Cost of Food Monopolies

download Cost of Food Monopolies

of 55

Transcript of Cost of Food Monopolies

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    1/55

    Food MonopoliesThe Economic Cost of

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    2/55

    Food & Water Watch works to ensure the ood, waterand fsh we consume is sae, accessible and sustainable

    So we can all enjoy and trust in what we eat and drink,

    we help people take charge o where their ood comes

    rom, keep clean, aordable, public tap water owing

    reely to our homes, protect the environmental quality

    o oceans, orce government to do its job protecting

    citizens, and educate about the importance o keeping

    shared resources under public control.

    Food & Water Watch Caliornia Ofce

    1616 P St. NW, Ste. 300 25 Stillman St., Ste. 200

    Washington, DC20036 San Francisco, CA 94107

    tel: (202) 683-2500 tel: (415) 293-9900

    ax: (202) 683-2501 ax: (415) 293-8394

    [email protected] [email protected]

    www.oodandwaterwatch.org

    Copyright November 2012 by Food & Water Watch.

    All rights reserved.

    This report can be viewed or downloaded

    at www.oodandwaterwatch.org.

    About Food & Water Watch

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    3/55

    Execuive Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2

    Inroducion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

    Consolidaion in Iowas Hog Secor Erodes Rural Economies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

    Consolidaion and Collusion in he New York Dairy Indusry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

    Corporae Capure o Marylands Easern Shore . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

    Monopoly Conrol o Organic Soymilk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31

    Consolidaion and Globalizaion inCaliornias Processed Frui & Vegeable Indusry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

    Mehodology and Daa . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .41

    Appendix I. Agriculural Policy Analysis Cener

    a Universiy o Tennessee Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .42

    Appendix II. Esimaing Ne Gain From Shifing o Increased

    Frui & Vegeable Producion on Marylands Easern Shore . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

    Endnoes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    4/55

    2 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    Executive Summary

    The agriculure and ood secor is unusually concenraed,

    wih jus a ew companies dominaing he marke in

    each link o he ood chain. In mos secors o he U.S.

    economy, he our larges irms conrol beween 40 and

    45 percen o he marke, and many economiss mainain

    ha higher levels o concenraion can sar o erode

    compeiiveness.1 Ye according o daa compiled by he

    Universiy o Missouri-Columbia in 2012, in he agriculure

    and ood secor, he our larges companies conrolled 82percen o he bee packing indusry, 85 percen o soybean

    processing, 63 percen o pork packing, and 53 percen o

    broiler chicken processing.2

    Consolidaion is no isolaed o arms and processing. In

    1998, he our bigges ood reailers sold abou one-ifh

    (22 percen) o groceries.3 By 2010, reail concenraion had

    more han doubled and over hal o grocery sales wen o

    he our larges companies.4 Walmar became he naions

    larges ood reailer wihin a dozen years o opening is irs

    supercener in he lae 1990s.5

    The concenraion o economic power in every segmen

    o ood and agriculure can harm boh armers and

    consumers. Farmers can pay more or supplies when only

    a ew irms sell seeds, erilizer and racors. They also

    sell ino a highly consolidaed marke, and he ew irms

    bidding or crops and livesock can drive down he prices

    ha armers receive. Consumers have ewer choices a he

    supermarke, and ood processors and reailers are quick

    o raise prices when arm prices rise (as is anicipaed as a

    resul o he 2012 drough) bu are slow o pass savings on

    o consumers when arm prices all.

    Rural communiies ofen bear he brun o agribusiness

    consolidaion. For nearly 80 years, academic sudies have

    documened he negaive impac o agriculures consolida-

    ion and indusrializaion, which aligns arms more closely

    wih ood manuacurers han heir local communiies.

    The rising economic concenraion has conribued o he

    decline in he number o arms and he increased size in he

    arms ha remain. Communiies wih more medium- andsmaller-sized arms have more shared prosperiy, including

    higher incomes, lower unemploymen and lower income

    inequaliy, han communiies wih larger arms ied o

    ofen-disan agribusinesses.

    Agribusiness concenraion works in many ways, all wih

    same objecive: o move income rom armers and rural

    economies o Wall Sree. In his repor, we examine ive

    case sudies o agribusiness concenraion.

    Pork Producion in Iowa:Food & Waer Wach ound

    ha over he pas hree decades, he Iowa counies hasold he mos hogs and had he larges arms had declining

    couny-wide incomes, slower growh in median house-

    hold income and declining numbers o local businesses

    compared o he saewide average. Iowa armers sold

    wice as many hogs in 2007 (47.3 million) as in 1982 (23.8

    million), bu he oal real value o Iowas hog sales was 12

    percen lower in 2007. As pork packing consolidaed and

    hog arms in Iowa became larger and more inegraed wih

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    5/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 3

    he pork processing companies, he value o hogs o he

    local economy declined. These rends were conirmed by

    an economeric analysis by he Universiy o Tennessees

    Agriculural Policy Analysis Cener.

    Dairy Farming in New York:Milk processors and

    handlers in New York have come under such concenraed

    and coordinaed ownership ha he prices armers receive

    or heir milk have been pushed lower han wha heywould have received in a compeiive economic sysem wih

    more independen buyers. Food & Waer Wach compared

    wo New York dairy counies ha experienced dieren

    rends in he size and srucure o heir dairy secor. S.

    Lawrence Couny has ranked among he counies wih he

    mos dairy arms in New York or 30 years bu has shifed

    o ewer, larger arms.Yaes Couny sared wih very ew

    dairy arms bu was he only dairy couny in New York o

    have an increase in he number o arms. Yaes Couny had

    sronger economic perormance han S. Lawrence Couny,

    despie S. Lawrences saus as a dairy leader.Poulry Producion on Marylands Easern Shore:

    The rise o he indusrialized poulry indusry evenually

    ransormed he enire Easern Shore region rom a diverse

    agriculural mix o one dominaed by verically inegraed

    chicken producion. Food & Waer Wach esimaes ha

    i he arms on Marylands Easern Shore culivaed he

    same proporion o ruis and vegeables in 2007 as 1940,

    oal arm sales would have been $137 million higher 65

    percen more han wha conrac poulry growers received

    or raising chickens in 2007.6

    The Organic Soybean Marke: In 2009, he company

    ha owns Silk-brand soymilk, Dean Foods, shifed he

    ormerly organic produc o a naural label ha required

    no organic soybeans. The impac o his change rom

    organic o convenional soybeans is magniied because o

    Deans marke dominance in soymilk producion, and had

    subsanial ramiicaions or armers. The change rom

    organic o naural reduced he marke or organic soybean

    armers by 1.2 million bushels o ood-grade soybeans in

    he irs year.

