Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

download Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

of 14

Transcript of Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    1/14

    9www.DGFI.com

    Your entry to in-depth

    knowledge in nance

    Global Financial Institute

    Deutsche Asset& Wealth Management

    Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    May 2013 Pro. Barry Eichengreen

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    2/14

    Author

    Pro. Barry Eichengreen

    George C. Pardee and Helen N.

    Pardee Proessor o Economics

    and Political Science

    Department o Economics

    University o Caliornia, Berkeley

    Email:

    [email protected]

    Web Page:

    Click here

    2

    Barry Eichengreen is the George C. Pardee and

    Helen N. Pardee Proessor o Economics and

    Proessor o Political Science at the University

    o Caliornia, Berkeley, where he has taught

    since 1987. He is a Research Associate o the

    National Bureau o Economic Research (Cam-

    bridge, Massachusetts) and Research Fellow o

    the Centre or Economic Policy Research (Lon-

    don, England). In 1997-98 he was Senior Policy

    Advisor at the International Monetary Fund. He

    is a ellow o the American Academy o Arts

    and Sciences (class o 1997).

    Proessor Eichengreen is the convener o the

    Bellagio Group o academics and economic

    ocials and chair o the Academic Advisory

    Committee o the Peterson Institute o Inter-

    national Economics. He has held Guggenheim

    and Fulbright Fellowships and has been a

    Global Financial Institute

    ellow o the Center or Advanced Study in the

    Behavioral Sciences (Palo Alto) and the Insti-

    tute or Advanced Study (Berlin). He is a regu-

    lar monthly columnist or Project Syndicate.

    Proessor Eichengreen was awarded the Eco-

    nomic History Associations Jonathan R.T.

    Hughes Prize or Excellence in Teaching in

    2002 and the University o Caliornia at Berke-

    ley Social Science Divisions Distinguished

    Teaching Award in 2004. He is the recipient

    o a doctor honoris causa rom the American

    University in Paris, and the 2010 recipient o

    the Schumpeter Prize rom the International

    Schumpeter Society. He was named one

    o Foreign Policy Magazine s 100 Leading

    Global Thinkers in 2011. He is Immediate Past

    President o the Economic History Associa-

    tion (2010-11 academic year).

    mailto://[email protected]://emlab.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/biosketch.htmlhttp://emlab.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/biosketch.htmlmailto://[email protected]
  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    3/14

    Table of contents3

    Table o contents

    Introduction to Global Financial Institute

    Global Financial Institute was launched in November

    2011. It is a new-concept think tank that seeks to oster a

    unique category o thought leadership or proessional

    and individual investors by eectively and tasteully

    combining the perspectives o two worlds: the world

    o investing and the world o academia. While primar-

    ily targeting an audience within the international und

    investor community, Global Financial Institutes publica-

    tions are nonetheless highly relevant to anyone who is

    interested in independent, educated, long-term views

    on the economic, political, nancial, and social issues

    acing the world. To accomplish this mission, Global

    Financial Institutes publications combine the views o

    Deutsche Asset & Wealth Managements investment

    experts with those o leading academic institutions in

    Europe, the United States, and Asia. Many o these aca-

    demic institutions are hundreds o years old, the perectplace to go to or long-term insight into the global econ-

    omy. Furthermore, in order to present a well-balanced

    perspective, the publications span a wide variety o

    academic elds rom macroeconomics and nance to

    sociology. Deutsche Asset & Wealth Management invites

    you to check the Global Financial Institute website regu-

    larly or white papers, interviews, videos, podcasts, and

    more rom Deutsche Asset & Wealth Managements

    Co-Chie Investment Ocer o Asset Management Dr.

    Asoka Whrmann, CIO Oce Chie Economist Johannes

    Mller, and distinguished proessors rom institutions

    like the University o Cambridge, the University o Cali-

    ornia Berkeley, the University o Zurich and many more,

    all made relevant and reader-riendly or investment

    proessionals like you.

    Introduction ............................................. .............................. 04

    1. History Lessons ................................................ ..................... 06

    2. Reasoning by Analogy ................................................... .... 08

    3. The Fog o War ................................................. ..................... 11

    4. Reerences ................................................ .............................. 12

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    4/14

    Introduction

    4

    The problem o currency wars emerged as both a

    major concern and a source o conusion in early 2013.

    This once obscure term, rst uttered by Brazilian Finance

    Minister Guido Mantega in response to the initial round

    o quantitative easing in the United States, came into

    widespread use ollowing the ormation o a new Japa-

    nese government under Prime Minister Shinzo Abe in

    late 2012. Mr. Abe indicated his intention o pursuing

    more aggressively refationary monetary and exchange

    rate policies. This caused the yen to all by 16% against

    the dollar and 19% against the euro between the end o

    September, when it became likely that Mr. Abe would

    take power, and mid-February 2013, when his appoint-ment o a new Bank o Japan governor was imminent.

