro-­‐‑generation   plants  with   an   output   of   up   to   200   kWp   and  green   certificates   (“Certificati   Verdi”)   for   larger   plants.   These   certificates   are   issued   for   free   to  those  producing  energy  from  wind  power  and  can  be  sold  at  a  market  price  to  enable  conventional  producers  to  increase  their  production  power  from  conventional  sources.  

The”Tariffa  Onnicomprensiva”,  which  is  a  type  of  feed-­‐‑in  tariff,  includes  both  a  premium  and  the  sale  price  for  electricity.  This  tariff  will  be  paid  for  15  years  after  the  plant  starts  operating,  as  long  as  it  does  so  by  31  December  2012.  

Green   certificates   will   be   abolished   after   2015.   The   ministerial   decrees   implementing   future  incentive  systems  will  establish  how  the  transition  will  be  coordinated  from  the  green  certificates  system  to  a  new  system  based  on  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs.  

 

5.2.2.3 Biogas  and  biomass  Like   the  wind   energy   sector,   the   incentive   scheme   for   the   biogas   and   biomass   energy   sector   is  based   on   the   Tariffa   Onnicomprensiva   for   plants   with   an   output   of   up   to   1   MWp   and   green  certificates  for  larger  plants.  The  tariff  will  be  paid  for  15  years  after  the  plant  starts  operating,  as  long  as  it  does  so  by  31  December  2012.  

As  for  all  other  renewable  energy  plants,  a  new  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  system  will  be  introduced  for  biogas  and  biomass  plants  on  1  January  2013.  The  ministerial  decrees  that  will  implement  this  new  system  will  consider  the  origin  and  the  traceability  of  the  raw  materials  in  order  to  channel  each  specific  product  toward  its  most  productive  use.  The  decrees  will  also  consider  how  to  promote  the  efficient  use  of  waste  products,  the  construction  of  co-­‐‑generation  plants,  and  the  construction  of  micro  and  mini  co-­‐‑generation  plants.  (source  :  KPMG.com)    

 

5.2.2.4 Green  Certificates  The  1999  Electricity  Liberalisation  Act  and  Decrees   from  Italy'ʹs  Ministries  of  Trade  and   Industry  and  of  Environment   (MICA  Decree  11/11/99)   introduced  a  cap  and   trade  mechanism  to  promote  renewable   energy   sources.     It   required   Italian   energy   producers   and   importers   (producing   or  importing  more   than  100  GWh/year   from  conventional  sources)   to  ensure   that  a  certain  quota  of  electricity  fed  into  the  grid  comes  from  renewable  energy  sources.    The  budget  law  of  2008  (Law  No  244  24-­‐‑12-­‐‑2007)  set  the  following  minimum  obligation  quotas:  

• 2007:  3.8%  

Page 23: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

23  

• 2008:  4.6%  • 2009:  5.3%  • 2010:  6.1%  • 2011:  6.8%  

Producers  and  importers  can  comply  with  the  obligation  by  means  of  green  certificates.    They  can  buy  those  certificates  through  bilateral  contracts  or  participating  in  the  green  certificates  platform  (managed  by  GME,  the  energy  markets  operator).    Suppliers  can  fulfill  the  obligation  by:  

• buying  green  certificates  from  entitled  new  renewable  energy  plants,    • building  new  renewable  energy  plants,  or    • importing  electricity  from  new  renewable  energy  plants  from  countries  with  similar  

instruments  on  the  basis  of  reciprocity.  

Renewable   source   plants   that   came   into   operation   before   31   December   2007   can   obtain   green  certificates   for  12  years.  Subsequent  regulatory   interventions  have   increased   the   incentive  period  to  15  years.  

On   29  March   2011,   the   Legislative   Decree   no.   28   came   into   force.     This   Decree,   also   known   as  “Renewables  Decree”,   constitutes   the   implementation  Directive   2009/28/EC   on   the   promotion   of  the  use  of  energy  from  renewable  sources.    This  basically  reforms  Italy’s  Green  Certificate  System.    For  plants  built  up  to  December  2012,  the  current  scheme  would  still  be  used  but  by  2015,  a  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  would  be  applied  (GSE,  2012).  

 

   

Page 24: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

24  

5.3 Renewable  energy  incentives  in  the  Emilia  Romagna  Region  Emilia-­‐‑Romagna   is   a   governmental   region   of   Northern   Italy,   comprising   the   former   regions   of  Emilia  and  Romagna.  Its  capital  is  Bologna  (see  Figure  5  and  Figure  6  below).  

 

Figure  5  -­‐‑  Map  of  Emilia  Romagna  

Capital   Bologna  Area   22,446  km2  (8,666  sq.  mi)  Population  (2010-­‐‑11-­‐‑30)   4,429,766  Density   200/km2  (510/sq.  mi)  GDP/  Nominal   €138.7  billion  (2008)  GDP  per  capita   €31,900  (2008)  Rate  of  unemployment   3.2%  

Figure  6  -­‐‑  Some  Key  facts  about  Emilia-­‐‑Romagna  

 

5.3.1 Incentive  mechanisms  in  the  Emilia  Romagna  Region  The   Emilia   Romagna   Region   considers   that   the   following   mechanisms   are   feasible   to   be  implemented:  

1. Capital  account:   incentives  are  given  as  a  grant,  and  no  money  is  returned  to  the  Region.    Grants  are  about  a  percentage  of  the  total  plant  cost.    Previous  economic  incentives  (2003,  2004   and   2007)   have   been   distributed   by   means   of   a   single,   sealed   bid   english   auction.    Other  auction  types  can  be  considered  within  ePolicy.  

2. Interests   account:   incentives   are   given   as   a   grant   only   to   pay   (part   of)   interests   on   bank  loans  (again  no  money  is  returned  to  the  Region).  

3. Rotation  fund:  the  Region  lends  money  and  interests  are  returned  after  a  given  period.  

Page 25: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

25  

4. Guarantee   fund:   the   Region   guarantees   for   the   investor   that   obtains   a   bank   loan,   thus  easing  the  loan  request.  

It  is  understood  that  so  far  Emilia  Romagna  has  made  three  calls  offering  to  provide  incentives  to  photovoltaics:    

• 2001  with  incentives  given  in  2002,  • 2003  with  incentives  given  in  2004  • 2009  program  

These  programs  are  briefly  analysed  below.    However,  the  data  for  the  2009  program  is  currently  not  available.    It  is  not  known  if  there  have  been  any  further  calls  since  2009.  

5.3.2 Grants  

5.3.2.1 2001  program  In   2001   the   Emilia   Romagna   Region   opened   an   auction   for   providing   incentives   for   the  construction  of  photovoltaic  plants.    Requests  could  be  made  in  four  different  sectors:  

1. Residential  areas  (private  citizens  or  industries  collecting  requests  from  private  citizens)  2. Schools  and  services  for  University  students  3. Hotels  and  related  activities,  touristic  buildings  (in  rural  areas  and  mountains)  4. Infrastructures  for  sport,  cultural,  entertainment  activities  

The  available  budget  was  divided  between  these  sectors  taking  account  of  the  number  of  proposals  that  were  submitted.  

In  each  group,  for  each  proposal  the  proposal  being  funded  by  the  applicant  was  identified.      

Overall   the   779   proposals   were   eligible.   The   total   investment   required   by   these   proposals  amounted  to  €22.3  million  whereas  the  budget  available  for  grants  was  around  €1.8  million.    This  was  divided  between  the  sectors,  as  follows:  

• Sector  1:  €1,236,000  • Sector  2:  €177,000  • Sector  3:  €282,000  • Sector  4:  €134,000  

From  the  779  applications,  122  were  funded  based  on  the  following  selection  criteria:  

1. For  each  group  applications  were  sorted  according  to  the  percentage  funding  requested  from  the  region  in  ascending  order  

2. The   fund  was  allocated   to   the  projects  with   the   lowest  percentage   requested  until   the  budget  was  exhausted.  

Page 26: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

26  

Figure  7  shows  the  average,  minimum  and  maximum  accepted  bid  for  the  funded  projects.    As  it  can   be   seen,   the   successful   bids   ranged   from   a  minimum  of   4%   to   a  maximum  of   63%   funding  requested  from  the  region.    

It   is   not   clear  why   the   Emilio  Romagna   regional   government   chose   to   segment   the   applications  into  the  four  sectors  described  above.  

 

 

 

 

 

Figure  7  -­‐‑  Average,  Maximum  and  minimum  accepted  bid  for  the  renewable  energy  program  in  2001  

 

Almost  all  of  the  funded  projects  had  a  capacity  of  less  than  2kW  (i.e.  PV  installed  in  residences).    Figure   11   shows   the   distribution   of   funded   PV   projects   based   on   the   size   and   the   contribution  requested.    As  can  be  seen  more  than  80%  of  the  funded  projects  are  less  than  10  kW  and  requested  less  than  €50,000.  