    Frui and Vegeable Producion in Californias Cenral

    Valley: The global reach o ransnaional agribusiness

    gians can serve o drain wealh rom rural economies,

    as seen in he case o rui and vegeable producion in

    Caliornias Cenral Valley. Food & Waer Wach ound ha

    beween 1992 and 2007, as impors rose, one ou o eigh

    (12.7 percen) o he large reezing and canning plans in

    Caliornia closed.7 Fewer plans mean ewer workers bu

    also ewer oules or Caliornia armers o sell heir crops.

    Conclusions

    For decades, he U.S. Deparmen o Jusice and he U.S.

    Deparmen o Agriculure (USDA) have aken a hands-

    o approach o consolidaion in he ood sysem. The

    economic harm caused by he concenraion o he ood

    sysem is real, bu ofen negleced. Federal regulaors

    mus srenghen he oversigh o his highly consolidaed

    secor ha aecs every member o sociey every day. Fair

    markes will require new rules and beter oversigh ha:

    Collecs and disseminaes informaion abou

    concenraion hroughou he food chain: The

    ederal governmen should deermine he levels o

    concenraion in he various secors o he ood sysem

    rom arm inpus, ood processing, markeing and

    reailing.

    Coordinaes compeiion and anirus policy

    for he enire food and farm secor: The USDA

    should have a special counsels oice on agriculural

    consolidaion in he ood and arm secor o eecivelycoordinae beween he agencies wih jurisdicion over

    compeiion policy.

    Remedies and prevens disorions in he hog and

    catle markes: Currenly, several common pracices

    allow meapackers o avoid buying hogs and catle

    on public markes, which reduce compeiion and

    lower he price ha armers receive. These pracices,

    including meapackers ha buy catle and hogs wih

    opaque conracs ha do no give armers irm prices

    when he conracs are negoiaed (known as capive

    supplies) or meapackers ha own heir own livesock

    o avoid aucion markes when prices are higher, should

    be prohibied.

    Prevens unfair and decepive pracices in agri-

    culural conracing: Many armers raise livesock

    or crops under conrac wih large agribusinesses,

    bu because he ew irms have remendous leverage,

    armers are ofen orced ino ake-i-or-leave-i

    conracs ha can be unair or abusive. Fair conrac

    pracices should be spelled ou in regulaion and law.

    Fuure arm policy should ocus on access o air and open

    markes ha benei armers, workers, consumers and he

    markeplace. A every poin in he ood chain, here are

    a handul o companies squeezing prois ou o armers,

    wages ou o workers and choices ou o eaers. A more

    vibran markeplace wih more choices or armers and

    consumers is essenial, bu i canno happen wihou

    breaking up he agribusiness carels.

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    6/55

    4 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    Introduction

    Consolidaion in he ood and arm secor can sap he

    economic vialiy o rural communiies. Fewer naional

    companies selling arm inpus and buying crops and

    livesock means ha here are ewer small agriculural

    businesses providing producs and services o armers.

    Independen agriculural producers and he eed and

    equipmen dealers, locally owned grain elevaors, small

    slaugherhouses and medium-sized ood processing irms

    ha hey do business wih are he economic engine ha

    drives economic sabiliy in rural communiies. Consolida-

    ion has disabled ha engine, draining wealh and people

    ou o rural communiies.

    In a reely uncioning marke sysem, a balance will be

    sruck beween he incomes o armers, rural economies

    and disan invesors who urnish echnologies no easily

    provided in rural areas. Agribusiness concenraion works

    o change ha balance in avor o Wall Sree. As global

    agribusiness ineress grow and become more powerul, heincome o rural arm and non-arm residens declines.

    Consolidation in the Food System

    The agriculure and ood secor is unusually concenraed,

    wih jus a ew companies dominaing he marke in each

    link o he ood chain. In mos secors o he U.S. economy,

    he our larges irms conrol beween 40 and 45 percen

    o he marke, and many economiss mainain ha higher

    levels o concenraion can sar o erode compeiive-

    ness.8 Ye according o daa compiled by he Universiy

    o Missouri-Columbia in 2012, in he agriculure and ood

    secor, he our larges companies in agriculure and ood

    conrolled 82 percen o he bee packing indusry, 85

    percen o soybean processing, 63 percen o pork packing

    and 53 percen o broiler chicken processing.9 These

    naional concenraion measuremens can conceal even

    higher levels o concenraion a he regional or local level.

    Consolidaion is no isolaed o arms and processing. In

    1998, he our bigges ood reailers sold abou one-ifh

    (22 percen) o groceries.10 By 2010, reail concenraion had

    more han doubled, and over hal (53 percen) o grocerysales wen o he our larges companies.11 Walmar became

    he naions larges ood reailer wihin a dozen years o

    opening is irs supercener in he lae 1990s.12

    Large reailers now have so much buying power ha hey

    have considerable inluence over which oods are available

    o he public, he mehods in which he oods are produced

    and he prices paid o heir suppliers. Walmar is now

    he bigges cusomer or many o he op ood producers

    and processors in he counry, including dairy gian Dean

    Foods, General Mills, Kraf Foods and Tyson Foods,13 which

    can creae uneven power dynamics even or hese large

    companies.

    The Impact of Consolidation

    on Rural Economies

    For nearly 80 years, academic sudies have documened he

    negaive impac o agriculures consolidaion and indusri-

    alizaion, which aligns arms more closely wih ood manu-

    acurers han heir local communiies. Communiies wih

    more medium- and smaller-sized arms have more shared

    prosperiy, including higher incomes, lower unemploymen

    and lower income inequaliy, han communiies wih larger

    arms ied o ofen-disan agribusinesses.