    Both the term and the concerns to which it reerred

    thereore migrated to the ront pages o the nancial

    press. A host o additional policymakers some rom

    emerging markets, such as Alexei Ulyukyev, rst deputy

    chairman at the Russian Central Bank, and Bahk Jae-

    wan, South Koreas nance minister, and others rom

    advanced countries, like Bundesbank President Jens

    Weidmann warned o the adverse consequences o

    currency manipulation, Mr. Weidmann reerring omi-

    nously to an undesirable politicisation o exchange

    rates.1 The currency-war problem then became a key

    topic at the meetings o the Group o Seven and Group

    o Twenty this February, where it was the subject o a

    careully crated set o communiques.2

    But careully crated is not the same as clearly under-

    stood. The conusion stems rom the act that there is

    no widely accepted denition o a currency war. The

    term is not ound in the leading textbooks o econom-

    ics. There is the implication that a currency war is to be

    understood by analogy with the concept o a trade war,

    in which countries use trade policy to shit spending

    toward products produced domestically at the expense

    o their neighbours a process that is ultimately utile

    insoar as it provokes retaliation. The only dierence is

    that in the case o a currency war, it is currency policy

    rather than trade policy that is being deployed. There

    is, however, the analytical problem that while trade

    warare destroys trade, creating a deadweight loss, o-

    setting devaluations simply return bilateral exchange

    rates to their initial levels with no enduring relative price

    eects. It is not clear that the analogy holds water, in

    other words.

    Similarly, there is the implication that a currency warcan be said to have broken out when one or more

    countries engages in beggar-thy-neighbour competi-

    tive currency depreciation. But it is not clear in this

    case whether all policies that result in currency or

    exchange-rate depreciation are necessarily competitive

    or beggar-thy-neighbour. Just because a country sees

    its exchange rate depreciate, is it necessarily engaged

    in a currency war?

    Probably the most widely accepted denition o what

    constitutes a currency war is what countries did in the

    1930s. Starting in 1931, one country ater another

    depreciated its currency. Since currencies were

    pegged to gold rather than to one another, countries

    depreciated by abandoning their pre-existing gold pari-

    ties and allowing the domestic currency price o gold

    to rise. This consequently had the eect o also raising

    the domestic currency price o oreign currencies still

    pegged to gold at prevailing parities.3

    As the story is conventionally told, this enhanced the

    competitiveness o countries depreciating their curren-

    cies but worsened that o the remaining gold-standard

    Currency Wars: Perception and RealityPro. Barry EichengreenMay 2013

    Currency Wars: Perception and Reality Global Financial Institute

    1Quoted in Randow and Schneeweiss (2013).2 See Group o Seven (2013) and Group o Twenty (2013).3The gold parity reerred to the weight o gold o specied purity in the national monetary unit as specied by law or

    statute o a country said to be on the gold standard.

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    5/14

    5 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    countries. This saddled the latter with overly strong

    exchange rates, creating pressure or them to respond

    tit or tat, as they ultimately did. Ater ve years o com-

    petitive devaluations, exchange rates had returned to

    levels very close to those prevailing in early 1931. No

    country succeeded in engineering a sustained improve-

    ment in competitiveness or, it is argued, achieved

    aster economic growth. But there were a variety o

    other adverse consequences ranging rom height-

    ened exchange rate uncertainty that disrupted trade

    and production to the imposition o trade barriers and

    exchange controls by countries with overvalued curren-

    cies and weakened balances o payments.4 It is not an

    exaggeration to say that popular accounts blame the

    currency wars o the 1930s or aggravating the political

    tensions that made it more dicult or countries to col-

    laborate in averting the military and diplomatic conficts

    that led ultimately to World War II.5

    In act, this conventional narrative is oversimplied and

    misleading in important respects. This in turn meansthat todays debate over currency wars, because it is

    heavily inormed by that narrative, is itsel oversimpli-

    ed and misleading. The modern literature empha-

    sises that the policy changes associated with currency

    depreciation in the 1930s were not actually zero sum.

    To the contrary, those policy changes let all countries

    better o relative to the status quo ante, in which policy

    did not change and exchange rates did not move. But

    this was not well understood at the time. As a result,

    the point is not understood today by those advancing

    the conventional story.

    In part, contemporary misunderstanding arose rom

    the act that interwar governments did a poor job o

    communicating their intentions. In part it arose rom

    the act that they did a poor job o implementing their

    policies; they could have done much more to accentu-

    ate the positive-sum aspects. And in part it arose rom

    the act that policymakers continued to view their cur-

    rent situation through the lens o past problems, ailing

    to acknowledge that circumstances and thereore the

    appropriate policies had changed.

    The same actors are again present today, once more distort-

    ing the debate over currency policies. Policymakers have

    done a poor job communicating their intentions. They could

    have done more to accentuate positive-sum aspects o their

    actions. And, along with market participants, they have had a

    tendency to view policies through the distorting lens o pastproblems rather than current circumstances. Understanding

    these shortcomings o the present debate and correcting the

    resulting misapprehensions would go a long way toward solv-

    ing the currency war problem.

    4These negative side eects were highlighted by Ragnar Nurkse (1944) in his infuential contemporary account, which

    helped to clear the way or the Bretton Woods System o pegged-but-adjustable exchange rates. A recent, somewhat

    revisionist treatment is Eichengreen and Irwin (2010).5 See or example Kennedy (1999).