 

 

Figure  8  -­‐‑  Distribution  of  funded  PV  project  based  on  the  size  and  the  contribution  requested  

   

 €  -­‐    

 €  10.000    

 €  20.000    

 €  30.000    

 €  40.000    

 €  50.000    

 €  60.000    

 €  70.000    

 €  80.000    

 €  90.000    

 €  100.000    

0   5   10   15   20   25  kWp  

Contribu-on  requested  (€)  

Sector   Average  Capacity  kWp  

Average  %   Max  %   Min  %  

1   3   52   63   40  2   7   42   50   4  3   12   48   63   10  4   20   31   40   13  

Page 27: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

27  

5.3.2.2 2003  program  In  2003  the  second  regional  program  was  launched.    The  available  budget  amounted  to  about  €3.3  million  (mainly  sourced  from  the  capital  account).  The  eligibility  criteria  included  the  following      

• Plants  should  be  in  the  range  1  kWp  to  20  kWp  • Architectural  integration  would  be  an  advantage  • Plants  should  be  compliant  to  a  technical  specification  designed  by  ENEA  (Italian  National  

agency  for  new  technologies,  Energy  and  sustainable  economic  development)  • Connection  to  the  electricity  distribution  network  should  be  considered  

An  evaluation  criteria  was  developed  and  expressed  in  the  equation  shown  below                  

X  =  100*K*(C*P)/(Y*Z)  

Where:  

• C  is  the  unit  cost  (€/kW)  • P  is  nominal  power  of  the  plant  between  1  and  20  kW    • Y  is  expected  expenses  (in  €)  • Z  is  percentage  of  incentive  required    • K  is  multiplicative  factor  of  1  or  3  (if  architectural  integration  is  performed)  •  

5.3.2.3 2009  program  The  data  for  this  program  is  not  currently  available.  

 

5.3.3 Fiscal  incentives  The  following  fiscal  incentives  have  been  considered  but  not  applied:  

• Interests  account:   Incentives  are  given  as  a  grant  only   to  pay   interests  on  bank   loans   (no  money  is  returned  to  the  region).  

• Rotation  fund:  The  region  lends  money  and  interests  are  returned  after  a  given  period.  • Guarantee  fund:  The  region  guarantees  for  the  investor  that  obtains  a  bank  loan.  

 

   

Page 28: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

28  

5.4 Renewable  energy  incentives  in  France  A  number  of  acronyms  are  used  in  this  section.    These  are  defined  below:  

• ADEME:  French  Agency  for  Environment  and  Energy  Management  • CHP:   Combined   Heat   and   Power,   the   use   of   a   heat   engine   or   a   power   station   to  

simultaneously  generate  both  electricity  and  useful  heat  • CRE:  Commission  for  the  Regulation  of  Energy  (in  France)  • CSPE:  Contribution  to  the  Public  Service  of  Electricity,  tax  on  electricity  bills  • DOM:  Overseas  Territories  • EDF:  Electricity  Of  France  • ERDF:  Electrical  Distribution  Network  of  France  • RTE:  Transmission  Network  of  France  • FIT:  Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  • kWc:   kWp   or   kiloWatt-­‐‑peak,   a   measure   of   the   nominal   power   of   a   photovoltaic   solar  

energy  under  laboratory  illumination  conditions  • kWhEP:  kWhPE  or  kiloWatt  of  Primary  Energy.  It  takes  into  account  the  energy  necessary  

to  the  production  and  transport  of  electricity.  By  convention,  1kWh  charged  by  the  supplier  =  2,58kWhEP  

 

5.4.1 Political  approach  to  Energy    The  French  presidential  campaign  lasted  from  October  2011  to  May  2012,  when  François  Hollande  (socialist)  was  elected  President  of  France.  

Energy  was   one   of   the  most   discussed   topics   during   this   campaign   –   including   two   competing  visions  regarding  nuclear  power;  one  approach  in  favour  supported  by  the  right-­‐‑wing  parties  and  another  opposed  to  it  and  supported  by  anti-­‐‑nuclear  ecologists.    François  Hollande  appeared  to  be  seeking   to   promote   a   compromise:   committing   himself   –   if   elected   –   to   undertake   a   “green  revolution”,   including   a   decrease   of   the   nuclear   share   in   France’s   energy  mix   from   75%   to   50%  until  2025.    In  the  short-­‐‑term  (the  5-­‐‑year  period  until  the  next  Presidential  election)  this  implied  the  closure  of  a  potentially   less  safe  nuclear  plant   in  Flamanville,  France.    Over   the   longer   term,   this  necessarily  implied  an  increase  in  the  generation  of  electricity  from  renewable  generation  in  France  which  is  somewhat  lower  than  that  of  many  other  EU  countries  (see  Figure  9  below).    He  declared  during   the   campaign   that   any   job   lost   in   the   nuclear   industry   would   be   transferred   to   the  renewable  energies  one.  

Page 29: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

29  

However  it  is  generally  believed  in  France  that  investment  in  renewable  generation  is  unlikely  to  be   sufficient   to   compensate   for   the   decrease   in   the   nuclear   share   of   the   energy  mix.   The   newly  elected  French  government  seems  willing  to  fundamentally  restructure  energy  markets  as  well  as  giving   a  major   boost   to   renewable   energies.   The   right-­‐‑wing  opposition   states   that   this   approach  will  drastically   increase  the  electricity  costs   in  France.    Figure  10  below  shows  the  energy  mix   in  2010   in   France   and   for   the   world   as   a   whole   showing   France’s   relatively   high   dependence   on  nuclear  power.    These  issues  are  further  discussed  below.  

Figure  9  -­‐‑  Percentage  of  production  from  renewable  sources  in  European  countries  in  2007  

Page 30: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

30  

 

 

5.4.2 Energy  stakeholders  in  France  • The  CRE  (Commission  for  Regulation  of  Energy)  is  the  French  regulator  • RTE  is  the  (only)  transmission  system  operator  • (and  is  a  wholly  owned  subsidiary  of  EDF)  • ERDF   is   the   main   distribution   operator,   but   not   the   only   one.     Private   companies   like  

Poweo,  GDF  Suez  or  Direct  Energie  and  regionally  based  utilities  like  Gaz  de  Barr,  Gaz  de  Strasbourg,  Gaz  de  Grenoble  are  also  distribution  companies.  However  none  of   these  are  the  owners  of  the  parts  of  the  network  that  they  are  operating.    These  remain  the  property  of  either  ERDF  or  of  the  relevant  local  authority.  

• EDF  is  the  main  producer  of  energy,  and  is  partially  state-­‐‑owned  (84.48%).    EDF  owns  all  of  the  nuclear  facilities  in  France  as  well  as  solar,  wind  and  thermal  plants.  

• The   main   customer   groups   together   with   their   relative   sizes   (in   terms   of   electricity  consumption)  are  shown  on  the  chart  below  –  Figure  11  (Source:  EDF).    In  2010,  residential  and   tertiary   customers   consumed   the  main   share   of   total   electricity   consumed   in   France,  with  a  constant  steady  growth  in  recent  years  (of  around  approximately  4%).  

   

Figure  10  -­‐‑  Energy  mix  in  France  in  2010  

Page 31: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

31  

 

Figure  11  -­‐‑  Electricity  Consumption  in  France  (2010)  

 

5.4.3 Energy  markets    

 

Figure  12  -­‐‑  Energy  sectors  in  France  

Legislation  

The   “NOME”   Act   (December   2010)   reorganised   the   French   energy   market   by   opening   it   to  competition.  

With  the  Act,  the  market  for  the  production  of  energy  has  been  opened  to  competition.    However  this  would  have   created  problems   for  newly  emerging,   currently   relatively  expensive   renewable  technologies  without  some  further  policy  initiatives.    

2,70%  2,30%  

1,80%  

68,10%  

25,10%  

Electricity  Consump-on  in  France  (2010)  

Urban  and  rail  transport  

Steel  Industry  

Agriculture  

ResidenFal  and  terFary  

Industry  

Page 32: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

32  

The  response  has  been  the  Code  of  Energy,  which  gives  a  significant  boost   to  renewable  energy,  through  the  purchasing  obligation  .    

The  opposite  effects  on  renewable  energy  of  these  two  pieces  of  legislation  are  described  in  the  two  sections  below.  

 

The  NOME  Act  

Prior  to  NOME,  EDF  had  a  full  monopoly  of  the  use  of  nuclear  production  in  supplying  end  use  customers.     However   following   the   implementation   of   NOME,   EDF   is   required   to   sell   up   to  100TWh  per  year  of  such  nuclear  production  to  their  competitors  who  use  this  to  compete  for  such  end-­‐‑use  customers.    Conditions  for  the  sale  of  this  nuclear  production  are  defined  and  evaluated  by  the  CRE  (French  regulator).    The  nuclear  buying  price  is  fixed  by  the  Ministry  of  Energy.    From  1st  January  2012,  this  price  is  42€  per  MWh.    This  may  be  revised  when  a  new  nuclear  generation  facility  (EPR)  becomes  operational  which  is  not  expected  until  2015.  

While  opening  the  energy  market  to  competition  can  be  seen  as  a  positive  development,  it  brings  about  a  key  change  in  terms  of  connection  fees.    Article  11  of  NOME  states  that  all  connection  fees  have   to  be  paid  by   the  generator.    Prior   to  NOME,  40%  of   the  connection  cost  was  borne  by   the  transmission  utility  RTE  for  transmission  network  connected  generators.    For  distribution  network  connected  generators,  all  costs  were  and  are  to  be  borne  by  the  generator  (these  are  estimated  and  the  work  associated  with  these  costs  is  performed  by  the  distribution  utility).    This  measure  has  the  potential  to  have  a  serious  detrimental  impact  on  the  implementation  of  renewable  technologies  on  the  French  network,  especially  when  compared  to  nuclear  generation.  