    Economically viable independen arms are he lieblood o

    rural communiies,14 and arms have a greaer impac on

    local economies han he reail or service secors.15 Hisori-

    cally, rural economies have resed on a oundaion o manymid-sized arms and local agriculural processing.16 The

    earnings rom locally owned and locally conrolled arms

    generae an economic muliplier eec when armers

    buy heir supplies locally and he money says wihin he

    communiy.17 Larger, indusrialized arms are more likely o

    purchase arm supplies rom ouside he local communiy,

    and non-local arm owners siphon o a larger share o he

    prois rom hese operaions.18

    Among he irs sudies o examine he impac o larger,

    indusrialized arms on local communiies was a compar-ison o wo rural owns in Caliornia in he 1940s. Rural

    anhropologis Waler Goldschmid ound ha he own

    wih more small and moderae-sized arms had higher

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    7/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 5

    overall income and educaion levels and more civic and

    social organizaions.19 In conras, he communiy wih

    a higher prevalence o larger arms had worse economic

    oucomes and a lower sandard o living han when he

    agriculural economy was spread ou among many smaller

    arms.20 The U.S. Deparmen o Agriculure originally

    suppressed he indings o Goldschmids research, and he

    sudy was even burned in public in Caliornia.21

    Mos sudies esing he Goldschmid hypohesis since he

    Depression ound ha large, indusrialized arms had a

    derimenal eec on economic, social and environmenal

    communiy oucomes. A 2007 analysis o 51 sudies ound

    ha 82 percen showed some derimenal impacs o indus-

    rialized agriculure in local communiies, and more han

    hal (57 percen) had predominanly negaive indings.22

    Only 6 percen o sudies had largely posiive indings rom

    he impac o indusrialized agriculure.23

    Household income, poverty and inequality

    Larger-scale indusrialized arms ended o reduce he

    economic well-being o neighboring amilies, reduce house-

    hold incomes, increase povery and exacerbae economic

    inequaliy. A 2001 sudy ound ha counies wih more

    large arms had lower median amily incomes, whereas

    counies wih a sronger arming middle class had lower

    povery raes, lower levels o unemploymen, less violen

    crime and ewer low-weigh birhs.24

    Several sudies have shown rising income inequaliy in

    communiies wih larger, indusrialized arms.25 A 2004

    sudy ound ha he concenraion o armland ownershipwas associaed wih higher levels o income inequaliy.26 A

    1990 sudy ound ha areas wih more moderaely sized

    arms had lower povery and unemploymen raes, higher

    household income and a more sable and large middle

    class.27 In conras, he sudy ound ha communiies

    where larger, indusrial arms predominaed had higher

    income inequaliy and conribued o he long-erm decline

    o household incomes and rising povery raes.28

    Local spending

    A more vibran arming middle class pumps money inorural economies and Main Sree businesses. Small arms

    spend more locally han large arms, boh or arm supplies

    and household purchases ha have a muliplier eec on

    local economies.29 A 1994 deailed examinaion o line-iem

    expendiures by Minnesoa arms ound ha smaller arms

    spen wice as much locally as large arms (based on he

    share o heir purchases).30 Smaller livesock operaions (less

    han $400,000 in income) spen beween 60 and 90 percen

    o heir purchases locally compared o less han 50 percen

    o he purchases by arms wih income over $600,000.31 The

    erosion o arm numbers may have he larges eec on

    communiies ha rely on arms and he rural populaion

    o suppor local businesses in small owns.32 Many rural

    communiies worry ha he growing size o arms hreaens

    he survival o small owns and heir small businesses. 33

    Negative non-economic impactsConsolidaion in he arm secor and igh agribusiness

    linkages can also ray he civic abric o rural communiies,

    derimenally impac he healh and educaional well-being

    o rural residens and pollue he local environmen. As

    mid-sized amily arms disappear, so do people who ill

    church pews, atend schools, join civic organizaions and

    provide local governmen leadership.34 Indusrial arming

    can increase communiy sress, crime, eenage birh raes

    and in-migraion o low-wage workers, while overburdening

    local schools, worsening healh oucomes and reducing

    civic paricipaion and voing.35 Many communiies aceincreased environmenal impacs rom manure spills,

    declining air qualiy and reduced qualiy o lie rom odors

    rom large livesock operaions.36

    Food & Water Watchs Analysis

    Agribusiness concenraion works in many ways, all wih

    he same objecive: ha o moving income rom armers

    and rural economies o Wall Sree. In his repor, we

    examine ive case sudies o agribusiness concenraion.

    Pork Production in IowaIn Iowa, over he las hree decades, massive amouns

    o ouside money creaed processing plans ha became

    so large ha many smaller plans have been orced ou

    o business. Gradually, enormous processing plans were

    mached by super-sized acory arms avored by ouside

    agribusiness ineress. Food & Waer Wach has ound ha

    over he pas hree decades, he Iowa counies ha sold he

    mos hogs and had he larges arms had declining couny-

    wide incomes, slower growh in median household income

    and alling numbers o local businesses compared o he

    saewide average.

    Iowa armers sold wice as many hogs in 2007 (47.3 million)

    as in 1982 (23.8 million), bu he oal real value o Iowas

    hog sales was 12 percen lower in 2007. As pork packing

    consolidaed and hog arms in Iowa became larger and

    more inegraed wih he pork processing companies, he

    value o hogs o he local economy declined. These rends

    were conirmed by an economeric analysis by he Univer-

    siy o Tennessees Agriculural Policy Analysis Cener.

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    8/55

    6 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    Dairy Farming in New York

    This case sudy examines a exbook case o marke iner-

    erence. Milk processors and handlers in New York have

    come under such concenraed and coordinaed ownership

    ha he prices armers receive or heir milk have been

    pushed lower han wha hey would have received in a

    compeiive economic sysem wih more independen

    buyers. In 2009, dairy armers in New York and oher

    Norheas saes iled an anirus sui alleging ha hebigges milk processor and bigges milk handling coopera-

    ive worked in concer o eecively lower he prices ha

    armers receive.

