Delien Hans

download Delien Hans

of 21

Transcript of Delien Hans

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    1/21

    CHAPTER 2

    SAVINGS AND RURAL DEPOSIT MOBILIZATION

    The objective of this chapter is to develope a conceptual framework to analyze determinants of

    rural deposit mobilization. The chapter is divided into five parts. The first part reviews the role of

    finance in economic development, and it surveys traditional views regarding rural financial markets.

    The second part focuses on the importance of financial intermediation for the economy as a whole and

    on the importance of deposits for financial markets, and it evaluates past policy designs and their

    impact on financial markets. The fourth part analyzes the problems in achieving a cost-effective

    deposits mobilization in less-developed regions and risky environments, and it reviews the efforts to

    improve the regulatory framework needed to achieve safe deposit taking. The fifth part examines the

    determinants of deposit mobilization, and it highlights theories of savings behavior for credit

    constrained households in developing countries.

    2.1 Finance and Economic Development

    Finance plays a vital role in economic development. Since the late 1950s several authors

    already underscored the role of finance in economic development (Tobin, 1965, Patrick, 1966, Gurley

    and Shaw, 1967). It was not until the publication of the work of McKinnon and Shaw argued that

    financial repression for a small size of the financial sector, for keeping the rates of return on money too

    low, and for inhibiting economic growth. Financial repression results mainly from four kinds of direct

    controls :

    (a) the control of aggregate bank liquidity and credit,

    (b) the control of interest rates,

    (c) qualitative controls of band credit,

    (d) foreign exchange controls.

    These controls distort financial prices and reduce the real size of the financial system.

    Strategies of financial repression gravely retarded economic development in many countries.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    2/21

    Techniques of financial repression have included low and even negative lending interest rates,

    high reserve requirements, the use of selective credit policies through specialized financial institutions,

    and controls that result in high intermediation costs (Fry, 1981)

    The dependency of rural financial markets on cheap funds through rediscount mechanisms

    discourages intermediaries from aggressively mobilizing rural deposits (Vogel, 1980, Adams, 1984).In the absence of attractive deposit services, most of the accumulated rural savings are dept in non-

    financial forms (e.g, gold, land), or are invested in assets generating low marginal rates of return

    (Gonzalez-Vega, 1985).

    Efficient rural financial markets draw resources from unproductive investments, particularly

    inflation hedges, by offering positive real rates of interest on deposits (Vogel, 1984 ; Bhatt and

    Meerman, 1978). In turn, rural financial markets allocate these command over resources toward the

    most productive investments.

    2.2 Importance of Financial Intermediation

    Surplus units posses a comparatively ample endowment of own resources which, when applied

    to their own productive opportunities, render low marginal rates of return. Deficit units possess few

    resources in comparison to their productive opportunities and as a result their marginal rates of return

    are relatively high. Surplus units have comparatively more resources than opportunities, while the

    opposite is true for deficit units. In general, differences in marginal rates of return are a signal of

    opportunities to increase the efficiency of resource allocation in the economy (Gonzalez-Vega, 1984)

    Direct financing (transactions between surplus units may charge interest rates higher than the

    marginal rates of return they would obtain from alternative investments. In turn, the inflow of

    resources allows deficit units to engage in projects with marginal rates of return high enough to pay the

    principal and rate of interest on the loan.

    Although direct finance improves the welfare of both types of units, the process is costly.

    Double coincidence of interests is necessary to close the transaction: surplus and deficit units must

    agree on loan size, maturity and interest rate. When they have limited information about each other,

    transaction costs are bid up. Because of the high transaction costs involved, many surplus and deficit

    units may be unwilling to participate in financial markets, which narrows the scope of direct financing.

    In contrast, indirect financing allows financial transactions between surplus and deficit units

    through specialized intermediaries such as banks. Hanks provide deposit facilities to surplus units

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    3/21

    which are more attractive than the alternative investment opportunities they may posses. Intermediaries

    also offer more flexible terms and conditions to borrowers than individual surplus units do.