 

The  Code  of  Energy  

Since   February   2000   there   has   been   a   purchasing   obligation   on   distribution   companies   to   buy  renewable   production.     This   was   subsequently   incorporated   in   the   2011   Code   of   Energy.     The  money   that   distribution   companies   lose   by   buying   such   electricity   at   a   cost   that   exceeds   that   of  more   conventional   or   mature   generation,   are   recovered   from   end-­‐‑use   customer   through   a   tax  called  CSPE.    

Feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   apply   to   any   renewable   energy   installation   satisfying   any   one   of   the   following  conditions  (in  addition  to  certain  size  limitations):  

•   Any  installation  transforming  residential  waste  

•   Any  installation  feeding  a  heat  network  

•   Any   installation   using   renewable   technologies   including   wind,   solar,   hydroelectricity,  geothermic,  cogeneration,  biogas,  methanisation  

Page 33: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

33  

 

5.4.4 Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  (FIT)    In  the  previous  section  it  is  explained  that  any  renewable  generation  that  meets  the  conditions  has  to   be   purchased   by   distribution   companies   (mainly   ERDF).     The   material   below   discusses   the  conditions  and  the  price  for  such  sales.  

The   value   of   FITs   and   the   conditions   under   which   these   are   applicable   to   various   renewable  technologies  are  discussed  in  the  sections  below.  

 

5.4.4.1 Photovoltaic  In  France  different  FIT  terms  apply  to  solar  panels  without  and  with  full  building  integration.    

Full-­‐‑building  integration  means  part  of  the  roof  is   removed   (and   replaced   by   the   solar   panel)  and   that   the   installation   includes   insulation  work   (see   opposite).   Without   Full   integration  means  that  the  solar  panels  are  placed  on  top  of  the  existing  roof  surface.  Solar  panels  with  full-­‐‑building  integration  get  premium  feed-­‐‑in  tariff    

The   PV   FIT   tariffs   in   Figure   14   are   the   latest  available,   apply   to   connections   made   in   the  period,  and  are  fixed  for  the  next  20  years  (i.e.  

up  to  2032).    Figure  15  illustrates  the  FIT  price  variations  for  different  capacity  ranges  and  shows  the  difference  between  simplified  and  full  building  integration.  

 

Type  of  building   Type  of  installation   Installed  Capacity  FITs  valid  between  01/10/2012  –  31/12/2012  (c€/kWh)  

Residential  Full  building-­‐‑integration  

0-­‐‑9kWc   34.15  9-­‐‑36kWc   29.88  

Simplified  building-­‐‑integration  

0-­‐‑36kWc   17.04  36-­‐‑100kWc   16.19  

School,  university  or  hospital  

Full  building-­‐‑integration  0-­‐‑9kWc   22.79  9-­‐‑36kWc   22.79  

Simplified  building-­‐‑integration  

0-­‐‑36kWc   17.04  36-­‐‑100kWc   16.19  

Others  (farms,  commercial  buildings…)  

Full  building-­‐‑integration   0-­‐‑9kWc   19.76  Simplified  building-­‐‑integration  

0-­‐‑36kWc   17.04  36-­‐‑100kWc   16.19  

Figure  14  -­‐‑  PV  FIT  for  PV  in  France  

Figure  13  -­‐‑  PV  Full-­‐‑building  integration  

Page 34: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

34  

Figure  15  -­‐‑  FIT  for  PV  in  France.  

 

 

Figure  16  -­‐‑  Evolution  of  FIT  for  PV  in  France  

As  shown  in  Figure  16,  the  PV  FIT  value  has  varied  over  the  last  few  years.    In  2011,  the  decrease  in  FIT  was  prompted  by  the  French  government  in  view  of  the  large  number  of  connections  that  were  occurring.    The  decrease   in   the  value  of   the  FIT  was  seen  as  necessary   to   limit   the  costs  of  subsidisation  of  PV  which  were  being   recovered   from  addition   to   customer  bills.     This  decrease  

Page 35: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

35  

may  have  led  to  a  reduced  number  of  connections.  This  has  prompted  the  government  to  increase  the  FIT  value  for  all  full-­‐‑building  integration  installations  of  36-­‐‑100kWc,  whose  FIT  increases  from  16.19  to  18.4  c€  per  kWh  or  around  12%.  

It  is  clear  from  Figure  16  that  a  strong  correlation  exists  between  PV  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  and  the  number  of  PV  connection  requests.      

 

5.4.4.2 Wind  farms  Connection:   If   a  wind   farm   installation   seeking   connection   is   rated   less   than  or   equal   to   12MW  capacity  then  it   is  connected  to  the  distribution  network.    Installations  with  capacity  greater  than  12MW  are  connected  to  the  transmission  network.  

Various  mechanisms  that  fix  the  wind  power  prices  are  described  below:  

Responses  to  a  call  for  tenders  fix  the  prices  

Some  onshore  and  all  offshore  wind  project  proposals  are   requested  by  a   call   for   tenders  by   the  Ministry  of  Energy.    The  first  call  for  tenders  for  3000MW  of  offshore  wind  production  in  five  areas  in  the  west  of  France  was  launched  in  April  2012.    The  call  for  tenders  stated  that:  

• The  participant  has  to  include  technical,  financial  and  environmental  commitments.    • The   feed-­‐‑in   price   is   proposed   by   the   participant   and   the   process   can   be   seen   as   an  

“auction”.  

The  selling  tariff  of  energy  produced  is  one  of  the  parameters  of  a  wind  producer’s  offer,  alongside  with  investment  cost,  technology,  and  environmental  factors.  

Subsidiaries  of  EDF  won  four  out  of   the   five  areas  of  offshore  wind  farm  installations  whilst   the  fifth  one  was  not  attributed  to  any  participant.  

Another  call  for  tenders  for  2000MW  is  expected  in  the  first  Semester  of  2013.    

The   government   aims   to   reach   the   target   of   6000MW  of   offshore  wind  production   in   France   by  2020.  

Figure   17  below   indicates   the   criteria  under  which   the   schemes  were   assessed  and   their   relative  weights  in  the  marking  scheme  

Page 36: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

36  

40%  

40%  

20%  

Offshore  Wind  Farms  -­‐  Proposal  Appraisal  Criteria  

and  Weights  

Quality  of  the  industrial  and  social  project  

Selling  tariff  for  generated  electricity  

Respect  of  environment  

 

Other  initiatives:  Government  set  price  resulting  from  the  purchasing  obligation  

As   a   result   of   the   purchasing   obligation,   state-­‐‑fixed   feed-­‐‑in   tariff   exist   for   households   and  producers  not  participating  in  a  tender  process.    The  values  are  quoted  in  Figure  18.  

  Period   Tariff  (c€/kWh)  Onshore   0-­‐‑10Y   8.2  

10-­‐‑15Y   2.8-­‐‑8.2  Offshore   0-­‐‑10Y   13  

10-­‐‑20Y   3-­‐‑13  Figure  18  -­‐‑  FIT  for  wind  production  in  France  

 

5.4.4.3 Other  renewables  The  French  government  ensures  through  the  Purchasing  Obligation  that  a  minimum  Feed-­‐‑In  tariff  exists  for  all  renewable  technologies  and  these  values  are  quoted  in  Figure  19.  

Type   Effective  from   Duration  of  contracts  (years)  

Tariffs  

Wind   17th    November  2008   15/20   See  Figure  11    

Photovoltaic   4th    March  2011   20   See  Figure  11    

Hydraulic   1st  March  2007   20   -­‐‑  6.07  c€/kWh  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  of    0.5-­‐‑  2.5  for  small  installations  +  

Figure  17  -­‐‑  Offshore  Wind  Farms  Proposal  Assessment  

Page 37: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

37  

Figure  19  -­‐‑  FIT  for  other  renewable  energies  in  France  

 

   

                                                                                                               1 Cogeneration (also combined heat and power, CHP) is the use of a heat engine or a power station to simultaneously generate both electricity and useful heat.  

feed-­‐‑in  premium  0  –  1.68  c€/kWh  in  winter  depending  on  regularity  of  production  -­‐‑  15  c€/kWh  for  ocean  energy    

Geothermal   23rd  July  2010   15   -­‐‑  Mainland  France    :  20  c€/kWh  ,  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  efficiency  of  0  -­‐‑  8  c€/kWh    -­‐‑  Overseas  territories  (DOM)    :  13  c€/kWh  ,  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  efficiency  of  0  -­‐‑  3  c€/kWh    

Combined  heat  and  power  (CHP)1  

31st    July  2001   12   6.1  to  9,15  c€/kWh  depending  on  gas  price,  operating  time  and  power.    

Burning  household  waste  

2nd    October  2001   15   4.5  -­‐‑  5  c€/kWh  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  efficiency  of    0  –  0.3  c€/kWh    

Biomass  (non  vegetal  and/or  animal)  +Gross  or  transformed  (animal  flour)  animal  wastes    

27th  January  2011   20   4.34  c€/kWh  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  tariff  7.71  –  12.53  c€/kWh  depending  on  power,  resources  used,  and  especially  efficiency  criteria.  