    Food & Waer Wach compared wo New York dairy coun-

    ies wih dieren rends in heir dairy arms. S. Lawrence

    Couny has ranked among he counies wih he mos

    dairy arms in New York or 30 years bu has shifed o

    ewer, larger arms.Alhough S. Lawrence los 77 percen

    o is dairy arms beween 1982 and 2007, i remained ied

    or he couny wih he mos dairy arms in he sae in2007. Yaes Couny sared wih very ew dairy arms bu

    during he period we sudied, many small-scale Mennonie

    dairy armers migraed o he couny.37Yaes Couny was

    he only dairy couny in New York o have an increase in

    he number o arms and had sronger economic peror-

    mance han S. Lawrence Couny, despie S. Lawrences

    saus as a dairy leader.

    The Yaes Couny experience is more a cauionary ale han

    a model or mos armers o emulae. Mennonie armers

    use ewer inpus and expensive equipmen, rely on pleny

    o low-cos amily labor and ypically have litle arm deb.

    These are pre-condiions ha mos armers and communi-

    ies will be unable o replicae, and i is sriking ha he

    only couny o have growh in he number o dairy arms

    had hese unusual characerisics.

    Poultry Production on

    Marylands Eastern Shore

    Someimes a paricular agribusiness ineres can ake over

    an enire economy beore any compeiors can ener. The

    resuling siuaion is one o such economic dominance ha

    large regions can become, essenially, company sores inwhich all economic aciviy is guided by a single ineres.

    On he Easern Shore o Maryland, he rise o he indusri-

    alized poulry indusry evenually ransormed he enire

    region rom a diverse agriculural mix ha primarily grew

    vegeables and ruis o sell o Philadelphia, Balimore and

    Washingon, D.C., ino a region ha raised more han 300

    million chickens ha produce over hal a million pounds o

    chicken manure per square mile every year.38

    Food & Waer Wach esimaes ha i he arms on

    Marylands Easern Shore culivaed he same propor-

    ion o ruis and vegeables in 2007 as in 1940, oal arm

    sales would have been $137 million higher 65 percen

    more han he esimaed $83 million ha conrac poulry

    growers received or raising chickens or he poulry compa-

    nies in 2007.39

    The Organic Soybean MarketSome cases o agribusiness consolidaion are quie simple:

    he power ha comes wih concenraion can be used o

    change he rules in such a way as o eliminae arming

    opporuniies alogeher. In 2009, he company ha owns

    Silk-brand soymilk, Dean Foods, shifed he ormerly

    organic produc o a naural label ha required no

    organic soybeans. The impac o his change rom organic

    o convenional soybeans is magniied because o Deans

    marke dominance in soymilk producion and had subsan-

    ial ramiicaions or armers. The change rom organic o

    naural reduced he marke or organic soybean armers byover 1.2 million bushels o ood-grade soybeans in he irs

    year.

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    9/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 7

    Fruit and Vegetable Production

    in Californias Central Valley

    The global reach o ransnaional agribusiness gians can

    serve o drain wealh rom rural economies, as seen in

    he case o rui and vegeable producion in Caliornias

    Cenral Valley. Food & Waer Wach ound ha beween

    1992 and 2007, as impors rose, one ou o eigh (12.7

    percen) o he large reezing and canning plans in Cali-

    ornia closed.40 Fewer plans mean ewer workers bualso ewer oules or Caliornia armers o sell heir crops.

    Consolidaion and globalizaion in he canned and rozen

    rui and vegeable indusries allowed he ewer irms o

    reduce he prices hey paid o armers and shif producion

    overseas o ake advanage o lower wages and weaker

    environmenal proecions.

    Conclusions

    For decades, he U.S. Deparmen o Jusice and he USDA

    have aken a hands-o approach o ood sysem consoli-

    daion, on he grounds ha increased concenraion has

    no direcly harmed consumers. Agribusiness companies

    conend ha hrough mergers and acquisiions, hey can

    provide eiciencies o scale ha benei consumers. Bu in

    realiy, consumers rarely see a decrease in wha hey pay

    or ood a he grocery sore.

    The economic harm caused by he concenraion o he

    ood sysem is real, bu is ofen negleced. The larges

    players in agribusiness have been providing mos o he

    daa, allowing hem o perpeuae he myh ha he

    economy has beneied rom he eiciency oered by heindusrialized agriculure sysem. Meanwhile, independen,

    small and mid-sized producers oer irs-hand examples o

    he sorely needed compeiion-relaed reorms.

    Fair markes will require new rules and beter oversigh

    ha:

    Collecs and disseminaes informaion abou

    concenraion hroughou he food chain: The

    ederal governmen should deermine he levels o

    concenraion in he various secors o he ood sysem

    rom arm inpus (including seeds, agrochemicals,equipmen and credi), o ood processing (grain

    handling, slaugher and processing o livesock and

    poulry as well as ood manuacuring), o markeing

    and reailing (rom disribuion o grocery sores).

    Coordinaes compeiion and anirus policy for

    he enire food and farm secor:Currenly, several

    agencies have overlapping anirus jurisdicion over

    dieren elemens o he agriculure and ood indusry,

    which has hampered eecive enorcemen. The USDA

    should have a special counsels oice on agriculural

    consolidaion in he ood and arm secor o eecively

    coordinae beween he agencies wih jurisdicion over

    compeiion policy.

    Remedies and prevens disorions in he hog and

    catle markes: Currenly, several common pracices

    allow meapackers o avoid buying hogs and catle on

    public markes, which reduce compeiion and lower

    he price armers receive. Some companies own heir

    own livesock or long periods prior o slaugher, which

    allows hem o slaugher heir own livesock when

    aucion prices are high and buy on public markes

    when prices are low, which drives down he prices

    armers receive over he long erm. Some meapackers

    press armers o sell heir livesock hrough opaque

    conracs ha do no disclose he price armers will

    receive (armers only learn wha hey will ge or heir

    hogs or catle when hey are delivered o he mea-

    packer). The conracs ypically are based on aucion

    prices (known as ormula pricing), and since mea-

    packers have considerable livesock secured hrough

    hese capive supply conracs and packer-owned

    livesock, he cash aucion prices ha are he basis or

    ormula prices are ofen very low. These sraegies ha

    reduce he number o publicly raded livesock makes

    he markeplace subjec o disorion or manipulaion

    ha harms all armers. The capive supply arrange-

    mens and packer-ownership o livesock should be

    prohibied.

    Prevens unfair and decepive pracices in agri-

    culural conracing: Many armers raise livesock

    or crops under conrac wih large agribusinesses,

    bu because he ew irms have remendous leverage,

    armers are ofen orced ino ake-i-or-leave-i

    conracs ha can be unair or abusive. Fair conrac

    pracices should be spelled ou in regulaion and law.