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    6/14

    1. History Lessons

    6 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    The background to the currency and exchange rate

    problems o the 1930s was, o course, the depression

    and defation that started in 1929. In turn, that depres-

    sion and defation must be understood in the context o

    the gold standard, the monetary regime providing the

    structure or global monetary and nancial aairs.6

    The 1920s monetary regime was a gold-exchange stan-

    dard rather than a pure gold standard. Central banks

    and governments operated under statutes obligat-

    ing them to back their monetary liabilities with gold

    and convertible oreign exchange.7 Other than this

    provision or holding reserves in the orm o oreign

    exchange, the regime had many o the eatures o a text-

    book gold standard. International nancial fows were

    unrestricted. With the capital account o the balance

    o payments open, domestic interest rates could not

    deviate signicantly rom those in the rest o the world.

    I domestic policymakers sought to depress rates ur-

    ther, capital would migrate to oreign nancial markets

    where they were higher, causing the central bank tolose gold and oreign exchange reserves, and threaten-

    ing the maintenance o gold convertibility. This is the

    standard open-economy trilemma.8 With exchange

    rates pegged and capital markets open, central banks

    had limited monetary policy room or manoeuvre.

    The gold-exchange standard had been put back in place

    in the 1920s ater roughly a decade o suspension, dur-

    ing which a number o current and ormer belligerents

    had suered high infation.9 That experience in turn

    shaped their expectations o risks and outcomes in the

    event that gold convertibility was again suspended.

    As it happened, defation rather than infation turned

    out to be the immediate danger.10 When it developed

    ater 1929, central banks and governments had little

    reedom o action. As long as they remained on the

    gold standard, they could not unilaterally take steps

    to stem the all in prices. They could not unilaterally

    cut interest rates to encourage borrowing and spend-

    ing. Injecting liquidity in order to support a distressed

    banking system threatened to atally weaken the cur-

    rency. Running budget decits rekindled ears, inher-

    ited rom the 1920s, that central banks would be pres-

    sured to monetise public debts. Governments were

    thereore orced to cut public spending and raise taxes

    in order to preserve condence in their exchange rate

    commitments.

    It might be thought that these policies o austerity, pur-

    sued in the ace o depression and defation, could not

    be sustained indenitely. Indeed, they could not. Brit-

    ain was the rst major country to abandon them and

    depreciate its currency. It had a Labour government

    that could not agree on budgetary economies and high

    unemployment that rendered the central bank reluctant

    to raise interest rates urther in order to stem capital

    fight.11 It suspended gold convertibility in September

    1931, and the pound quickly ell rom $4.86 to a low o

    $3.40, rom which it recovered modestly beore stabi-lising. Some two dozen other economies, principally

    members o the Commonwealth and Empire and British

    trading partners, quickly ollowed suit. The next shoe

    to drop was Japan, whose nance minister Korkiyo

    Takahashi implemented an aggressively expansion-

    ary monetary policy that pushed down the yen start-

    ing in December. President Franklin Delano Roosevelt

    embargoed gold exports on March 5th, 1933, his rst

    ull day in oce. He made that embargo permanent

    in April and actively pushed up the dollar price o gold

    (pushed down the dollar exchange rate) rom October.

    A number o U.S. trade partners, principally in Latin

    America, ollowed the dollar down. In January 1934,

    when the dollar was again stabilised against gold, the

    sterling/dollar exchange rate was back to roughly the

    level prevailing beore September 1931.

    These eorts by Britain, the U.S., and Japan to depre-

    ciate sterling, the dollar, and the yen made lie more

    6

    As I argued in Eichengreen (1992), on which the remainder o this section draws.7Typically at ratios o 33 to 40 per cent.8 See Obsteld, Shambaugh and Taylor (205).9 The hyperinfations in Germany, Austria, Hungary, and Poland being extreme cases in point.10 Describing the origins o the global defation would take us too ar aeld; in this, see Bernanke (1995) and Eichen-

    green (2004).11 That Labour government was succeeded by a National government which agreed on budgetary economies in August,

    but by this time it was too late.

    32

    48

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    7/14

    7 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    dicult or countries still on the gold standard. (That

    these are the same three countries currently under

    attack or being engaged in currency war is presum-

    ably a coincidence.) Having lost international competi-

    tiveness, these so-called gold-bloc countries saw their

    balances o payments accounts weaken and gold fow

    out o their central banks. Forced to raise interest rates

    to deend the reserve position rather than cutting them

    to support the economy, their depressions deepened.

    The result was not an equilibrium in either the eco-

    nomic or political sense. Economically, the condition

    o domestic nancial institutions continued to worsen.

    Politically, opposition welled up against policies o aus-

    terity. The remaining members o the gold bloc pro-

    gressively ell by the wayside. Czechoslovakia and Italy

    devalued in 1934, Belgium in 1935, Poland, France, the

    Netherlands, and Switzerland in 1936, returning their

    exchange rates to roughly the same levels against the

    dollar and sterling that prevailed beore 1931. These

    competitive devaluations gave rise to a good deal o

    damaging exchange rate and nancial volatility, but atthe end o the day, it is said, they changed nothing.