    Informal or non-institutional forms of direct financing preceded formal indirect financing

    through the banking system. In effect, moneylending activities have taken placed for centuries in risky

    environments. In most cultures , however, moneylenders have been characterized as evil. This biasagainst money lenders has influenced the authorities in attempts to reduce the range of action of

    moneylenders, especially in rural areas.

    In the 1980s, the criticism against moneylenders was challenged on the grounds that :

    (a) there is free entry and exit into money lending activities and, therefore, monopoly

    profits are likely to be eroded away by newcomers,

    (b) the interest rates changed usually reflect the opportunity cost of money,

    (c) interest rates incorporate lender transaction costs and a premium for risk, and

    (d) policymakers have ignored that consumption purposes, such as weddings and illness,

    can also explain the demand for loans ( Bottomly, 1983, and Singh, 1983)

    Moneylenders have satisfied many demands for loans of the population has also found informal

    alternative forms of holding accumulated savings (livestock, inventories, jewelry) or informal

    arrangements such as savings clubs, cooperatives or rotating savings

    agreements, which have been present to fulfill many of their demands. Informal markets,

    however, have also left many demands for financial services unsatisfied (Gonzalez-Vega and Graham,

    1995)

    In attempts to displace the moneylenders, development finance efforts had focused almost

    exclusively on the provision of credit. During the past decade, however, the introduction of deposit

    facilities tailored to the requirements of small savers has become an important topic in development

    finance. Deposit mobilization was called the forgotten half of financial development, due to the almost

    exclusive prior attention to credit (Vogel, 1984)

    The new view has emphasized the social and private benefits of deposits. Social gains arise

    from the reallocation of resources for investment, transferring them from relatively low-return uses to

    high-return alternatives through financial intermediaries. The improvement of resource allocation

    reduces the dispersion of marginal rates of return in the economy (McKinnon, 1973). Private gains are

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    4/21

    enjoyed by depositors, borrowers, and financial intermediaries. Depositors may find in financial assets

    safer, more liquid, and profitable forms to store wealth. Their risks are reduced and their earnings

    increased by access to deposit facilities. Borrowers benefit from the expanded availability of loanable

    funds for investment projects and from lower transaction costs.

    Intermediaries also benefit from deposit mobilization. First, deposits represent a more stablesource of funds for intermediaries than reliance on loans from the government or donor funds. Hence,

    independence in the formulation of credit policies and less donor and government intervention are

    possible. Second, deposit services reduce risks of adverse selection and of default, due to valuable

    information obtained through the deposit behavior of the clients. Finally, the combination of credit

    and deposit activities may generate economies of scope for the intermediary as well as for the clients.

    2.3 Faulty Assumptions and Rural Development Policies

    Traditionally, the complexity of the rural sector in developing countries was ignored or

    underestimated. Faulty assumptions underpinned the views that :

    (a) only the activities of farmers are important and need to be promoted,

    (b) farmers are so poor that they are not able to save, and

    (c) farmers are inefficient in the allocation of their resources, due to lack of knowledge and

    the use of traditional techniques.

    These beliefs have been challenged by many authors. Meyer and Alicbusan (1984), for

    instance, mentioned at least four sources of heterogeneity which contour the complexity of the rural

    sector :

    (a) the wide range of economic activities in which farmers and non-farmers are engaged,

    (b) differences among farmers in both access to resources and investment opportunities.

    (c) different patterns of cash flows that lead to continuous shifts from a deficit position to a

    surplus position, and

    (d) differences in family life cycles.

    As a result of this heterogeneity among farmers, credit and savings activities in rural areas are

    common and have a long history. Many authors have documented informal arrangements in rural

    areas. Adams (1983), for instance, documented rotating savings and credit associations in Asia and

    Latin America. Bouman (1983) and Holst (1985) reported ablut indigenous banks, credit societies, and

    rotating savings. Several studies reported in Adams and Fitchet (1992) and in Bouman and Hospes

    (1994) further documents these activities.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    5/21

    The traditional view of rural finance led to policies that reduced the viability of financial

    institutions ad retarded deposit mobilization efforts. Adams (1985) argues that because of the flows of

    cheap refinance and rediscount funds, bank managers pay less attention to deposit mobilization. Cheap

    credit forces bankers to offer low interest rates on deposits, which in turn discourages depositors.