    Fuure arm policy should ocus on access o air and open

    markes ha benei armers, workers, consumers and he

    markeplace. The goal should be policy ha allows here o

    be enough buyers o he crops and livesock and sellers oagriculural inpus ha he compeiive beneis o markes

    can work or armers.

    A every poin in he ood chain, here are a handul o

    companies squeezing prois ou o armers, wages ou

    o workers and choices ou o eaers. A more vibran

    markeplace wih more choices or armers and consumers

    is essenial, bu i canno happen wihou breaking up he

    agribusiness carels.

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    10/55

    8 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    Consolidation in Iowas Hog Sector

    Erodes Rural Economies

    Since he 1980s, he U.S. pork packing and processing

    indusry has gained a dominan posiion over hog armers

    hrough mergers, acquisiions and he emergence o

    conracual relaionships beween packers and producers.

    The hog producion secor is concenraed horizonally

    (only a ew companies buy, slaugher and process hemajoriy o hogs) and verically inegraed (hog packers

    have igh conracual relaionships wih hog producers

    hroughou he sages o producion).

    Iowa has long been a major player in U.S. hog and pork

    producion. Since here are ewer buyers or hogs and many

    packers procure hogs primarily hrough conracs wih large

    hog producers, independen armers ofen canno ge air or

    compeiive prices or heir hogs. The long-erm downward

    rend in real hog prices has orced some producers o heir

    arms and oher armers o massively expand heir hog

    operaions. Consolidaion in he pork packing indusry has

    conribued o he 82 percen decline in he number o hog

    arms in Iowa beween 1982 and 2007.41 The average-sized

    Iowa hog arm ballooned more han 10-old beween 1982

    and 2007. The shif o larger hog arms ighly inegraed

    wih he pork processing indusry has caused a concenra-

    ion o economic beneis o ewer armers and irms in

    rural communiies.42

    The debae over wheher large hog arms are a benei

    or a curse o communiies is conroversial. Proponens

    conend ha very large, indusrial-syle hog operaionsare more eicien and producive and generae wealh and

    prosperiy.43 Indusrial-scale hog producion is purpored

    o creae jobs, srenghen local ax bases and provide a

    muliplier eec hrough local economies.44 A 1998 sudy

    ound ha larger hog arms are associaed wih higher

    income and employmen levels.45 Iowa Sae Universiy

    esimaed ha he Iowa hog indusrys $4.3 billion in gross

    sales generaed $2.2 billion in personal income, 60,500 jobs

    and $3.86 billion in gross sae produc in 2005.46

    I is indispuable ha hog producion has a signiicanimpac on Iowas economy. Hog arms provide arm jobs,

    hog sales supply he meapacking secor ha employs addi-

    ional workers, and he arms hemselves generae income.

    These hog-relaed workers in urn induce addiional aciviy

    by spending heir earnings on goods and services, heorei-

    cally muliplying economic aciviy in he local communiy.

    Hog producion also drives demand or Iowas corn and

    soybean producion, which beneis armers and drives

    employmen and income hroughou he communiy.

    Bu Food & Waer Wach has ound ha as pork packing

    consolidaed and hog arms became larger and more

    inegraed wih he pork processing companies, he value

    o hogs o he local economy declined. Over he pas hree

    decades, he number o hogs sold by Iowa armers doubled

    o 47.3 million in 2007, bu he oal real value o Iowas

    hog sales was 12 percen lower in 2007 han in 1982, even

    hough Iowa armers sold 23.5 million more hogs. (See

    Figure 1.) As he value o hogs reverberaes hrough he

    economy, he economic ripples o hog producion in Iowaare becoming smaller and less valuable.

    Description of Study

    Food & Waer Wach analyzed he impac o consolidaion

    in he pork packing secor on Iowa hog arms and rural

    economies rom 1982 o 2007. The hog secor exempliies

    he indusrializaion o arming, wih he rapid decline in

    he number o hog producers, he sharp increase in he

    size o hog operaions and igher ies beween arms and

    speciic pork processors.47

    Iowa is he larges hog-producing sae in he counry48

    and has abou one-quarer o he naions hog slaugher

    capaciy.49 (See Table 1 on page 9.) The ransormaion o

    he Iowa hog secor is represenaive o changes in he

    hog secor hroughou he Unied Saes. Hisorically,

    independen hog producers were a oundaion o Iowas

    agriculure secor.50 Bu over he pas hree decades, hog

    producion changed signiicanly. Insead o being based on

    independen amily arm, small-scale producion, larger hog

    Figure 1.Value of Real Hog Sales Fallsas Total Number of Hogs Sold Doubles

    SOURCE: USDA

    Real Hog Sales(in Billions of 2010 Dollars)

    Number of Hogs Sold(in Millions)

    $5.8

    $4.8

    $3.9

    $4.1

    $3.7

    $5.1

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    23.8 23.5

    26.8 27.5

    41.2

    47.3

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    11/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 9

    irms ha are closely inegraed wih pork producion and

    disribuion chains became dominan in hog producion.51

    Food & Waer Wach analyzed couny-level hog arm,

    economic and demographic daa beween 1982 and 2007 in

    he ive-year inervals corresponding wih he USDA Census

    o Agriculure. The analysis builds on years o academic

    research and provides a more exensive longiudinal exami-

    naion o he impac o larger arms on he local economyspanning he rise o indusrial-scale hog arms and conrac

    inegraion wih pork packers. We analyzed he economic

    rends in he counies wih he mos hogs, he larges hog

    arms and he mos rural areas. Food & Waer Wach also

    commissioned he Agriculural Policy Analysis Cener a he

    Universiy o Tennessee o perorm a mulivariae regression

    analysis o measure he impac o agribusiness concenra-

    ion in hog producion on he Iowa economy.