    Such is the conventional narrative. The modern litera-

    ture on exchange rate policy in the 1930s, beginning

    with Eichengreen and Sachs (1985), disputes this view

    that the exchange rate policies o the 1930s were with-

    out positive eect. While currency depreciation did

    switch demand toward domestic goods and away rom

    their oreign substitutes, this was not its exclusive or

    even its principal impact. Rather, abandoning the com-

    mitment to peg the exchange rate allowed countries

    to replace the defationary measures o the preceding

    period with refationary monetary policies. Going o

    the gold standard was a credible way o signaling this

    commitment to prioritise price stability over exchange

    rate stability.

    Thus, six months ater abandoning the gold standard,

    the Bank o England began cutting interest rates; by

    July 1932 these had reached the historically low level

    o 2%, inaugurating a new era o cheap money. The

    Swedish government and Riksbank replaced the gold

    standard with an explicit price level target. In Japan,

    Takahashi supplemented his refationary monetary

    policy with an increase in public spending and instruc-

    tions that the Bank o Japan purchase the resulting

    increase in the public debt. In the U.S., FDR used his

    bombshell message to the World Economic Coner-

    ence o June-July 1933 to signal that he was unwilling

    to restore the gold standard. He was not prepared to

    privilege exchange rate stability (what he reerred to in

    that message as the old etishes o international bank-

    ers). The bombshell message may have made interna-

    tional cooperation on trade policy, security policy, and

    other matters more dicult, but it was a strong signal

    o a durable change in the monetary regime.

    These new policies had other important eects apart

    rom their impact on exchange rates. Lower inter-

    est rates encouraged interest-rate sensitive orms o

    spending, in the U.K. or example, where the literature

    reers to the housing boom o the 1930s. 12 They put

    upward pressure on asset prices which, other things

    equal, stimulated investment spending. By haltingdefation, they stemmed the rise in debt burdens and

    squeeze on prots. By creating expectations o higher

    uture prices, they encouraged households to shit

    consumption rom the uture to the present. By giv-

    ing central banks more reedom o action, they allowed

    them to intervene as lenders o last resort to limit bank

    distress.13 And insoar as the policies had these stabi-

    lising eects on the initiating country, they encouraged

    residents to spend more on oreign as well as domestic

    goods. Currency devaluation by an individual country

    may have had negative spillovers on its neighbours via

    the exchange rate channel, but it had positive spillovers

    via these interest rate, asset price, and expectations

    channels. Even i the negative exchange rate spillovers

    dominated when a single policy was taken in isolation,

    once the entire round o exchange rate changes was

    complete those negative spillovers were gone and only

    the positive interest rate, asset price, and expectation

    eects remained.

    These conclusions are, o course, inconsistent with the

    presumption that monetary policy was impotent in the

    1930s because interest rates were at the zero lower

    12 See Middleton (2010) or reerences.13 The cross-country evidence can be ound in Grossman (1994).

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    8/14

    8 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    bound.14 Cross-country comparisons, calibration exer-

    cises, and national case studies, all using data rom the

    1930s, have combined to overturn this presumption.15

    These studies highlight that interest rates were still

    signicantly above zero prior to the change in policy

    regime; the change thereore gave central banks ur-

    ther room to cut. They remind us that even when nomi-

    nal interest rates are near zero, central banks can still

    aect the real interest rates on which allocation deci-

    sions depend through the expectations channel by

    using orward guidance and asset purchases to create

    expectations o infation rather than defation. FDRs

    gold purchases and Takahashis government bond pur-

    chases can be thought o as analogous to quantitative

    easing, while the Bank o Englands commitment to

    keep interest rates low and the Riksbanks commitment

    to target the price level can be thought o as orward

    guidance.

    Modern studies thus conclude that countries abandon-

    ing the gold standard and allowing their currenciesto depreciate recovered most quickly rom the 1930s

    depression. Recovery was, however, less than vigor-

    ous. Countries abandoning the gold standard and

    depreciating their currencies were reluctant to imple-

    ment aggressively refationary policies. In Britain, or

    example, the Bank o England, concerned that the ster-

    ling exchange rate could collapse in the absence o its

    golden anchor, took three ull quarters to convince itsel

    that cheap money was sae and to cut interest rates to

    2%. Even then it remained reluctant to cut them ur-

    ther. FDR, although depreciating the dollar by 50%, put

    the U.S. back on the gold standard at the now higher

    gold price in January 1934, contrary to the advice o

    John Maynard Keynes and others. In the subsequent

    period, the Treasury repeatedly sterilised gold infows,

    limiting the growth o money and credit. Central banks

    and governments could not ree themselves o the

    specter o the 1920s infations and thus were reluctant

    to make ull use o their newound monetary room or

    manoeuvre.

    As a result, the beggar-thy-neighbour eect o currency

    depreciation tended to dominate the positive spillovers

    transmitted through now lower interest rates and infa-

    tionary expectations. And the ailure o policymakers

    to more clearly explain their intentions which were

    not to beggar their neighbours but to stabilize their own

    prices, economies, and nancial systems caused their

    motives to be widely misunderstood.