    2.4 Costs of Deposit Mobilization

    Schmidt and Zeitinger (1994) summarized the importance of deposit services and deposit

    mobilization, First, financial intermediaries provide deposit facilities to the relevant target group (e.g,

    the poor) and mobilize funds that they employ in their lending business. Deposit mobilization enables

    financial institutions to lend without being overly dependent on foreign financing and on money

    creation by the central bank. Second, there is a demand for deposit facilities in any economy. In strict

    contrast to what many experts long believed, poor people demand deposit facilities. If there is an

    institution accessible to them, such as development banks, the empirical evidence suggests that

    deposits can be mobilized. Third, financial institutions that have no access to other sources of funds,

    because they are not integrated to the financial system of the country and thus cannot borrow from

    other institutions, have to mobilize deposits in order to undertake their lending activities.

    Schmidt and Zeitinger (1994) raised several questions, however, about the importance that all

    financial institutions must at all times provide to the target grout deposit facilities and mobilize the

    bulk of the funds for their lending business from depositors (p.86). The first argument these authors

    raise is that the target group of small entrepreneurs already have more easy access to deposits facilities

    than they have to credit services. Thus, when one looks at the demand side, there is less justification to

    develop deposit facilities designed for the target group than there is for promoting credit services for

    small and micro entrepreneurs. If there are other institutions in the financial system that already

    provide adequate deposit facilities, this may be a good reason for an institution specialized in lending

    activities for the poor to focus on this mission.

    The second question raised by these authors is how important is the mobilization of deposits

    from the target group of the poor for the operations of specialized financial institutions. Will deposit

    mobilization enable the institution to become self-sufficient and achieve significant growth ? More

    important, how expensive is it to mobilize deposits ? These questions do not have easy answers.

    Schmidt and Zeitiger (1994) consider the arguments of positive synergies between credit and

    deposit businesses, which presumably improve borrower willingness to repay, unconvincing in the

    case of poor clientele. Further, the assumed moral and political obligation of development finance

    institutions to instill a spirit of prudence into their poor customers is considered as inappropriate.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    6/21

    The argument that deposits should be offered because there is a genuine demand for such

    services is valid, but the deposit mobilization experiences analyzed by the authors (BancoSol, Bolivia ;

    Cajas Municipales, Peru; and BKK, Indonesia) indicate that deposit mobilization is an extremely

    expensive undertaking. Lepp (1994) reached also similar results. Therefore, it is important to consider

    in each individual case whether there are other financial institutions in the domestic financial systemthat could provide this service to the target group. This is frequently the case, at least in urban areas.

    The authors find the concept of an inter-sector full-service bank more reasonable from an

    economic point of view than the intra-sector full-service bank concept. Intra-sector banks are

    institutions that mobilize deposits from and lend to the same target groups (g. g, the poor). In contrast,

    inter-sector banks attract depositors from some sector (the middle class) to lend to another sector (the

    poor). The deposit-taking institution, however, incurs high costs of funds when mobilizing deposits

    form middle and low-income savers. Not only must it pay high interest rates on deposits and incur in

    considerable administrative costs, but the institution must also offer a broader diversity of financial

    products such as credit cards, currents accounts, and other services to meet the demands from the new

    clientele. This could ultimately induce a gradual shift away form its target group (the poor)

    Schmidt and Zeitinger (1994) also show that an important proportion of the deposits in the

    microfinance institutions studied came from a few medium-size depositors and from big institutional

    depositors, which combined held more than 60 percent of the deposit volume. These clients usually

    prefer short-term time deposits rather than long-term time deposit contracts. This might have adverse

    consequences on the institution, because of the high volatility that such deposits tend to exhibit,

    creating a high degree of liquidity risk.

    Thus, the inter-sector full-service bank concept proves difficult to implement in an

    economically-sound basis in the case of microfinance. The question raised by the authors is, therefore,

    why an intermediary which is specialized in lending operations for the poor and which is already

    attempting to develop a market that is difficult and expensive to serve should be expected to deliver

    deposit facilities also, which are difficult and extremely expensive to provide and which can endanger

    the successful efforts on the lending side ?