    Food & Waer Wach ound ha each hog sold was making

    a smaller conribuion o he economy in 2007 han in 1982,

    measured by boh couny real oal personal income andreal median household income. Moreover, growing hog

    producion appears o increase income inequaliy, as he

    number o hogs sold has a bigger negaive impac on real

    household median income over ime han on real per capia

    income. Finally, he decline in he number o hog arms

    and rising average number o hogs sold per arm has a

    negaive impac on he number o reail sores, as here are

    ewer independen amily arms o paronize Main Sree

    businesses. Food & Waer Wachs indings are in line wih

    he Federal Reserve Bank o Kansas Ciys 1993 predicion

    ha, Many rural communiies will ace a decline in local

    economic aciviy as he number o small, independen hog

    armers erodes.52 (See mehodology and daa secion, page

    41, and Appendix I, page 42, or descripion o variables,

    economic model and regression analysis.)

    Meatpacker Consolidation,

    Control and Market PowerPork packers and processors are he gaekeepers o he hog

    and pork secor. Naionally, more han 70,000 hog armers

    sold mos o heir hogs o only a handul o irms in 2007.53

    The limied marke opporuniy orces armers o ake

    whaever prices meapackers oer or heir hogs.

    Over he pas ew decades, he bigges irms also have

    pushed armers o become more closely aligned wih

    packers hrough markeing agreemens and producion

    conracs. These arrangemens beween producers and

    packers, known as verical inegraion, have encouragedarmers o increase in size.

    Consolidaion in he hog slaugher indusry has nearly

    doubled over he pas hree decades as mergers signii-

    canly reduced he number o compeiors and increased

    marke concenraion. In 1982, he our larges irms

    slaughered one ou o hree hogs (35.8 percen) naion-

    ally, bu by 2007, he our bigges companies slaughered

    wo ou o hree hogs (65.0 percen).54 (See Figure 2 on

    page 10.) Mergers in he Iowa hog processing secor have

    Table 1. Iowa Hog Slaughter Facility Capacity, 20052011 (HEAD PER DAY)

    SOURCE: National Pork Board 200920012

    PLANT LOCATION 2005 2007 2009 2011

    IOWA TOTAL 117,800 117,050 124,950 112,050

    0RUUHOO6PLWKHOG Sioux City 14,500 11,200 14,000 Closed

    )DUPODQG6PLWKHOG Denison 9,200 9,200 9,300 9,400

    Tyson Foods/IBP Waterloo 19,200 19,350 19,350 19,350

    Tyson Foods/IBP Storm Lake 15,000 15,500 15,500 16,500

    Tyson Foods/IBP Colorado Junction 9,800 9,500 10,000 9,850

    Tyson Foods/IBP Perry 6,800 7,400 7,400 7,750

    Swift ( JBS) Marshalltown 18,500 18,500 18,500 18,500

    Excel (Cargill) Ottumwa 18,000 18,000 18,500 18,400

    Sioux-Preme Packing Sioux Center 3,500 3,500 4,200 4,200

    Pine Ridge Farms Des Moines 2,500 2,500 2,850 3,200

    Premium Iowa Pork Hospers 1,600 2,400 2,500

    Dakota Pork Esthersville 1,500 1,200

    Vershoor Meats Sioux City 800 800 1,200 1,200

    VanDeRose Farms Wellsburg 250 Closed

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    12/55

    10 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    reduced he number o buyers. Since he 1990s, Smihieldabsorbed compeiors including John Morrell and Farm-

    land, which had aciliies in Iowa.55 In 2001, Tyson Foods

    bough IBP, which has our hog packing plans in Iowa. 56

    Naional concenraion measuremens can conceal much

    higher marke concenraion ha armers ace a he

    regional or local level.57 Beween 2004 and 2011, he plans

    owned by he op our pork packing irms slaughered nine

    ou o 10 hogs in Iowa.58 (See Figure 3.) Iowa armers may

    sell heir hogs over he sae line, bu even including he

    packing plans in Minnesoa, Nebraska, norhern Missouriand wesern Illinois, Iowa armers sold heir hogs ino a

    marke where he our larges irms slaughered our ou o

    ive hogs (79 percen on average beween 2004 and 2011). 59

    The rise of contracting and vertical integration

    Mergers have concenraed he marke power o pork

    packers, bu hey also exer considerable power hrough

    verical inegraion. Pork packers ofen secure livesock

    hrough conrac markeing arrangemens wih armers.

    Farmers agree o deliver a cerain number o hogs a a

    uure dae (ypically, he price is o be deermined adelivery). These conracs give armers a guaraneed marke

    or heir hogs, bu large conrac buyers can exrac lower

    prices and disor and conceal prices. (In anoher ype o

    conrac arrangemen, known as a producion conrac,

    pork packers own he hogs and hire armers o raise hem.

    Producion conracs are more common in he Souheas,

    such as in hog-powerhouse Norh Carolina, and can ofen

    impose exploiaive conrac erms on armers.)

    Pork packers can use markeing conracs o secure live-

    sock wihou having o bid agains oher packers o buy

    hogs a aucion.60 Conracs also reduce ransacion coss

    or packers because conrac hog arms end o be much

    larger. Pork packers would preer o have ewer, larger

    purchases insead o many ransacions necessary o buy

    smaller volumes o hogs rom more, independen armers.61

    Conracs have been commonplace in some agriculuralsecors, such as poulry, or decades bu have been a rela-

    ively new phenomenon in he hog secor. Beween 1991

    and 1993, here were oo ew hog conracs or he USDA

    o coun; by 2008, wo-hirds o hogs were delivered under

    conrac.62 (See Figure 4 on page 11.) This indusrializaion

    larger arms wih igher markeing relaionships wih

    processors weakens he economic links beween arms

    and local communiies.63

    Vertical integration and contracts

    encourage larger hog farms

    Larger pork processors end o conrac wih he larges

    arms, and, over ime, his drives all armers o increase he

    number o hogs hey raise and marke. The USDA ound

    ha larger meapackers reliance on conracing [m]ay

    also encourage larger arms.64 The Federal Reserve Bank o

    Kansas Ciy repored, The shif oward a more inegraed

    indusry works hand-in-hand wih he rend oward ewer

    and larger hog arms. 65

    Figure 2.National Market Shareof Top Four Hog Packers

    SOURCE: USDA GIPSA

    35.8%

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    36.6%

    43.8%

    54.3% 55.0%

    65.0%

    Figure 3.Market Share of Top Four Hog

    Packers in Iowa and Surrounding States

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of National Pork Board 2009-2012 data