    Thus, to the extent that there was a currency problem

    in the 1930s, it stemmed not rom the decision o coun-

    tries abandoning the gold standard to refate, but rom

    the ailure o the countries o the gold bloc to do like-

    wise. That ailure was rooted, as noted above, in ear-

    lier experience with high infation in France, Belgium,

    Poland, and the Central European countries that now

    clung to the gold standard with the help o exchange

    control.16 Policymakers and their constituents contin-

    ued to perceive current economic and nancial circum-

    stances through the lens o past problems, with pro-

    oundly negative consequences.

    The problem in the 1930s, then, was not too much cur-

    rency warare, but too little.

    Many o these points have analogues in the current

    debate. First, there is the view, implicit in the critiques

    o emerging market policymakers, that the unconven-

    tional monetary policies o advanced-country central

    banks are ineectual. Monetary policy, they allege, has

    lost its potency now that interest rates are at the zero

    lower bound, just as it allegedly lost its potency in the

    1930s. Only the negative side-eects, it ollows, are

    let.

    While there is less than ull consensus on the ecacy

    o unconventional monetary policies at the zero lower

    bound, a growing body o literature studying dierent

    episodes suggests that such policies are not entirely

    without eect. Oda and Ueda (2005) and Ugai (2006)

    14 A presumption that is popularly cited as explaining Keyness discovery o the importance o using activist scalpolicy in a liquidity trap.15 See, respectively, Bernanke and James (1991), Eggertsson (2008), and Romer (1992) or examples.16 In the cases o Switzerland and the Netherlands, an additional motive was the desire not to jeopardise the position o

    Zurich and Amsterdam as international nancial centres and the power o the banking lobby.

    Global Financial Institute

    2. Reasoning by Analogy

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    9/14

    9 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    analyse the impact o the Bank o Japans experience

    with quantitative easing between 2001 and 2006 and

    conclude in avor o small but noticeable impacts on

    medium- and long-term interest rates. Gagnon, Raskin,

    Remarche, and Sack (2011) report evidence, derived

    using a variety o methodological approaches, o posi-

    tive eects o quantitative easing in the United States.

    Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) look at

    low requency variations in the supply o long-term

    Treasury bonds like those that would ollow rom quan-

    titative easing and identiy eects on interest rates on

    other relatively sae assets. Krishnamurthy and Vissing-

    Jorgensen (2011), disaggregating urther, nd evidence

    o a signaling channel, an expected infation channel,

    and a demand-or-long-term-sae-assets channel trans-

    mitting eects o both the rst and second rounds o

    quantitative easing by the Federal Reserve. Looking

    back at Operation Twist in the 1960s, Swanson (2011)

    nds a small but signicant impact on long-term inter-

    est rates operating through the portolio rebalancing

    channel. Joyce, Lasaosa, Stevens, and Tong (2010)similarly nd evidence o the operation o the porto-

    lio rebalancing channel in the response o gilt prices

    to large-scale asset purchases by the Bank o Eng-

    land starting in March 2009. In a companion paper,

    Kapetanios, Mumtaz, Stevens, and Theodoridis (2010)

    conclude that those Bank o England purchases had an

    eect on the level o real GDP o around 1 % and

    raised the annual rate o CPI infation by about 1 per-

    centage points at its peak. Dierent studies consider

    dierent episodes and arrive at dierent point esti-

    mates, but as a group they are inconsistent with the

    view that unconventional monetary policies are with-

    out eect. This casts doubt on the assertion by some

    observers based in emerging markets that such policies

    should simply be abandoned.

    Second, there is the view that unconventional monetary

    policies operate only by pushing down currencies, with

    beggar-thy-neighbour consequences or other coun-

    tries. To be sure, the exchange rate channel can be

    important or switching expenditure toward domestic

    goods. Insoar as this channel dominates, the eect

    will be to beggar thy neighbour. Just as in the 1930s, to

    the extent that central banks ail to complement open

    mouth operations pushing down the real exchange rate

    with open market operations and other asset purchases

    pushing down real interest rates, their neighbours will

    have correspondingly more reason to complain about

    the spillover eects on output and employment in other

    countries.

    But the exchange rate channel can also be important

    or signaling the policy authorities commitment to

    do what it takes to hit their infation target. Svensson

    (2003) reers to the combination o a price-level target

    path, a zero interest rate commitment and, importantly,

    currency depreciation and a commitment to maintain-

    ing a level or the exchange rate as the oolproo way

    o ending defation. Insoar as ending the defation and

    avoiding the extended period o economic stagnation to

    which it can give rise is good not just or the initiating

    country but also its trade and nancial partners, posi-

    tive spillovers on other countries rom depreciation o

    its exchange rate may still dominate.

    The studies reerred to earlier in this section suggest

    that unconventional monetary policies also operate

    through the portolio rebalancing channel that leads

    to changes in the term structure o interest rates. IMF

    (2011) nds that portolio-rebalancing-related interest-

    rate eects dominated the other negative cross-border

    spillover eects o QE1 and QE2 in other words, that

    the spillover impact on oreign output was positive on

    balance, the complaints o emerging market policymak-

    ers notwithstanding.

    Third, there are complaints about other negative side

    eects o unconventional monetary policies. The worry

    is that quantitative easing is encouraging renewed

    nancial excesses in advanced countries and emerg-

    ing markets alike. Risks are being allowed to build up.