Biogas   19th  May  2011   15   8.121  –  9.745  c€/kWh  depending  on  power  +  feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  efficiency  of  0  –  4  c€/kWh    

Methanization   19th  May  2011   15   11.19  –  13.37  c€/kWh  depending  on  power  feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  efficiency  of  0  –  4  c€/kWh  +    feed-­‐‑in  premium  depending  on  manure  processing  of  0  -­‐‑  2,6  c€/kWh    

Other  installations  (S  <  36kVA)    

13th  March  2002   15   7.87  –  9.60  c€/kWh  

Page 38: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

38  

5.4.4.4 Funding  of  renewable  energies    

Tariff  equalisation  

One   of   the  main   principles   in   electricity   billing   in   France   is   that   each   customer   (mainland   and  overseas  territories)  has  the  same  tariff  for  electricity,  whatever  investments  have  been  made  in  the  region  or  the  income  that  is  received  from  end-­‐‑use  customers  within  it.    Thus,  as  shown  in  Figure  20  is  that  some  regions  make  a  significant  loss,  whilst  others  have  profits  or  even  large  profits.      

 

CSPE  

CPSE  can  be  defined  as  a  tax  on  energy  bills  to  finance  renewable  energies  expansion    

All   investments   of   EDF   (essentially   state-­‐‑owned)   have   to   be   paid   by   all   customers   one  way   or  another   (income  tax  or  directly  on  the  bill),  and  as  result  of   tariff  equalisation  the   location  of   the  individual  customer  does  not  impact  on  the  amount  that  is  required  to  be  paid.  

The  French  government  created  in  2003  a  tax  on  the  electricity  bill  called  CSPE  (contribution  to  the  public  service  of  electricity).    It  was  originally  created  to  finance  and  support  CHP  and  renewable  technologies   (essentially   photovoltaic   feed-­‐‑in   tariffs,   onshore   and   offshore   wind   projects,   and  sustainable   energy   supplying   in   isolated   areas).   In   2011,   it  was   allocated   between   the   following  categories:  

   

ELECTRICITY  INVESTMENTS  IN  2010  (M€)  

PROFIT  OR  LOSS  IN  2010  (M€)  

Figure  20  -­‐‑  Tariff  equalisation  

Page 39: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

39  

 

Figure  21  -­‐‑  Allocation  of  CSPE  incomes  

 

More  precisely,   in  2013  every  domestic  consumer  will  be  paying  4€  per  year  via  CSPE  to  sustain  wind  energy  production.    This  has  to  be  compared  to  the  average  3000€  paid  per  year  for  energy  by  every  household.  

During   year   2011   the   CSPE   increased   from   4.5€   per  MWh   to   7.5€   per  MWh  which   on   average  represented  8%  of  domestic  energy  bills.    In  2012  the  CSPE  tax  stands  at  10.5€/MWh.    Larger  non  domestic  companies  are  also  paying  this  tax,  in  some  cases  (the  top  400  industrial  companies)  with  a  specific  ceiling.  Overall  contributions  are  shown  in  Figure  22.  

 

Figure  22  -­‐‑  Contribution  of  sectors  to  charges  (2011)  

 

5.4.5 Fiscal  incentives    Eco-­‐‑credit  was  launched  in  2009;  it  represents  a  new  type  of  financing  option  available  to  landlords  for   various   refurbishment   works   that   are   carried   out   to   improve   the   energy   efficiency   of   a  building.  

42,40%  

35%  

21,20%  

1,40%  Renewable  energies  in  mainland  

Tariffs  equalisaFon  in  rural  areas  

CHP  

Solidarity  (rebate  for  poorest  ones)  

51%  37%  

12%  

Contribu-on  of  sectors  to  charges  (2011)  

Medium-­‐sized  and  large  companies  

Private  customers  

Small  companies  

Page 40: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

40  

Loans   in   the   range   of   10000€   to   30000€   are   available   depending   on   the   nature   and   number   of  refurbishment  works  (less  than  300€  per  m2).    The  repayment  of  the  loan  is  expected  to  be  over  10  years.  

Eligibility:  

• Technical  o Credit  for  the  financing  of  certain  categories  of  works  including:  

§ Set  of  operations  improving  energy  efficiency  § Operation(s)  targeting  a  new  level  of  energy  efficiency:  

• consumption  lower  than  150kWhEP  per  m2  per  year    if  consumption  before  refurbishment  works  was  over  180  kWhEP  per  m2  per  year;  

• consumption  lower  than  80  kWhEP  per  m2  per  year  if  consumption  before   refurbishment   works   was   less   than   180   kWhEP   per   m2   per  year.  

o Refurbishing   a   collective   sanitation   system   with   a   solution   based   on   renewable  energy  

• Financial  o No  minimum  basic  or  income-­‐‑tested  benefits  o Credit  subscribed  by  the  landlord/owner  of  the  property  

The   eco-­‐‑credit   finance   is  designed   to   cover  delivery   and   installation  of   new  equipment   and   any  associated  operations  including  new  air  ventilation  system  and  electrical  operations.  

 

5.4.6 Investment  grants  

5.4.6.1 At  a  national  scale  Subvention  fund  for  isolated  areas  

This   national   fund   is   managed   by   ADEME   (French   Agency   for   Environment   and   Energy  Management),  the  state-­‐‑founded  national  environment  agency  and  is  available  to  any  installation  capable   of   producing   electricity   by   renewable   means.     This   includes   small   and   medium-­‐‑sized  domestic  wind  turbines.  

   This  subvention  fund  covers  up  to:  

• 90%  of  investment  cost  in  rural  areas  • 70%  of  investment  cost  in  urban  areas  

For  DOM  (overseas  territories)  such  as  La  Réunion,  Martinique  and  Guyane,  these  subventions  are  higher.  

Heat  Fund  (“Fonds  Chaleur”)  

Page 41: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

41  

The  Heating  fund  is  also  managed  by  ADEME.    Basically  it  is  an  auction  floor  for  projects  linked  to  renewable  energy.    It  selects  the  best  renewable  projects  within  eligible  categories,  and  gives  them  an  additional  grant   to   any  other  of   the  more  usual  ones   that   the  project  may  also  be   eligible   to.    Categories  of  eligible  projects  are  the  following:  

• Solar  thermal  • Geothermal  • Biomass  • Biogas  and  transformation  of  domestic  wastes  • Heating  networks  

This  fund  has  1.2billion  €  to  spend  on  a  five-­‐‑year  period  of  time  (2009-­‐‑2014).  

5.4.6.2 At  a  regional  and  local  scales  Solar  Energy  

Solar   investment  grants  depend  on   the   region  where   the  customer   lives   in  France.    These  grants  are  provided  by   the   region,   the  ADEME,   local   authorities   (towns,  groups  of   towns),   and  energy  utilities.    A  wide  range  of  policies  have  been  set  up  in  France,  depending  on  the  technology  and  region.  Figure  23  to  Figure  30  below  provide  more  information  about  these  arrangements.  

“X”  means  this  kind  of  grant  exists  in  at  least  one  region/town/utility  in  France  

 

  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Collective  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Combined  Solar  System  

Photovoltaic  for  private  customers  

Photovoltaic  for  groups  of  customers  

Global   X     X   X    

per  m2   X   X        

per  kWc     X     X   X  

per  kWh           X  

per  unit            

%  of  handwork   X          

%  of  total  cost     X     X   X  

Figure  23:  Investment  grants  from  Regions  and  ADEME  -­‐‑  types  

 

  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Collective  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Combined  Solar  System  

Photovoltaic  for  private  customers  

Photovoltaic  for  groups  of  customers  

Global   X     X   X    

per  m2   X   X   X   X    

per  kWc            

per  kWh         X    

per  unit            

Page 42: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

42  

%  of  handwork       X   X    

%  of  material            

%  of  total  cost     X        

Figure  24  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  from  Local  Authorities  –  types  

 

  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Collective  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Combined  Solar  System  

Photovoltaic  for  private  customers  

Photovoltaic  for  groups  of  customers  

Global   X          

per  m2   X          

per  kWc            

per  kWh            

per  unit   X          

%  of  handwork            

%  of  material            

Figure  25  -­‐‑    Investment  grants  from  Utilities  –  types  

 

average  on  values  >  0   Region   number  of  

regions  (/27)  

Local  Authorities   number  of  

regions  (/27)  

Utilities   number  of  

regions  (/27)  Grant  (global)   935.71  €   7   349.71  €   7   250  €   1  

%  of  handwork   33%   3   25%   2   -­‐      

%  of  material   -­‐   1   4%   1   -­‐      

%  of  investment  cost   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  kWc   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  m2   -­‐       67.50  €   5   300  €   1  

per  kWh   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  unit   -­‐       -­‐       210  €   2  

Figure  26  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  for  Solar  Water  Heaters  

 

average  on  values  >  0   Region   number  of  regions  (/27)   Local  Authorities  

number  of  regions  (/27)  

Utilities   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Grant  (global)   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  handwork   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  material   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  investment  cost   50%   11   17%   4   -­‐      

per  kWc   -­‐     -­‐       -­‐      

per  m2   445  €   5   90.00  €   3   -­‐      

per  kWh   1.42  €   5   -­‐       -­‐      

per  unit   -­‐     -­‐       -­‐      

Figure  27  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  for  Collective  Solar  Water  Heaters  