    2004 2005 2006 2007 2009 2011

    Iowa and Surrounding StatesIowa

    94.2% 94.2% 92.8%90.1% 89.0%

    81.2%78.7% 77.8% 76.8%

    84.6%

    75.6%

    94.2%

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    13/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 11

    Consolidaed meapackers primarily do business wih

    he larges operaions and are relucan o deal wih

    medium-sized or smaller producers.66 The resuls o a 1993

    survey o hog armers and processors suggesed ha he

    larges packers conrac almos enirely wih he larges

    hog producers and may no even oer conracs o small

    producers.67 Hal o he pork packers ha used markeing

    conracs in 1994 required hog producers o deliver a

    minimum supply o hogs.68

    Ofen meapackers oer sweehear deals wih higherprices o larger, avored irms, irrespecive o he number o

    hogs ha are delivered o he slaugherhouse. Theoreically,

    meapackers pay armers based on qualiy using a carcass

    meri pricing sysem (known as a grid), bu his sysem

    gives meapackers he discreion o pay premiums and

    discouns ha can provide wide variaions in paymen

    more han 25 percen or hogs o he same qualiy.69 As

    Chris Peerson, Presiden o he Iowa Farmers Union and

    a hog producer, repored a a 2010 livesock compeiion

    workshop held by he U.S. Deparmen o Jusice and he

    USDA:

    The packers routinely pay $0.05 to $0.06 more per

    pound or more in volume-based premiums to the

    largest hog producers simply because theyre large.

    $0.06 may not sound like much of a discount. But I

    tell you what, for an independent producer, the guy

    with 150 sows, farrow-to-finish operation, trying

    to market on a yearly basis, that equals $56,000 of

    income.70

    Lower Hog Prices, Farm Losses

    and Increasing Farm Size

    Buyer power

    Consolidaion gives he bigges irms more bargaining

    power over he many arms hey buy rom and can have

    a signiican impac on armers marke access.71 This

    anicompeiive buyer power is known as monopsony.

    The decline in he number o hog buyers has lef ewerselling opions or hog producers, which pus hem under

    increased pressure o ake whaever price hey can ge,

    even i i does no cover heir coss. When here are only a

    ew buyers, here are no enough compeing buyers o bid

    up prices.72

    A 1999 economic model by Purdue Universiy esimaed

    ha a markeplace wih 20 equally sized pork packers (akin

    o he naional marke in he lae 1980s) would pay abou

    5 percen less han a perecly compeiive markeplace;

    a markeplace wih eigh irms would pay 18 percen

    less, and i here were only our irms, hey would pay 28

    percen less han a perecly compeiive marke.73 The

    auhors concluded, We have shown ha greaer consolida-

    ion in he mea packing and processing indusry creaes

    a markdown eec on he prices armers receive or live

    animals.74

    Thinning the market

    Conracing can urher depress hog prices.Conracs

    shor-circui he price discovery uncions o he marke-

    place by securing supplies ouside o he public aucions or

    spo markes where hogs (or oher commodiies) are soldor cash or immediae delivery.75 The price or conrac

    hogs is ypically ied o he spo or uures marke prices, so

    meapackers benei when uures and spo prices decline.

    The rise o verical inegraion and livesock conracing

    hins he open-aucion marke or hogs.76 Since ewer

    livesock are sold on he open marke, he number o public

    ransacions and reporable sales prices ha are he basis

    or many livesock conracs declines.77 This creaes he

    poenial or pork packers and processors o manipulae hog

    prices across he indusry. For example, he basis price orhog conracs is ypically he prevailing mid-morning upper

    Midwes marke price, which allows pork-processor buyers

    o wihhold heir purchases unil he afernoon o drive

    down prices paid under conrac.78

    Smaller arms ace ewer opions o marke heir hogs and

    can become he suppliers o las resor when large packers

    need exra hogs or heir slaugher aciliies.79 Since mos

    hogs are delivered o packers under conrac arrangemens,

    Figure 4.Percent of HogsDelivered Under Marketing

    or Production Contracts

    SOURCE: USDA

    1991-1993 1996-1997 2001-2002 2005 2008

    N/A

    34.2%

    62.5%

    76.2%

    68.1%

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    14/55

    12 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    he hogs sold by independen armers eecively are sold on

    markes ha have he characerisics o a salvage marke,

    as economiss rom Purdue Universiy noed.80

    Fewer public ransacions leave he markes suscepible

    o volailiy, disorion and manipulaion, since even a

    ew sales can have a signiican impac on he prices ha

    armers receive. The rise o hog conracing can conribue

    o he long-erm downward pressure on price and increase

    price volailiy.81 The hog marke was wice as volaile in

    he 1990s han in he previous wo decades.82 Over he pas

    25 years, real hog prices ell by 55 percen, rom $241 per

    head in 1982 o $109 in 2007, in real inlaion-adjused 2010

    dollars.83 (See Figure 5.) Afer he hog marke crashed in

    1998, he price has coninued o lucuae by as much as a

    hird every ew monhs.84 (See Figure 6.)

    Hog farm loss and increase in hog farm sizeFarmers receiving lower prices or hogs ofen ace he sark

    choice o going ou o business or selling more hogs o earn

    he same income. These pressures o low prices combined

    wih conracs ha encouraged larger-scale hog producion

    conribued o he decline in he number o hog arms in

    Iowa and he growh in he size o he remaining arms.

    Naionally, he number o arms selling hogs has plum-

    meed 76 percen rom 315,000 in 1982 o 74,800 in 2007. 85 I

    Iowa, he number o arms markeing hogs dropped aser,

    alling 82 percen rom 49,000 in 1982 o 8,760 in 2007. (See

    Figure 7.)