    Equity markets in the United States are becoming richly

    valued as investors acing near-zero interest rates on

    sae assets stretch or yield by purchasing riskier instru-

    ments. The natural process o deleveraging by the

    household and nancial sectors needed to produce a

    saer and more stable economy is being rustrated, the

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    10/14

    10 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    implication ollows.

    This view has an analogue in the liquidationist

    response to the Great Depression.17 U.S. policymak-

    ers inside and outside the Fed worried that monetary

    accommodation would cause the development o an

    even larger Wall Street boom and bubble, leading sub-

    sequently to an even larger crash. Herbert Hoovers

    Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon amously argued

    that restraint was necessary to teach speculators

    a lesson and purge the rottenness out o the sys-

    tem.18 Similar views were advanced by Austrian and

    other Continental European economists rom Hayek to

    Schumpeter.

    The modern literature on the Great Depression and on

    nancial crises generally acknowledges that activism

    has risks but suggests that inaction in the ace o cri-

    sis also has a downside. And to the extent that pol-

    icy activism in response to crisis encourages nancial

    excesses, these are best addressed by tightening super-vision and regulation o nancial markets, not by pre-

    mature abandonment o supportive monetary policies.

    Some recent studies have questioned this separation

    principle they have questioned whether there exists

    an adequate array o monetary and regulatory instru-

    ments, so that monetary policy can be assigned to infa-

    tion and growth while regulation is assigned to nancial

    stability.19 Maybe not, but i not the call should be or

    policymakers to develop a wider array o instruments,

    not or central banks and governments to abandon the

    pursuit o all other valid goals in the interest o nancial

    stability.

    The same goes or the complaint that unconventional

    monetary policies in the advanced countries are eed-

    ing nancial excesses in emerging markets. The worry

    itsel is not without oundation: As Chen, Filardo, He

    and Zhu (2011) show, quantitative easing in the United

    States has had a strong impact on credit growth,

    asset prices, and capital infows in emerging markets.

    But the rst-best response or policymakers in those

    countries is not to jawbone the Federal Reserve and

    Bank o Japan to abandon quantitative easing, which

    would make or slower global and even possibly slower

    emerging-market growth, but to tighten their own

    supervision and regulation o nancial markets. And to

    the extent that conventional regulatory instruments are

    not up to the task, emerging market policy makers can

    resort to capital infow taxes and controls as a second

    line o deence against nancial excesses resulting rom

    oreign policies.20

    Similarly, to the extent that low interest rates in the

    advanced countries encourage capital infows into

    emerging markets that an infation, result in currency

    overvaluation, and create worries o overheating, the

    rst-best response is not or ocials there to pressure

    advanced country central banks to abandon their low

    interest rate policies but to adjust their own policies

    appropriately. The rst-best response is or emerging

    markets to tighten scal policy. Tightening scal policy

    puts downward pressure on domestic spending. It putsdownward pressure on asset valuations. It means less

    infation, other things equal. It means lower interest

    rates and, thereore, smaller capital infows and less

    pressure or real exchange rate appreciation. By reduc-

    ing sovereign debt burden, it puts the economy in a

    stronger position going orward.

    The objection here is that political constraints make

    it dicult to adjust scal policy, which is even more

    politicised than monetary policy. Maybe so, but then

    the call should be to make it easier to implement opti-

    mal adjustments o scal policy in emerging markets

    by strengthening automatic stabilisers or delegating

    aspects o scal policy to an independent scal council,

    not to insist that advanced country central banks aban-

    don the pursuit o price stability and recovery.

    The European Central Bank, spokesmen or which have

    complained about how the policies o other central

    banks have produced an uncomortably strong euro

    exchange rate, is in a dierent position. In contrast to

    17 See DeLong (1990).18 As quoted in Hoover (1952).19 See Committee on International Economic Policy and Reorm (2011).20This is the justication o capital infow restrictions as a second-best orm o nancial regulation rst developed, i I

    am correct, in Eichengreen and Mussa (1998).

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    11/14

    11 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    emerging markets, spokesmen or which have similarly

    complained that their exchange rates are uncomort-

    ably strong, the Eurozone does not currently suer rom

    excessive infation, rothy asset markets, or risk o eco-

    nomic overheating to the contrary. Eurozone infation

    ell to 2% in January in line with the ECBs target, while

    core infation at 1.2% is running below that. The ourth

    quarter o 2012 saw Eurozone GDP shrink by 0.6%.

    The standard policy prescription or a central bank

    engaged in fexible infation targeting and worried by

    an overly strong exchange rate would be to join the cur-

    rency wars. In the event, the ECB is not a conventional

    infation-targeting central bank. It has a mandate to

    hold infation at or below its target o 2% but not to pur-

    sue other goals. The European public, whose approval

    lends the ECBs policies political legitimacy, continues

    to worry about infation, which was yesterdays prob-

    lem but is less obviously todays or even tomorrows.

    The analogy with the defationary 1930s when central

    banks were haunted by the spectre o infation in anearlier decade, in turn eeding their reluctance to take

    more aggressive monetary action is direct. How the

    ECB squares this circle will have implications not just

    or the global currency wars, but or the uture o the

    Eurozone itsel.