    2.5 Some Principles of Prudential Supervision in Microfinance Programs

    The expansion of the supply of deposit facilities by several microfinance institutions in Latin

    America and other developing countries has significantly increased the volume of their liabilities. In

    the microfinance world, however, there are many badly-run and financially-weak semi-formal

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    7/21

    institutions that mobilize deposits or require their borrowers to keep compensatory deposits as a

    condition for their loans. An important policy issue is how to protect the deposits of the poor in these

    institutions.

    Although financial liberalization has expanded the range and volume of lending and deposits

    activities, often this expansion has been accomplished without improvements in prudential regulationand supervision. Recently, several authors have focused on regulation and supervision issues (Vogel,

    1994 ; Chaves and Gonzalez-Vega, 1994).

    Vogel (1994) points to two forces propelling successful microfinance programs towards some

    kind of formalization deposit mobilization and leverage. This author also lists two key features of

    microfinance programs that need to be considered in any regulation and supervision scheme. First, loan

    delinquency in successful microfinance programs is lower than in commercial banks, but it can be

    more volatile. When a microfinance intermediary faces high levels of delinquency, it can lose a higher

    percentage of its equity than a bank with a similar level of delinquency. This may be due to the

    absence of tangible guarantees and to the short-term maturity of the loans.

    Second, the potentially greater volatility of delinquency rates with a greater threat to equity

    suggests the need for more frequent reporting for microfinance institutions than for banks. This author

    argues that microfinance programs are highly sensitive to institutional failures. These failures may

    generate a run on deposits resulting in the collapse of the whole microfinance system. In addition,

    many microfinance programs have limited capacity to increase their levels of capitalization. In the

    event of a run on deposits, institutions have no clear and solvent owners who can rescue the program

    with inflows of additional capital. Therefore, examiners may need to the specially alert in determining

    the actual and potential capital adequacy of a microfinance program. For this, examiners need to have

    special skills and attitudes. Similarly, agencies dedicated to the supervision of microfinance institutions

    need to have a special orientation. Therefore, a common supervisory agency for both banks and

    microfinance programs is still an issue of debate.

    In order to achieve a safe and sound microfinance system, a technical paper of FAO (1995)

    remarked, that, in addition to a prudential regulation and supervision scheme, it is important to provide

    facilities of a lender of last resort to prevent temporary liquidity problems. This paper also discusses

    the moral hazard problems of deposit insurance systems. Arguing that under these schemes depositors

    have less incentive to choose more

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    8/21

    Stable financial institution and that financial intermediaries have less incentive to abide by the

    discipline of the market, the paper highlighted that deposit insurance can only provide adequate

    protection, if :

    (a) the microfinance system has access to at least a fairly stable banking system,

    (b) the microfinance system is covered by an adequate prudential regulation andsupervision mechanism, and

    (c) the microfinance system exhibits a willingness to adequately fund a deposit insurance

    scheme.

    Chaves and Gonzalez-Vega (1994) discussed some principles of prudential regulation and

    supervision for microfinance programs. These authors argue that :

    (a) regulation should not introduce competitive biases among financial intermediaries,

    (b) the negative effects of regulation on the efficiency of the financial system should be

    minimized,

    (c) regulation of financial markets should not be used to promote the achievement of social

    objectives, and it must rely as much as possible on the self-interest of economic agents

    (incentive compatibility),

    (d) the purpose of regulation and supervision should not be to avoid bank failures at all

    costs, and

    (e) the regulatory framework should be flexible enough to attempt to regulate different

    intermediaries in a different manner when necessary

    As noted by several researchers, deposit mobilization is of a paramount importance for the

    financial system and for financial intermediaries, but one must be cautious and analyze first the relative

    advantages of each institution, the organization of the financial system, as well as the maturity of the

    financial market before engaging in serous efforts to promote full-service microfinance institutions.

    2.6 Determinants of Savings and Deposits

    Savings are generally defined as the excess of current income over current expenditures.