Page 43: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

43  

average  on  values  >  0   Region   number  of  

regions  (/27)  

Local  Authorities   number  of  

regions  (/27)  

Utilities   number  of  

regions  (/27)  Grant  (global)   830.56  €   9   594.34  €   11   -­‐      

%  of  handwork   -­‐       28%   5   -­‐      

%  of  material   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  investment  cost   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  kWc   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  m2   -­‐       67.86  €   5   -­‐      

per  kWh   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  unit   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

Figure  28  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  for  Combined  solar  systems  

 

average  on  values  >  0   Region   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Local  Authorities   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Utilities   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Grant  (global)   750.00  €   1   327.26  €   4   -­‐      

%  of  handwork   -­‐       25%   3   -­‐      

%  of  material   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  investment  cost   94.50%   22   -­‐       -­‐      

per  kWc   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  m2   -­‐       100.00  €   2   -­‐      

per  kWh   -­‐       1.00  €   1   -­‐      

per  unit   -­‐     -­‐       -­‐      

Figure  29  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  for  photovoltaic  for  domestic  customers  

 

average  on  values  >  0   Region   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Local  Authorities  

number  of  regions  (/27)  

Utilities   number  of  regions  (/27)  

Grant  (global)   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  handwork   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  material   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

%  of  investment  cost   50.00%   4   -­‐       -­‐      

per  kWc   -­‐       3,000.00  €   3   -­‐      

per  m2   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

per  kWh   0.60  €   1   -­‐       -­‐      

per  unit   -­‐       -­‐       -­‐      

Figure  30  -­‐‑  Investment  grants  for  photovoltaic  for  groups  of  domestic  customers  

 

                                                                                                               2  Both  are  isolated  overseas  territories  (Martinique  and  La  Réunion)  

Page 44: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

44  

5.4.7 Tax  exemptions  

5.4.7.1 Tax  rebates  Consumption  tax  

VAT  in  France  is  a  form  of  consumption  tax.  From  the  perspective  of  the  buyer,  it  is  a  tax  on  the  purchase  price.    From  that  of  the  seller,  it  is  a  tax  only  on  the  value  added  to  a  product,  material,  or  service,  from  an  accounting  point  of  view,  by  this  stage  of  its  manufacture  or  distribution.    The  rate  is  usually  19.6%.  

A  rebate  on  purchase  of  renewable  production  and  its  installation    For  the  purchase  and  installation  of  renewable  energy,  this  VAT  is  decreased  to  5.5%.  

 

A  rebate  on  energy  bills  for  customers  subscribing  to  “green”  heating  suppliers    Besides,  this  VAT  is  also  decreased  down  since  2002  to  5.5%  on  the  electricity  bill  of  any  consumer  having   subscribed   to  a  heating   supplier  whose  heat   is  produced   from  at   least   80%  of   renewable  energies  from  biomass.  

Finance  tax    

This  “credit  on  taxes”  has  been  set  up  by  the  Government  in  2005  and  applies  to  the  total  material  cost,  after  deduction  of  consumption  taxes  and  any  subvention.  

Some  ceilings  apply  depending  on  the  subscriber,  as  follows:  

  Spending  limits  For  singles,  divorced  or  widowed  individuals   8000€  For  couples  paying  taxes  together   16000€  By  additional  adult/children   400€  By  property  rented   8000€  

Figure  31  -­‐‑  Spending  limits  for  the  French  credit  on  taxes  

This  is  applied  to  the  purchase  of  at  least  one  (or  more)  of  the  following  devices,  and  under  certain  conditions  including  technology,  surface  and  the  age  of  the  property/building:    

• generators  using  a  renewable  energy,    • heat  pumps  other  than  air/air  aiming  at  producing  heat  or  heated  water  (such  as  air/water  

or  geothermal  heat  pumps),    • solar  thermal  installations,    • condensing  boilers.    

Also  included  are  insulation  works  such  as  

• insulation   of   glazed  walls   and  works   relating   to   the   improvement   of   the   efficiency   of   a  heating  network,  

• the  insulation  of  a  part  or  all  of  an  asset  of  a  heating  network,  • the  purchase  of  heating  control  systems  or  other  equipment  to  a  heating  network.    

Page 45: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

45  

The  implementation  of  energy  efficiency  assessments  is  eligible  as  well.  

Lastly,  this  credit  can  only  cover  a  given  percentage  of  material  cost.    The  percentage  depends  on  the  equipment  purchase  as  listed  below  in  Figure  32:  

Figure  32  -­‐‑  Ceilings  by  type  of  equipment  purchased  for  the  French  credit  on  taxes  

The  combination  of  finance  credit  with  the  eco-­‐‑credit  is  possible,  but  this  finance  option  is  limited  to  2  years  and  available  only  for  low  income  households  with  an  income  of  less  than  45000€.  

 

5.4.7.2 Tax  exemptions  Tax   exemptions,   such   as   property   tax   exemption   and   tax   exemption   on   renewable   income   are  available  for  households  or  private  customers  with  micro  generation  on  site  and  the  properties  that  have  taken  up  some  energy  efficiency  improvement  works.  

Property  tax  

This  tax  is  the  one  any  landlord/owner  of  a  property  has  to  pay  every  year.  

Since  2007,  local  authorities  may  decrease  property  taxes  by  50%  or  exempt  landlords  from  paying  them.    

This   applies   to   properties   bought   before   1st   January   1989   for  which   the   owner   has   undertaken  refurbishment  works  improving  energy  efficiency.  Eligible  refurbishments  works  are  the  same  as  for  the  credit  on  taxes.  

Some  financial  conditions  apply:  the  total  amount  of  money  spent  the  year  before  exemption  has  to  be  over  10,000€  housing  or  the  total  amount  of  money  spent  the  last  3  years  before  exemption  has  to  be  over  15,000€.  

Tax  on  incomes  from  renewable  production  

The   finance   law   of   2008   applies   to   any   private   customer   producing   electricity   on   site.     It   is  applicable   to   photo   voltaic   installations   and  micro   turbines   etc.     This   law   exempts   the   need   to  declare  this  income  if  the  installed  power  capacity  does  not  exceed  3kWc.    

Equipment/Provision   %  of  material  cost  considered  as  “credit  on  finance  taxes”  

Generators  using  a  renewable  source  of  energy  other  than  solar  

45%  

Generators  using  solar  as  primary  energy   22%  Air/Water  Heat  Pumps  

 22%  

Geothermal  Heat  Pumps    

36%  

Solar  Thermal     45%  

Equipment  for  connection  to  a  heating  network   22%  Energetic  efficiency  assessment   45%  

Page 46: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

46  

5.5 UK  Energy  incentives    The  UK  is  committed  to  reducing  its  greenhouse  gas  emissions  by  at  least  80%  by  2050,  relative  to  1990   levels   as  well   as   other   interim   targets.     In   fact,   the  Climate  Change  Act   2008   established   a  legally  binding   target   to   reduce   the  UK’s  greenhouse  gas   emissions  by  at   least   this   figure,   to  be  achieved   through   action   at   home   and   abroad.     To  drive  progress   and   set   the  UK  on   a  pathway  towards  this  target,  the  Act  introduced  a  system  of  carbon  budgets  which  provide  legally  binding  limits  on  the  amount  of  emissions  that  may  be  produced  in  successive  five-­‐‑year  periods,  beginning  in  2008.    The  first   three  carbon  budgets  were  set   in   law  in  May  2009  and  require  emissions  to  be  reduced  by  at  least  34%  below  base  year  levels  in  2020.    Figure  33  below  sets  out  the  details  of  the  first  four  carbon  budgets.  

 First  carbon  budget  

(2008–12)  Second  carbon  

budget  (2013–17)  Third  carbon  

budget  (2018–22)  Fourth  carbon  

budget  (2023–27)  

Carbon  budget  level  (million  tonnes  carbon  dioxide  equivalent  (MtCO2e))    

3,018   2,782   2,544   1,950  

Percentage  reduction  below  base  year  levels    

23%   29%   35%   50%  

Figure  33  -­‐‑  UK  Carbon  Plan  Budgets:  2008-­‐‑2027  

Between   2010   and   2011   electricity   generation   from   renewable   sources   increased.     The   increase  amounted  to  around  one  third  -­‐‑  to  reach  34.4  TWh.    Capacity  grew  by  a  similar  proportion  (to  12.3  GW)  over   the   same  period   (DECC,   2012).     Figure   34   shows   the   capacity   of,   and   the   amounts   of  electricity   generated   from,   each   type   of   renewable   source.     Total   electricity   generation   from  renewables  in  2011  amounted  to  34,410  GWh,  an  increase  of  8,565  GWh  (plus  33%)  on  2010.    The  largest   absolute   increase   in   generation   came   from  onshore  wind,   rising   by   3,235  GWh   to   10,372  GWh  (a  45  per  cent  increase  on  the  previous  year),  reflecting  increased  installed  capacity  over  the  course  of  the  year  and  also  higher  average  wind  speeds.  