    A nal analogy with the 1930s is the ailure o policy

    makers in countries ollowing unconventional monetary

    policies to adequately communicate their goals and

    strategies. In late December, Japans incoming prime

    minister made a series o comments about the desir-

    ability o resisting a strong yen that were interpreted

    in terms o the desirability o a weaker yen exchange

    rate. By ocusing on the exchange rate rather than

    on measures to push up the price level, reduce inter-

    est rates, and encourage spending, those comments

    anned ears that the strategy was intentionally beggar

    thy neighbour. In its rst policy statement or 2013,

    the Bank o Japan then signaled its responsiveness to

    the new governments desires, but announced that it

    would consider urther ramping up its programme o

    asset purchases only in 2014. By creating expectations

    that it might acquiesce to a weaker yen exchange rate

    but that it would only take additional steps to oster

    expectations o higher prices, lower real interest rates,

    and more spending 12 or more months in the uture,

    that statement urther heightened ears abroad that the

    new strategy was exchange-rate-centered and beggar

    thy neighbour.

    It may be that the essence o Japans new monetary

    policy strategy is the higher infation target o 2% and

    that the Bank o Japan will make a concerted eort to

    achieve it, creating expectations o a higher uture price

    level and encouraging additional spending by Japanese

    consumers something that would be more likely to

    have positive spillovers or other countries. I so, this

    act needs to be conveyed more clearly to avoid anning

    ears o currency war.

    Currency war is now a standard trope in journalis-

    tic accounts o monetary policy. But what exactly

    constitutes currency warare remains unclear. Not

    every economic policy that is associated with a weaker

    exchange rate is undesirable, and not every domestic

    policy associated with a weaker exchange rate nec-

    essarily redounds to the disavor o other countries.

    Ocials warning o currency wars would do better to

    distinguish positive rom negative eects o the oreign

    monetary policies o which they complain. They would

    do well to consider the alternatives. Would emerging

    markets really be better o i advanced countries at

    risk o defation and recession abandoned their uncon-

    ventional policies? Policymakers in emerging markets

    could spend less time complaining about advanced

    country policies and more time identiying and imple-

    menting an appropriate policy response. Policymakers

    in advanced countries, or their part, need to do a better

    job o communicating the intent o their policies. Only

    then are we likely to see our way through the og o war.

    Global Financial Institute

    3. The Fog o War

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    12/14

    4. Reerences

    12 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    Bernanke, Ben (1995), The Macroeconomics o the

    Great Depression: A Comparative Approach, Journal

    o Money, Credit and Banking 27, pp.1-28.

    Bernanke, Ben and Harold James (1991), The Gold

    Standard, Defation and Financial Crisis in the Great

    Depression, in R. Glenn Hubbard (ed.), Financial Mar-

    kets and Financial Crises, Chicago: University o Chi-

    cago Press, pp.33-68.

    Chen, Qianying, Andrew Filardo, Dong He, and Feng

    Zhu (2011), International Spillovers o Central Bank

    Balance Sheet Policies, BIS Paper no.66, pp.230-274.

    Committee on International Economic Policy and

    Reorm (2011), Rethinking Central Banking, Washing-

    ton, D.C.: Brookings Institution.

    DeLong, J. Bradord (1990), Liquidation Cycles:

    Old-Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the

    Great Depression, NBER Working Paper no.3546(December).

    Eggertsson, Gauti (2008), Great Expectations and the

    End o the Depression, American Economic Review

    98, pp.1476-1516.

    Eichengreen, Barry (1992), Golden Fetters: The Gold

    Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939, New

    York: Oxord University Press.

    Eichengreen, Barry (2004), Understanding the Great

    Depression, Canadian Journal o Economics 37,

    pp.1-27.

    Eichengreen, Barry and Douglas Irwin (2010), The

    Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who

    Succumbed and Why? Journal o Economic History

    70, pp.871-897.

    Eichengreen, Barry and Michael Mussa, with Giovanni

    DellArricia, Enrica Detagiache, Gian Maria Milesi-

    Ferretti, and Andrew Tweedie (1998), Capital Account

    Liberalization: Theoretical and Practical Aspects,

    IMF Occasional Paper no.172, Washington, D.C.: IMF

    (August).

    Eichengreen, Barry and Jerey Sachs (1985),

    Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the

    1930s, Journal o Economy History 49, pp.924-946.

    Gagnon, Joseph, Mathew Raskin, Julie Remache, and

    Brian Sack (2011), The Financial Market Eects o the

    Federal Reserves Large-Scale Asset Purchases, Inter-

    national Journal o Central Banking 7, pp. 3-43.

    Grossman, Richard (1994), The Shoe that Didnt Drop:

    Explaining Banking Stability During the Great Depres-

    sion, Journal o Economic History 54, pp.654-682.

    Group o Seven (2013), Statement by G7 Finance

    Ministers and Central Bank Governors (12 February),

    http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/nance/index.htm .

    Group o Twenty (2013), Communique o Meeting oFinance Ministers and Central Bank Governors, Mos-

    cow, 15-16 February 2013, http://en.g20russia.ru/

    documents/.

    Hoover, Herbert (1982), The Memoirs o Herbert

    Hoover: The Great Depression, New York: Macmillan

    International Monetary Fund (2011), United States:

    Spillover Report 2011 Article IV Consultation, Wash-

    ington, D.C.: IMF (22 July).