    Savings are also defined as the change in net worth resulting from the change in physical asset holding

    plus the change in financial assets minus the change in financial liabilities during a given period. There

    is a close relationship among the flows of income, consumption, and savings. Households make

    intertemporal decisions between consumption now or consumption in the future through savings and

    investment.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    9/21

    The postponement of consumption leads to the accumulation of the stock of wealth (net worth).

    Wealth comprises both financial and non-financial assets. Non-financial assets in agriculture typically

    include land, irrigation, facilities and other improvements, buildings and equipment, inventories, and

    livestock. Gold and other non-productive assets are also held in some countries as precautionary

    reserves and inflation hedges. Financial assets include cash, deposits and other financial instrumentssuch as government securities or bonds. Deposits are one type of financial assets, and financial assets

    are a component of total wealth.

    Alternative theories have been developed to explain the relationship among income,

    consumption and savings and the extent to which some variables, such as interest rates, affect savings

    and deposits.

    Keynes (1936) awoke a great interest in the analysis of the consumption function. National

    income data and cross-sectional analysis confirmed the hypothesis that consumption is a positive but

    decreasing function of income, so that the marginal propensity to consume is lower then the average

    propensity to consume. The opposite is true for savings function. In the early 1930s, high

    unemployment, deflation and high real interest rates had a significant impact on Keynesians, who did

    not consider savings as important as investment for the reactivation of the economy. In their view,

    investment should be encouraged through a reduction in interest rates and growth promoted by higher

    levels of government expenditures.

    Kuznets (1960) found that the average propensity to consume is constant in the long run. The

    idea that savings is a fixed proportion of output was generally accepted in most of the earlier growth

    models. When these models where used in developing countries, it was argued that low income

    implied low absolute and relative savings in comparison to developed countries.

    Later formulations of the savings function developed by Friedman and by Modigliani and Ando

    shared a common microeconomic point of view. These researchers focused more on individual

    behavior than on macroeconomic relationships. Friedman (1957) introduced the interest rate in the

    consumption function to allow for individual borrowing and lending decisions. In rural areas, the

    distinction made by Friedman between permanent and transitory income called the attention of

    researchers, due to the variability of farm income. Modigliani and Ando (1963) introduced interest

    rates to discount the income stream generated during the life cycle of consumers. In both cases,

    however, the existence of efficient capital markets was assumed, and interest rate changes were

    supposed to be known in advance and incorporated into expected income streams.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    10/21

    The life cycle hypothesis attracted attention on the influence of dependency ratios on savings

    patterns. Some authors found in high dependency ratios a partial explanation for low savings ratios in

    developing countries (Leff, 1968). Other authors rejected these results, arguing that the cur-off age for

    dependency must be low, especially in rural settings (Gupta, 1970).

    Theoretical and empirical studies have thus singled out a group of variables that presumablyinfluence savings. Income, family size, wealth, interest rates, returns on physical assets or alternative

    investments, transaction costs, and the size of the financial system are among these variables.

    A number of studies provide evidence of a strong relationship between income levels and

    savings levels. There are three main theories of savings and income: the absolute income theory, the

    relative income theory, and the permanent income theory.

    The absolute income theory states that the level of income determines the level of savings. It

    further indicates that savings increase with each rise in income at an increasing rate (Gilboy, 1968).

    The relative income theory states that in the long run the aggregate savings ratio is independent

    of absolute income and that in the short run it is contingent upon the relationship between current

    income and previous peak income. Very few researchers have attempted to test this hypothesis

    (Chauhan, Mundle and Jadhav. 1972).

    Friedman (1957) classifies income into permanent and transitory income. According to the

    permanent income hypothesis, permanent income and permanent consumption are positively

    correlated, and there is no correlation between transitory income, and that the elasticity of savings with

    respect to transitory income is unity.

    Friedman argues that consumption is determined by long-term considerations, so that any

    transitory changes in income lead primarily to additions to accumulated balances or to the use of

    previously accumulated balances rater than to corresponding changes in consumption. Furthermore,

    this hypothesis states that the relationship between permanent income and permanent consumption is

    proportional. Thus, an increase in permanent income will cause a proportionate increase in permanent

    consumption, suggesting that the relationship between permanent income and permanent savings is

    also proportional.