Page 47: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

47  

 

Figure  34  -­‐‑  Percentage  of  sources  renewable  energy  in  the  UK  

A  range  of  policy   instruments  are  being  used   to  encourage   the  meeting  of   these  greenhouse  gas  emission   targets   –  with   different   approaches   being   used   in   various   parts   of   the   economy.     The  following  incentives  related  to  electricity  generation  have  been  or  are  in  use  in  the  UK:  

1. Renewable  Obligation  Certificate  (ROC)  2. Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  3. Grants  

Other  policy  instruments  relating  to  transport  and  heat  (i.e.  the  renewable  heat  incentive  (RHI)  and  the  renewable  transport  fuel  obligation  (RTFO))  are  also  being  utilised.  

 

5.5.1 Renewable  Obligation  Certificates  (ROC)  The   renewable   obligation   (RO)   is   currently   the   main   financial   mechanism   by   which   the   UK  Government  incentivises  the  deployment  of  large-­‐‑scale  renewable  electricity  generation.    Support  is  granted  for  20  years,  which  balances  the  need  to  provide  investors  with  long-­‐‑term  certainty  with  the  need  to  keep  costs  to  consumers  to  a  minimum.  

Since  the  RO’s  introduction  in  2002,  it  has  succeeded  in  supporting  the  deployment  of  increasing  amounts  of  renewables  generation  from  3.1GW  in  2002  to  8GW  in  2009  and  more  than  tripling  the  level  of   renewable  electricity   in   the  UK  from  1.8%   in  2002   to  6.6%   in  2010.     It   is   currently  worth  around  £1.3  billion  a  year  in  support  to  the  renewable  electricity  industry.  

In  April  2010,  the  end  date  of  the  RO  was  extended  from  2027  to  2037  for  new  projects  to  provide  long-­‐‑term  certainty   for   investors  and  to  ensure  continued  deployment  of  renewables   to  meet   the  UK’s  2020  target  and  beyond.  

Page 48: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

48  

The  RO  places  a  mandatory  requirement  on  licensed  UK  electricity  suppliers  to  source  a  specified  and  annually  increasing  proportion  of  electricity  they  supply  to  customers  from  eligible  renewable  sources  or  pay  a  penalty.    The  scheme  is  administered  by  the  energy  regulator,  Ofgem,  who  issues  Renewables  Obligation  Certificates  (ROCs)  to  renewable  electricity  generators  for  every  megawatt  hour   (MWh)   of   eligible   renewable   electricity   they   generate.     Generators   sell   their   ROCs   to  suppliers   or   traders   which   allows   them   to   receive   a   premium   in   addition   to   the   wholesale  electricity  price.  

Suppliers   present   ROCs   to  Ofgem   to   demonstrate   their   compliance  with   the   obligation.    Where  they  do  not  present  sufficient  ROCs,  suppliers  have  to  pay  a  penalty  known  as  the  buy-­‐‑out  price.    This   is   set   at   £40.71  per  ROC   for   2012/13   (this   is   linked   to   changes   in   retail  prices).     The  money  collected  by  Ofgem  in  the  buy-­‐‑out  fund  is  recycled  on  a  pro-­‐‑rata  basis  to  suppliers  who  presented  ROCs.  Suppliers  that  do  not  present  ROCs  pay  into  the  buy-­‐‑out  fund  at  the  buy-­‐‑out  price,  but  do  not  receive  any  portion  of  the  recycled  fund.  

Thus,   a   ROC   is   a   green   certificate   issued   to   an   accredited   generator   for   eligible   renewable  electricity   generated   within   the   UK   and   supplied   to   customers   within   the   UK   by   a   licensed  electricity   supplier.     The   number   of   ROCs   issued   for   each   megawatt   hour   (MWh)   of   eligible  renewable  output  generated  depends  on  the  generating  technology.  

This  is  illustrated  in  the  diagram  below  which  shows    

1) Generators  providing  renewable  generation  output  information  to  Ofgem  2) Ofgem  issuing  ROC’s  in  respect  of  the  generation  reported  in  1)  3) Generators  sell  ROC’s  to  electricity  Suppliers  4) Suppliers  present  ROC’s  or  payment  -­‐‑  the  buy-­‐‑out  (where  they  have  insufficient  ROC’s)  to  

fulfil  the  obligation.  

 

Figure  35  –  UK  Renewable  Obligation:  ROC  flows  

Page 49: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

49  

5.5.1.1 Supported  level  ROCs  are  intended  to  create  a  market,  and  be  traded  at  market  prices  that  differ  from  the  official  buy-­‐‑out  price.     If   there   is  an  excess  of  renewable  production,  beyond  the  supplier  obligation,   the  price  of  ROCs  would  fall  below  the  buy-­‐‑out  price.    If  there  is  less  renewable  production  than  the  obligation,   the   price   of   ROCs  would   increase   above   the   buy-­‐‑out   price,   as   purchasers   anticipate  later  payments  from  the  buy-­‐‑out  fund  on  each  ROC.  

Obligation   periods   run   for   one   year,   beginning   on   1   April   and   running   to   31   March.     Supply  companies  have  until   the   31  September   following   the  period   to   submit   sufficient  ROCs   to   cover  their  obligation,  or  to  submit  sufficient  payment  to  the  buy-­‐‑out  fund  to  cover  the  shortfall.    Figure  4  below  shows  the  percentage  of  the  amount  that  they  supply  that  electricity  suppliers  are  required  to  source  from  renewable  generation  and  the  buy-­‐‑out  price  to  be  paid  for  any  of  this  which  is  not  achieved  for  the  period  from  2002/03  to  2012/13.  

 

Figure  36  -­‐‑  UK  Renewable  Obligation:  Percentage  of  supply  and  buy-­‐‑out  price  –  2002/03  to  2012/13  

 

5.5.1.2 Bands  of  support:  Technology  When  the  renewable  obligation  was  first  introduced  in  2002  there  was  no  differentiation  between  the   renewable   generation   technologies   used   to   generate   electricity,   qualify   for   ROC’s,   and   thus  fulfil  the  renewable  obligation.    However  in  2009  bands  of  support  were  introduced  which  allowed  the  RO   to   offer   varied   support   levels   by   technology.     The  UK  Government   indicated   that   these  bands  would  be  set  for  four  years  and  then  reviewed.    The  decisions  resulting  from  the  first  review  of  these  bands  which  are  for  implementation  in  April  2013  for  the  following  four  year  period  until  2017  have  recently  been  announced.    

The  Government   stated  during   the   recently   completed   consultation  process   that   its   aims   for   the  banding  review  were  to:    

• Ensure  that  support  levels  under  the  RO  will  support  renewables  growth  to  help  meet  our  2020  and  interim  renewables  target  

• Drive  greater  value  for  money  in  the  operation  and  support  levels  set  under  the  RO  

Page 50: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

50  

• Support  technologies  with  the  potential  for  mass  deployment  • Ensure  coordination  with  other  Government  financial  incentive  schemes  • Contribute   to   the   effective   delivery   of   wider   energy   and   climate   change   goals   to   2050,  

including   greenhouse   gas   emissions   reductions,   decarbonising   the   energy   sector   and  ensuring  energy  security.    

This  review  was  broad  and  complex  and  is  publicly  available.    The  detailed  proposals  seem  aimed  at   limiting   costs   to   customers,   focusing   support   where   it   is   needed  most,   and   recognising   that  certain  technologies  are  likely  to  become  economic  and  self  sustainable.  

The  position  regarding  two  of  the  technologies  is  reported  below.      

However  firstly   it  may  be  worth  outlining  in  a   little  more  detail  how  the  technology  banded  RO  works.    In  brief,  each  MWh  of  electricity  generated  by  a  renewable  generator  qualifies  for  a  certain  number  of  ROC’s  depending  on  the  technology.    Thus  in  the  period  2009  to  2013  this  support  level  generally   fell   in   the  range  0.25   to   two.    Specifically   for  onshore  wind   the   figure  was  one  and  for  solar  PV   it  was   two   i.e.  each  MWh  of  electricity  generated   from  on-­‐‑shore  wind  qualified   for  one  ROC  whereas  each  MWh  of  electricity  generated  from  solar  PV  qualified  for  two  ROCs.  

 

Solar  Photovoltaics  (PV)  

The   UK   government’s   initial   proposals   -­‐‑   that   it   publicly   consulted   on   -­‐‑   were   to   maintain   the  support  level  at  two  ROCs  per  MWh  for  2013/14  and  2014/15  and  then  to  decrease  this  to  1.9  and  1.8  ROCs  per  MWh  for  2015/16  and  2016/17  respectively.  

However   in   its   recently   published   (July   2012)   decision   document   these   have   been   substantially  amended.    Despite   arguments   from   industry   that   further   support  was   required   the  Government  has  concluded  that   its  aim  is   to  encourage  cost-­‐‑effective  deployment  of  solar  PV  through  the  RO  but  that  costs  had  continued  to  fall  dramatically  since  the  original  consultation  was  published  and  new   evidence   has   become   available   which   indicates   that   the   level   of   support   proposed   in   the  consultation  would  substantially  over-­‐‑reward  this  technology.    