    Joyce, Michael, Ana Lasaosa, Ibrahim Stevens, and

    Matthew Tong (2010), The Financial Market Impact o

    Quantitative Easing, Bank o England Working Paper

    no.393 (August).

    Kapetanios, George, Haroon Mumtaz, Ibrahim Stevens,

    and Konstantinos Tehodoridis (2012), Assessing the

    Economy-wide Eects o Quantitative Easing, Eco-

    nomic Journal 122, pp.F316-F347.

    Kennedy, David (1999), Freedom rom Fear: The Ameri-

    can People in Depression and War, 1929-1945, New

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    13/14

    13 Currency Wars: Perception and Reality

    York: Oxord University Press.

    Krishnamurthy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen

    (2011), The Eects o Quantitative Easing on Interest

    Rates: Channels and Implications or Policy, NBER

    Working Paper no.17555 (October).

    Krishnamurthy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen

    (2010), The Aggregate Demand or Treasury Debt,

    unpublished manuscript, Northwestern University.

    Middleton, Roger (2010), British Monetary and Fis-

    cal Policy in the 1930s, Oxord Review o Economic

    Policy 26, pp.414-441.

    Nurkse, Ragnar (1944), International Currency Experi-

    ence, Geneva: League o Nations.

    Obsteld, Maurice, Jay Schambaugh, and Alan Taylor

    (2005), The Trilemma in History: Tradeos Among

    Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies and CapitalMobility, Review o Economics and Statistics 87,

    pp.423-438.

    Oda, Nobuyuki and Kazuo Ueda (2005), The Eects

    o the Bank o Japans Zero Interest Rate Commitment

    and Quantitative Monetary Easing on the Yield Curve:

    A Macro-Finance Approach, Bank o Japan Working

    Paper no. 05-E-6, Monetary Aairs Department, Bank

    o Japan (April).

    Randow, Jana and Zoe Schneeweiss (2013), Weid-

    mann Says Exchange Rates Should be Determined by

    Markets, Bloomberg Business Week (15 February),

    http://www.businessweek.com/news/2013-02-15/wei-

    dmann-says-exchange-rates-should-be-determined-by-

    markets.

    Romer, Christina (1992), What Ended the Great

    Depression? Journal o Economic History 52,

    pp.757-784.

    Ugai, Hiroshi (2006), Eects o the Quantitative Eas-

    ing Policy: A Survey o Empirical Analyses, Working

    Paper no.06-E-10, Monetary Aairs Department, Bank

    o Japan (October).

    Svensson, Lars (2003), Escaping rom a Liquidity Trap

    and Defation: The Foolproo Way and Others, Journal

    o Economic Perspectives 17, pp.145-166.

    Swanson, Eric T. (2011), Lets Twist Again: A High-

    Frequency Event-Study Analysis o Operation Twist

    and Its Implications or QE2, Brookings Papers on

    Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 151-88.

    Global Financial Institute

  • 7/27/2019 Currency Wars - Perception and Reality. EICHENGREEN, Barry.

    14/14

    Disclaimer

    Deutsche Asset & Wealth Management represents the asset management and wealth management activities conducted by Deutsche

    Bank AG or any o its subsidiaries. Clients will be provided Deutsche Asset & Wealth Management products or services by one or more

    legal entities that will be identied to clients pursuant to the contracts, agreements, oering materials or other documentation relevant

    to such products or services.

    This material was prepared without regard to the specic objectives, nancial situation or needs o any particular person who may

    receive it. It is intended or inormational purposes only and it is not intended that it be relied on to make any investment decision. It

    does not constitute investment advice or a recommendation or an oer or solicitation and is not the basis or any contract to purchase

    or sell any security or other instrument, or or Deutsche Bank AG and its aliates to enter into or arrange any type o transaction as a con-

    sequence o any inormation contained herein. Neither Deutsche Bank AG nor any o its aliates, gives any warranty as to the accuracy,

    reliability or completeness o inormation which is contained in this document. Except insoar as liability under any statute cannot be

    excluded, no member o the Deutsche Bank Group, the Issuer or any ocer, employee or associate o them accepts any liability (whether

    arising in contract, in tort or negligence or otherwise) or any error or omission in this document or or any resulting loss or damage

    whether direct, indirect, consequential or otherwise suered by the recipient o this document or any other person.

    The opinions and views presented in this document are solely the views o the author and may dier rom those o Deutsche Asset

    & Wealth Management and the other business units o Deutsche Bank. The views expressed in this document constitute the authors

    judgment at the time o issue and are subject to change. The value o shares/units and their derived income may all as well as rise. Past

    perormance or any prediction or orecast is not indicative o uture results.

    Any orecasts provided herein are based upon the authors opinion o the market at this date and are subject to change, dependent on

    uture changes in the market. Any prediction, projection or orecast on the economy, stock market, bond market or the economic trends

    o the markets is not necessarily indicative o the uture or likely perormance. Investments are subject to risks, including possible loss

    o principal amount invested.

    Publication and distribution o this document may be subject to restrictions in certain jurisdictions.

    Deutsche Bank May 2013

    14

    R-31183-1 (4/13)

    Global Financial Institute