    In a rural economy, the permanent income hypothesis seems to explain the influence of income

    on household savings better than the absolute income hypothesis because of the typical variability of

    rural household income. In addition to savings out of permanent and transitory income for

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    11/21

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    12/21

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    13/21

    Vogel and Buser (1976) also reviewed the experience of Latin America and found evidence

    supporting the positive elasticity of financial asset holding to higher returns on financial assets.

    Evidence that deposits respond to higher interest rates is also indicated by the growth of parallel

    financial sectors in countries with repressed financial systems. Depositors are attracted to unregulated

    intermediaries whenever these are able to offer depositors interest rates that compensate for both

    inflation and the greater risk of depositing with non-regulated intermediaries (Gonzalez-Vega andZinser, 1987).

    Savings and deposits are affected by inflation. Increases in the price level have two effects.

    First, an increase in prices raises nominal consumption expenditures. Second, inflation increases

    nominal income. Farmers may derive benefits from inflation, if the increases in the prices for their

    products are greater than the increases in the prices of their inputs and vice-versa. Wage earners

    usually suffer the most from price increases.

    Different studies show both a positive and a negative relationship between savings and

    inflation. Diwan (1968) found an inverse and significant relationship between savings and the price

    level in India, while in Bangladesh. If real interest rates are negative as a consequence of inflation, the

    demand of deposits is reduced.

    The returns on alternative investments and transaction costs are two other variables that

    influence the level of deposits. The magnitude of the relationship between interest rates and deposits

    may be influenced by the rates of return on alternative investments. Several studies in India show that

    rural investments in irrigation, land, and dairy farms are highly profitable (Rajagopalan and

    Krishnamurty, 1969, Desai, 1981, Krishnamurty and Raychaudhuri, 1980). The existence of profitable

    investment opportunities that are more attractive than the interest paid by banks induces households to

    invest in alternative businesses rather than to keep their purchasing power in deposit accounts. Adams

    (1983) and Burket and Vogel (1987) found a significant negative relationship between returns on

    physical capital and financial savings.

    High transaction costs reduce the net return to depositors and have a negative impact on

    deposits. Transaction costs include explicit costs of travel and other incidental expenses and the

    implicit coat of the time spent in maintaining accounts. Transaction costs influence both non-interest

    bearing deposits and time deposits. Such costs are reduced by proximity to bank branches, financial

    innovations, and the expansion of roads and vehicles.

    Depositors may also be discouraged from holding wealth in financial instruments by the same

    reasons potential borrowers are rationed when they apply for loans. For depositors and borrowers, the

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    14/21

    costs of meeting bank requirements result in too high total costs of loans or too low net returns on

    deposits. Small depositors, in particular, are screened out by large requirements of initial amounts, high

    service charges, or simply by limiting branch expansion to important urban or rural areas (Gonzlez-

    Vega and Poyo, 1986 ; Burket and Vogel, 1987)

    In rural areas where people have little understanding and confidence on banking, depositmobilization may depend largely on the quality of the services of bank employees, where frequent

    interaction may increase peoples confidence. Furthermore, the existence of bank branches has positive

    effects by lowering transaction costs and increasing awareness about banking. In Bangladesh, for

    example, policies for deposit mobilization encompass personal contact of employees with potential

    depositors and large-scale publicity. These policies are observed to be effective in deposit mobilization

    particularly in urban areas (Kahlily, 1987). Earlier studies did not include quality of service as a

    variable that affects deposit mobilization. The omission of this variable may have infalted the effect of

    interest rates on deposits.

    Von Pischke (1978) and Mauri (1983) argued that the demand for deposits is largely influenced

    by education, Yet, the evidence on the elasticity of deposits with respect to education levels is quite

    conflicting. While Koropecky (1984) found a significantly positive relationship between literacy and

    rural deposits in Bangladesh, Vasquez (1986) found a negative elasticity of rural deposits with respect

    to education levels in Dominican Republic. Educated depositors avoided financial assets which earned

    negative real rates of return.