Analysis   of   the   new   evidence   by   the   government   suggests   that   RO   support   rates   should   be   set  significantly   lower   than  was  proposed   in   the   consultation.    Because   such  a   reduction   in   support  would   represent   a   significant   departure   from   the   consultation   proposals   and   would   be   based  largely   on   new   evidence   it   has   been   considered   appropriate   to   re-­‐‑consult   on   the   issue.     Thus   a  consultation   will   shortly   be   published   on   proposals   for   reduced   ROC   support   for   solar   PV  generating  stations  which  accredit  or  add  additional  capacity  on  or  after  1  April  2013.    

 

Onshore  wind  

Page 51: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

51  

The   support   level   for   onshore  wind  will   be   reduced   from   one   ROC   per  MWh   to   0.9   ROCs   per  MWh  for  2013/14  onwards.    In  addition  a  further  call  for  evidence  is  to  be  made  which  could  lead  to  a  further  reduction  later  in  the  period.  

 

5.5.2 Feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  This  instrument  fits  into  the  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  category  outlined  in  Section  2  above.  

The  Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  (FITs)  scheme  was  introduced  on  1  April  2010,  under  powers  in  the  UK  Energy  Act   2008.     Through   the   use   of   FITs,   the   UK   government   hopes   to   encourage   deployment   of  additional   small-­‐‑scale   (less   than   5MW)   low-­‐‑carbon   electricity   generation,   particularly   by  organisations,  businesses,  communities  and  individuals  that  have  not  traditionally  engaged  in  the  electricity  market.  

This   will   allow   many   people   to   invest   in   small-­‐‑scale   low-­‐‑carbon   electricity,   in   return   for   a  guaranteed   payment   from   an   electricity   supplier   of   their   choice   for   the   electricity   they   generate  and  use   as  well   as   a   guaranteed  payment   for  unused   surplus   electricity   they   export   back   to   the  grid.  

5.5.2.1 Technologies  supported  Small-­‐‑scale  low-­‐‑carbon  electricity  technologies  eligible  for  FITs  are:  

• wind    • solar  photovoltaics  (PV)    • hydro    • anaerobic  digestion    • domestic   scale   microCHP   (with   a   capacity   of   2kW   or   less)   –   although   this   is   subject   to  

review  as  the  volume  of  installations  increase.    

5.5.2.2 Supported  level  There  are  three  financial  benefits  for  the  small-­‐‑scale  generator  from  FITs:  

• Generation   tariff   –   the   electricity   supplier   of   the   generators   choice  will   pay   for   each  unit  (kilowatt)  of  electricity  generated  throughout  the  lifetime  of  the  installation’s  eligibility  for  FITs  payments.  

• Export  tariff  –  if  electricity  is  generated  that  is  not  used  by  the  generator  it  can  be  exported  to  the  grid  for  an  additional  payment  (on  top  of  the  generation  tariff)    

• Energy  bill  savings  –  not  as  much  electricity  will  need  to  be  imported  from  your  supplier  because   a   proportion   of   what   has   been   used  will   have   generated   by   the   generator   thus  reducing  the  electricity  bill.      

The   Feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   are   adjusted   annually   for   retail   inflation   by   being   linked   to   the   Retail   Price  Index  (RPI).    

Page 52: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

52  

The   Feed-­‐‑in   tariffs   are   adjusted   annually   for   retail   inflation   by   being   linked   to   the   Retail   Price  Index  (RPI).    DECC  have  released  the  results  of   their   latest  PV  Feed-­‐‑in  Tariff  consultation  which    will  introduce  new  lower  rates  for  installations  from  1st  August  2012  (See  Figure  37).  

 

Figure  37  -­‐‑  New  PV  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  from  1st  of  August  2012  

 

5.5.2.3 Cost  of  metering  The  payment  of  export  tariffs  is  based  on  either  metered  or  estimated  quantities.  At  the  start  of  the  FITs  scheme  it  was  made  clear  that  payment  of  export  tariffs  based  on  deemed  or  estimated  values  was  an  interim  measure  and  that  all  FITs  payments  should  where  possible  be  made  on  the  basis  of  accurately  metered  electricity  flows.  However,  the  cost  of  metering  and  registering  small  quantities  of   electricity   in   the   electricity  market   systems  makes   this   uneconomic   at   present   at   the   smallest  scale  (up  to  30  kW).  This  is  expected  to  change  with  the  rollout  of  smart  meters,  but  not  therefore  in   the   immediate   future.   The   amount   of   electricity   that   is   deemed   to   be   exported   by   different  categories  of  accredited  FITs  installations  with  a  total  installed  capacity  of  up  to  30  kW  that  is  not  measured  by  export  meters  is  determined  annually  by  the  Secretary  of  State.    

This  is  currently  estimated  to  be  50%  for  small  scale  PV  generators.  

 

5.5.3 Grants  Whilst   the   UK   previously   had   a   number   of   schemes   which   provided   grants   for   renewable  generation,  particularly  PV,  these  have  now  substantially  been  replaced  by  Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  and  the  renewable  heat  incentive.      

 

5.5.4 Renewable  Heat  Incentive  (RHI)  • The  RHI’s  objective  is  to  increase  significantly  the  level  of  renewable  heat;  • Non-­‐‑domestic   sectors   will   be   have   an   RHI   tariff   from   the   outset   –   the   industrial   and  

commercial  sectors;  the  public  sector,  not-­‐‑for-­‐‑profit  organisations  and  communities;  

Page 53: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

53  

• RHI  Premium  Payments  will  be  available  in  2011  and  RHI  tariffs  will  be  introduced  from  2012  alongside  the  Green  Deal  for  homes.    

• Ofgem  will  administer  the  RHI  tariff  scheme;  and    • Owners  of  eligible  installations  for  the  RHI  tariff  scheme  to  apply  to  Ofgem  for  support.  

5.5.4.1 Technologies  supported  Biomass,   solar   thermal,   heat-­‐‑pumps,   on-­‐‑site   biogas,   deep   geothermal,   energy   from   waste   and  injection  of  biomethane  into  the  gas  grid;  

5.5.4.2 Supported  level  • RHI   tariff   levels   have   been   designed   to   bring   forward   a   wide   range   of   renewable   heat  

technologies,   including   heat   pumps,   solar   thermal   and   various   types   of   bio-­‐‑heat   such   as  biomass  and  biomethane;  

• The  RHI   focuses   on   cost-­‐‑effective   technologies   and   fuels   such   as   large-­‐‑scale   industrial   or  commercial  installations  using  biomass;  

• The  principle  for  setting  the  tariffs  has  been  to  base  them  on  the  costs  of  each  technology  plus  providing  a  return  on  capital,   in  order   to  provide  sufficient  support  but  at   the  same  time  avoid  over-­‐‑subsidising;  and  

• Compensation   is  provided  only   for  additional   costs  of   renewable   technologies  over   fossil  fuel  heating.  

Payments  will   be   calculated  by  multiplying   the   appropriate   tariff   (depending  on   the   technology  and  size  of   the   installation)  by   the  eligible  heat  use.  The  eligible  heat  use  will  be  metered  actual  generation  or  use.  

Page 54: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

54  

 

Figure  38  –  UK  Renewable  Heat  Incentive  (RHI):  Levels  of  Support  [9]  

 

5.5.5 Renewable  Transport  Fuel  Obligation  (RTFO)    The   Renewable   Transport   Fuel   Obligation   (RTFO)   in   the   United   Kingdom   is   a   requirement   on  transport   fuel   suppliers   to   ensure   that   5   percent   of   all   road   vehicle   fuel   is   supplied   is   from  sustainable  renewable  sources  by  2010.  The  Government  intends  to  set  variable  targets  for  the  level  of   carbon   and   sustainability   performance   expected   from   all   transport   fuel   suppliers   claiming  certificates  for  biofuels  in  the  early  years  of  the  RTFO.  

The   RTFO  will   help   bring   the  UK   into   line  with   European  Union   biofuels   directive,  which   sets  targets   for   all  EU  countries   for  biofuel  usage  of   2%  by   the   end  of   2005  and  5.75%  by   the   end  of  2010.  

The   RTFO  will   be   implemented   through   a   certification   scheme   administered   by   the   Renewable  Fuels  Agency.  Companies  certified  as  having  sold  more  than  the  5%  obligation  will  be  able  to  sell  their  certificates  for  the  excess  to  those  who  sold  less.  

 

   

Page 55: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

55  

5.6 European  Union  (EU)  Renewable  Generation  Incentives  and  Policy  Instruments  

 

The  EU  Directive  2009/28/EC  on  the  promotion  of  the  use  of  energy  from  renewable  sources  (RES)  sets   an   overall   target   to   reach   20%   of   gross   final   energy   consumption   being   produced   from  renewable  sources  by  2020.    

Figure  39  below  provides  an  overview  of  the  renewable  electricity  support  instruments  that  are  in  place  in  the  EU  Member  States.    As  outlined  in  Section  2  six  categories  of  support  instruments  have  been  identified  as  follows:-­‐‑  

• feed-­‐‑in  tariff;    • premium;    • quota  obligation;    • investment  grants;  • tax  exemptions;  and    • fiscal  incentives.    