    It has been evident from the experience of Grameen Bank in Bangladesh and in other places

    that linking future loans with deposits induces households to demand deposit facilities. The linkage

    between loans and deposits may allow financial institutions to get more information about potential

    borrowers, reducing potential default rates (Meyer, 1985).

    Among other authors, Mauri (1983) argued that not only economic factors influence the

    decision to demand deposits. Safety considerations are also an important factor that Positively affects

    deposit mobilization. This is particularly true where law and order are precarious.

    Wai (1972) developed a conceptual framework to study savings behavior. According to this

    author, three sets of factors determine the decision to save:

    (a) The ability to save, which is a function of variables such as income, dependency rations,

    and wealth levels.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    15/21

    (b) The willingness to save, determined by variables such as interest rates, the stage in the

    life cycle of the household, and cultural factors.

    (c) The opportunity to save, where the supply of financial services and the marginal

    efficiency of capital are determinant factors according to wai.

    With regard to deposit mobilization, Wai argued that the variables that can be more easily

    influenced in order to increase deposits are interest rates and the degree of financial intermediation. In

    contrast, a reduction in dependency ratios, for instance, can come along only after a slowdown in the

    rate of population growth, and it cannot be changed in the short ruin. Finally, other variables affect

    deposit behavior in opposite ways, and thus their effect at the aggregate level may cancel out. This is

    the case, for instance, of the stage in the life-cycle of the household.

    In some models, Wai used as a proxy for the aggregate ability to save the rate of growth of per

    capita income; for willingness to save, he used various proxies of the degree of financial

    intermediation, such as branch/population ratios and the growth of financial assets held by the private

    sector. For developing countries, Wai found evidence to support the positive effect of growth in

    income per capita and of financial intermediation on savings as a well as the negative influence of

    capital inflows and of inflation.

    A newer approach to the relationship between savings behavior and income in developing

    countries was initiated in the late 1980s. This approach falls into two categories. The first category

    includes studies that investigate how well households smooth consumption for a given income level,

    but abstracts from issues of production (Deation, 1991). The second category includes a small but

    growing literature that studies the inter-linkages between savings, credit constraints, and production

    decisions (Rosenzweig, 1992; Paxson, 1992; Udry, 1993).

    Deaton (1990) constructs a model of savings that includes several special characteristics to

    reflect better the environment in developing countries. First, a model of savings for developing

    countries will not consider retirement savings, because of the internal transfers from children to

    parents, which occur when parents reach low-productivity ages. Second, income derived from

    agriculture is uncertain, and poor consumers are more risk averse. Risk aversion has important

    implications for the shape of the consumption function. The marginal disutilities of losses in

    consumption near subsistence levels is greater than the marginal utilities of gains in times of

    abundance. Individuals will therefore give up consumption (save) when it is possible so as to prepare

    of possible disasters, even if those disasters are few and far between.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    16/21

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    17/21

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    18/21

    The econometric results together with descriptive statistics by wealth level of the rural and

    urban households shed some light on their savings and deposit patterns.

    7.1 Determinants of Saver Status

    For the model for urban areas, the sector of economic activity in trade, agriculture, and services

    as well as education are significant variables in explaining the probability of being a saver. This result

    reflects the greater demand for transaction balances and inventories in trade and service activities andthe lack of synchronization of earnings and expenditures in agriculture, which requires the

    accumulation of assets.

    In contrast, being a male head of household has a negative effect on the probability of being a

    saver. This unusual result refers, however, to the higher probability of being a saver among female

    heads of household and not a women in general. The dependency ratio also has a negative impact on

    the probability of being a saver. Wealth, on the other hand, is not significant. Ceteris paribus, there are

    no significant differences in the probability of being a saver according to wealth: both the rich and the

    poor save.

    For the model for rural areas, education, wealth level, and being a bank and a cooperative

    borrower have a positive effect on the probability of being a saver. The different sectors of economic

    activity did not have a significant impact on the probability of being a saver. Wealth may reflect more

    binding constraints on the ability to save in rural areas, while being a borrower suggests a positive

    impact of financial intermediation on savings behavior.

    7.2 Determinants of Bank Depositor Status

    In urban areas, earning of monthly income has a positive effect on the probability of holding a

    bank deposit. Heads of household with monthly earnings in urban areas prefer to hold their money

    balances in a safe place, such as a bank deposit. In urban areas, education is not a significant

    determinant of the probability of being a bank depositor, while in rural areas education does have a

    positive significant effect on this outcome. This might reflect the fact that in rural areas over 40 percent

    of the populations has no schooling at all. Higher levels of education may enable heads of household to

    initiate a relationship with a bank.

    Among the most important determinants of the probability of being a bank depositor are the

    existence of bank-client relationships and perceptions about the transaction costs of being a depositor.

    Being a bank borrower has a positive significant effect on the probability of having a bank deposit

    account in both urban and rural areas. This result suggests that borrowers are more integrated to the

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    19/21

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    20/21

    may offer higher rates of return are added to the households portfolio of wealth, as predicted by

    Deaton (1991) and others.

    Although deposits are liquid and a close substitute of cash at home, they are not widely held in

    rural areas, most likely because of deficiencies in the supply of deposit facilities. This is reinforced by

    the negative and significant effect of occupation in agriculture on the probability of holding bankdeposits over cash at home. The relative low rates of interest offered by banks can be a disincentive for

    potential depositors, particularly if transaction costs are high. The significance of the impact of

    education in rural but not in urban areas suggests that differences in schooling levels in the two areas

    and familiarity with banking procedures may also explain this result.

    Bank transaction costs have a significant effect on the probability of holding bank deposits over

    only cash at home in rural areas, but they are not significant in urban areas. This result was expected,

    and it suggests that although transaction costs may not be a significant determinant of the net return on

    deposits in urban areas, they indeed are in rural areas. This reflects the urban bias of financial

    development. Given a strong preference for liquidity in rural areas, in the absence of deposit facilities,

    the alternative to costly deposits is cash at home. If, in addition, the transaction costs of cooperative

    deposits are perceived as being low, the probability of being a bank depositor declines, as shown by

    the corresponding significant coefficient. The reduction in transaction costs for depositors in

    cooperatives may thus imply a substitution effect on bank deposits.

    Being a borrower in a cooperative has a positive significant has a positive significant effect on

    the probability of holding cooperative deposits over cash at home only in both urban and rural areas.

    This result shows that loans from cooperatives are closely associated with a deposit account at the

    same institution, in reflection of the institutional requirement in cooperatives to open a deposit account

    before obtaining a loan. Similarly, being a bank borrower has a positive significant effect on the

    probability of holding bank deposits over cash at home, but only in rural areas.

    7.4 Policy Implications

    The financial sector plays an important role in economic growth and development especially in

    rural areas. Credit-constrained households are not able to borrow during adverse shocks. To face these

    shocks, they need to keep precautionary reserves. reserves. The absence of deposit facilities eliminates

    a most attractive means of holding these reserves.

  • 8/6/2019 Delien Hans

    21/21

    A deepening in the outreach of rural financial intermediation would allow these households to

    keep precautionary deposits and to borrow when necessary. This will reduce their risk aversion and

    would free resources for productive investment that otherwise are kept hostage to guarantee a secure

    minimum standard of consumption. Therefore, the improvement and expansion of credit and deposit

    facilities will have an important impact on the investment behavior of rural households.

    The results of this thesis have several policy implications for government intervention in rural

    financial markets. First, it is important to recognize that, despite its importance, deposit mobilization in

    rural areas is more complex and costly than is traditionally believed. Low levels of wealth imply small

    deposit accounts. This increases the cost per dollar of handling deposit accounts. Further, the

    geographical dispersion of rural households makes it more costly for financial institutions to mobilize

    deposits. The low density of population reduces the size of the market and prevents the exploitation of

    economies of scale to dilute the fixed costs of branches. The same circumstances increase the

    transaction costs of depositors.

    Second, high levels of illiteracy in rural areas are strongly correlated with poverty. Both

    significantly reduce the probability of being a depositor. Illiteracy should be reduced as an important

    strategy to reduce poverty. Improvement in education will improve the probabilities of future

    generations of breaking away from the perennial condition of poverty suffered by most rural

    households.