Country   FIT   Premium   Quota  obligation  

Investment  grants  

Tax  exemptions  

Fiscal  incentives  

AT   x            BE   x    

x   x   x    BG   x  

   x  

 x  

CY   x      

x      CZ   x   x  

       DE   x          

x  DK  

 x  

       EE   x   x        

x  ES   x   x  

   x  

 FI        

x   x    FR   x  

         GR   x      

x   x    HU   x  

   x  

   IE   x            IT   x    

x        LT   x  

   x  

   LU   x      

x      LV   x  

   x   x  

 MT   x      

x    

x  NL  

 x  

   x   x  

PL      

x    

x   x  PT   x  

         RO      

x        SE  

   x  

 x  

 

Page 56: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

56  

Country   FIT   Premium   Quota  obligation  

Investment  grants  

Tax  exemptions  

Fiscal  incentives  

SI   x   x        

x  SK   x  

     x  

 UK   x    

x    

x    Figure  39  -­‐‑  An  overview  of  the  renewable  electricity  support  instruments  that  are  in  place  in  EU  Member  States.  

Source:  [7].  

 

5.6.1 Feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  (FITs)  FITs   are   currently   in  use   in  many  EU  countries.     Prices   are   in  Euros  per  kilowatt-­‐‑hour   (€/kWh).    'ʹ0.29-­‐‑0.46'ʹ   is   a  price   range   from  0.29   €/kWh   to   0.46   €/kWh,  depending  on   the   amount  produced.  Figure  40  below  provides  feed-­‐‑in  tariffs  by  EU  country  and  technology  (prices  valid  for  April  1st,  2010).  

Member  state   Windpower  'On-­‐shore'    

Wind  power  'Off-­‐shore'    

Solar  PV   Biomass   Hydro  

Austria   0.073   0.073   0.29  -­‐  0.46   0.06  -­‐0.16   n/a  Belgium   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a  Bulgaria   0.07  -­‐  0.09   0.07  -­‐  0.09   0.34  -­‐  0.38   0.08  -­‐  0.10   0.045  Cyprus   0.166   0.166   0.34   0.135   n/a  Czech  Republic   0.108   0.108   0.455   0.077  -­‐  

0.103  0.081  

Denmark   0.035   n/a   n/a   0.039   n/a  • Estonia   0.051   0.051   0.051   0.051   0.051  

Finland   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a  France   0.082   0.31  -­‐  0.58   n/a   0.125   0.06  Germany   0.05  -­‐  0.09   0.13  -­‐  0.15   0.29  -­‐  0.55   0.08  -­‐  0.12   0.04  -­‐  

0.13  Greece   0.07  -­‐  0.09   0.07  -­‐  0.09   0.55   0.07  -­‐  0.08   0.07  -­‐  

0.08  Hungary   n/a   n/a   0.097   n/a   0.029  -­‐  

0.052  Ireland   0.059   0.059   n/a   0.072   0.072  Italy   0.3   0.3   0.36  -­‐  0.44   0.2  -­‐  0.3   0.22  Latvia   0.11   0.11   n/a   n/a   n/a  Lithuania   0.1   0.1   n/a   0.08   0.07  Luxembourg   0.08  -­‐  0.10   0.08  -­‐  0.10   0.28  -­‐  0.56   0.103  -­‐  

0.128  0.079  -­‐  0.103  

Malta   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a  Netherlands   0.118   0.186   0.459  -­‐  

0.583  0.115  -­‐  0.177  

0.073  -­‐  0.125  

Poland   n/a   n/a   n/a   0.038   n/a  Portugal   0.074   0.074   0.31  -­‐  0.45   0.1  -­‐  0.11   0.075  Romania   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a  Slovakia   0.05-­‐  0.09   0.05-­‐  0.09   0.27   0.072  -­‐  

0.10  0.066  -­‐  0.10  

Slovenia   0.087  -­‐  0.094  

0.087  -­‐  0.095   0.267  -­‐  0.414  

0.074  -­‐  0.224  

0.077  -­‐  0.105  

Page 57: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

57  

Member  state   Windpower  'On-­‐shore'    

Wind  power  'Off-­‐shore'    

Solar  PV   Biomass   Hydro  

Spain   0.073   0.073   0.32  -­‐  0.34   0.107  -­‐  0.158  

0.077  

Sweden   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a   n/a  United  Kingdom   0.31   n/a   0.42   0.12   0.23  

Figure  40  –  Feed-­‐‑in  Tariffs  by  EU  country  and  technology  (April  2010)  [8]  

 

5.6.2 Feed-­‐‑in  Premium  system  Premium   systems  provide   a   secure   additional   return   for   producers,  while   exposing   them   to   the  electricity  price   risk.    Compared   to   feed-­‐‑in   tariffs,   premiums  provide   less   certainty   for   investors  and   hence,   imply   higher   risk   premiums   and   total   costs   of   capital.     There   are   different   design  options   for   premium   systems.     Premiums   that   are   linked   to   electricity   price   developments,   e.g.  limited  by  cap  and  floor  prices,  provide  higher  certainty  and  less  risk  of  over-­‐‑compensation  than  fixed  premiums.      

5.6.3 Renewable  or  quota  obligations  As   previously   explained,   in   this   case   governments   impose   minimum   shares   of   renewable  electricity  on   suppliers   (or   consumers  and  producers)   that   increase  over   time.     If   obligations  are  not  met,  financial  penalties  are  to  be  paid.    Penalties  are  recycled  back  to  suppliers  in  proportion  to  how  much   renewable   electricity   they   have   supplied.    Obligations   are   combined  with   renewable  obligation  certificates  (ROCs)  that  can  be  traded.    Hence,  ROCs  provide  support  in  addition  to  the  electricity   price   and   used   as   proof   of   compliance.     A   ROC   represents   the   value   of   renewable  electricity  and  facilitates  trade  in  the  green  property  of  electricity.      

An  advantage  of  quota  obligations  compared  to  feed-­‐‑in  tariff  and  premium  systems,  is  the  fact  that  support   is   automatically   phased   out   once   the   technology   manages   to   compete.     Tradable  certificates   represent   the   value   of   the   renewable   electricity   at   a   certain   time.    When   the   costs   of  renewable  technologies  come  down  through  learning,  this  is  represented  by  the  adjustment  of  the  price  of  certificates.    On  the  other  hand,  this  might  be  a  challenge  for  plants  already  in  operation  that  did  not  profit  from  this  technological  learning.    Furthermore,  certificate  prices  are  volatile  to  other  market  influences  (e.g.  exercise  of  market  power).      

 

5.6.4 Investments  grants  Investment  grants  are  sometimes  available  and  are  often  devised  to  stimulate   the   take-­‐‑up  of   less  mature  technologies  such  as  photo-­‐‑voltaics.  

 

5.6.5 Tax  incentives  or  exemptions  Again,   as   previously   mentioned,   some   countries   provide   tax   incentives   related   to   investments  (including   income   tax  deductions   or   credits   for   some   fraction  of   the   capital   investment  made   in  

Page 58: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

58  

renewable   energy   projects,   or   accelerated   depreciation).     Some   other   countries   have   devised  production   tax   incentives   that   provide   income   tax   deduction   or   credits   at   a   set   rate   per   unit   of  produced  renewable  electricity,  thereby  reducing  operational  costs.    

 

5.6.6 Fiscal  incentives  Fiscal  incentives  including  soft  –  or  low-­‐‑interest  loans  that  are  loans  with  a  rate  below  the  market  rate   of   interest.   Soft   loans   may   also   provide   other   concessions   to   borrowers,   including   longer  repayment  periods  or  interest  holidays.    

 

5.6.7 Tender  These   are   sometimes   used   for   larger-­‐‑scale   projects   and   most   commonly   for   offshore   wind.   Its  advantages   include   the   amount   of   attention   it   draws   towards   renewable   energy   investment  opportunities   and   the   competitive   element   incorporated   in   its   design.   Its   handicap   is   that   the  overall  number  of  projects  actually  implemented  so  far  has  proven  to  be  very  low.      

   

Page 59: DeliverableD2.2’ “Impacts,constraints,objectivesand ... · 9’ ’ 3 Environmental,social-and-economic-impacts-Each plan has’ environmental,’ social’ and economic’ impacts.’To’

59  

6 References    

[1] Paolo  Cagnoli.  VAS  valutazione  ambientale  strategica.  Dario  Flaccovio,  2010.  [2] Jens  C.  Sorensen  and  Mitchell  L.  Moss.  Procedures  and  programs  to  assist  in  the  impact  

statement  process.  Technical  report,  Univ.  of  California,  Berkely,  1973.  [3] RAMEA  Project  web  site:  http://www.arpa.emr.it/ramea/  [4] Programma  Operativo  Regionale,  Emilia  Romagna  :http://www.regione.emilia-­‐‑

romagna.it/temi/imprese/programma-­‐‑operativo-­‐‑regionale-­‐‑fesr-­‐‑2007-­‐‑2013  [5] Programma  Operativo  Regionale,  Abruzzo:  

http://www.regione.abruzzo.it/xeuropa/index.asp?modello=porPresentazione&servizio=xList&stileDiv=monoLeft&template=porFesrIntIndex&b=progfesr1  

[6] Programma  Operativo  Regionale,  Campania:  http://porfesr.regione.campania.it/opencms/opencms/FESR/  

[7] http://ec.europa.eu/energy/renewables/studies/doc/renewables/2011_financing_renewable.pdf  

[8] http://www.energy.eu/  [9] http://www.decc.gov.uk