    Fewer arms did no mean ewer hogs. In ac, he oal

    number o hogs markeed annually in Iowa doubled beween

    1982 and 2007, meaning ha he size o he remaining

    hog arms expanded dramaically. Naionally, he average

    number o hogs sold by each arm has ballooned over

    he pas hree decades, growing nineold o an average o

    2,765 hogs in 2007.86 In Iowa, he number o hogs sold rom

    average hog arms surged more han 10-old over he pas

    Figure 5.Real Iowa Hog Priceand Market Share of Top Four Firms

    SOURCE: USDA; GIPSA

    $241

    35.8%

    Iowa Real Hog Price(Per Hog, in 2010 Dollars)

    Top Four NationalMarket Share

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    $204

    $145 $151

    $100$109

    36.6%

    43.8%

    54.3% 55.0%

    65.0%

    Figure 6.National Real Farmgate Hog Prices(IN 2010 DOLLARS PER HUNDREDWEIGHT)

    SOURCE: USDA NASS

    Jan-90 Jan-95 Jan-00 Jan-05 Jan-10

    $120

    $100

    $80

    $60

    $40

    $20

    Figure 7.Number of Iowa Hog Farms

    SOURCE: USDA Census of Agriculture

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    49,012

    38,638

    34,058

    18,370

    11,2758,758

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    15/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 13

    hree decades, and by 2007 he average Iowa hog arm

    sold nearly wice as many hogs as he naional average. In

    1982, he average Iowa arm sold 470 hogs, bu by 2007 he

    average arm markeed more han 5,000 hogs. (SeeFigure 8.)

    In he las wo decades, hog producion has become

    concenraed ino arms ha specialize in a single sage

    o producion (arrowing, nursery pigs and inishing hogs)

    ha are linked ogeher by pork processing inegraorshrough conacs.87 In 1992, more han hal (54 percen) o

    hog operaions were arrow-o-inish arms ha sold he

    hogs ha were born on heir arms; by 2004, less han a

    hird (31 percen) were arrow-o-inish.88 Feeder-o-inish

    operaions ha aten hogs or slaugher provided a ifh

    (22 percen) o marke hogs in 1992, bu hree-quarers (77

    percen) in 2004.89

    Many academic, governmen and indusry observers

    sugges ha bigger arms are more eicien because o

    economies o scale. However, hese advanages are signii-

    canly oversaed. Mos o he economies-o-scale eiciencygains occur when small arms grow o be mid-sized, bu

    hese gains aper o rapidly as he arms ge larger, so

    increased size provides a diminishing eiciency and cos

    advanage. Hog arms wih he lowes cos o producion

    per hog marke abou 1,000 hogs a year.90

    Eiciency gains rom increasing size beyond a cerain poin

    are modes. An analysis o hog producion in Iowa ound

    ha large hog arms had only small labor advanages over

    medium-sized arms. Whereas i ook hree workers o

    marke 10,000 hogs on medium-sized arms (wih invenorybeween 2,000 and 5,000 hogs), i ook only slighly ewer

    workers (2.88) on arms wih more han 5,000 head.91

    The Declining Impact of Large-scale

    Hog Farms on Iowas Economy

    Alhough he number o hogs sold in Iowa has doubled over

    he pas hree decades (see Figure 9), Food & Waer Wach

    has ound ha hogs are providing a diminished benei o

    Iowas economy. These indings suppor nearly a cenury

    o academic and public policy sudies ha have ound ha

    larger, indusrial arms have lowered he economic andsocial vialiy o local communiies.

    The lieraure on he impac o large, indusrial arms on

    economic growh, household economic well-being, jobs and

    unemploymen, local purchases by arms as well as non-

    economic indicaors including healh, educaional and pollu-

    ion oucomes includes several sudies ha examine he hog

    secor in paricular. These sudies generally suppor Food

    & Waer Wachs indings ha more hogs are providing a

    diminishing benei o Iowas economy. For example, a 1996

    sudy o Iowa hog producion ound ha he number o

    hogs is no as imporan as he number o hog arms o he

    economic well-being o local communiies.92

    Economic growth and inequality

    Several academic sudies have documened ha economic

    growh is more sluggish in communiies wih a higherprevalence o large, indusrialized arms. A 2003 sudy o

    nearly 2,250 rural counies naionwide ound ha counies

    wih larger arms had lower levels o economic growh,

    suggesing ha larger arms make smaller conribuions o

    local economies.93 The counies ha were mos economi-

    cally relian on agriculure and he counies wih he larges

    arms had slower per capia income growh.94

    A 2000 Illinois Sae Universiy sudy o 1,100 Illinois

    owns ound ha larger hog arms did no conribue

    Figure 8.Average Number

    of Hogs Sold per Iowa Farm

    SOURCE: USDA Census of Agriculture

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    470 584747

    1,454

    3,582

    5,068

    Figure 9.Total Hogs Sold by Iowa Farmers(IN MILLIONS)

    SOURCE: USDA

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    27.5

    41.2

    47.3

    26.823.523.8

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    16/55

    14 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    The Statistical Story

    of Hog ConcentrationA statistical analysis conducted by the Agricultural Policy

    Analysis Center (APAC) at the University of Tennessee

    FRQUPHGZKDWHFRQRPLFWKHRU\FRPPRQVHQVHDQGWKH

    graphs from this report all say: agribusiness concentration

    drains value from rural economies. (SeeAppendix I, page 42.)

    What Was Analyzed

    7KH$3$&VWXG\DQDO\]HGWKHVHYHYDULDEOHVIRUDOORZD

    counties for 1982, 1987, 1992, 1997, 2002, and 2007:

    1. Real county-level total personal income

    2. Real county-level median household income

    3. Percent of county residents with a B.A. degree or higher

    4. Percent of county residents in the prime working age

    range of 2564

    5. The number of hogs sold in each county

    What Was Done

    (DFKRIWKHODVWWKUHHYDULDEOHVDERYHHGXFDWLRQDJHDQGKRJSURGXFWLRQVKRXOGDHFWWKHUVWWZRYDULDEOHVRQWKH

    list. Econometrics is a powerful statistical technique that allowed APAC to analyze the hundreds of data observations

    LQWKLVVWXG\DQGJDLQLQVLJKWLQWRWKHTXDQWLWDWLYHHHFWWKDWHDFKRIWKHODVWWKUHHYDULDEOHVKDGRQWKHUVWWZR

    7KH$3$&DQDO\VLVZDVGRQHLQWZRVWDJHV7KHUVWVWDJHLQYHVWLJDWHGWKHGHJUHHWRZKLFKHGXFDWLRQDJHDQGKRJ

    SURGXFWLRQDHFWHGUHDOFRXQW\OHYHOWRWDOSHUVRQDOLQFRPHDQGUHDOFRXQW\OHYHOPHGLDQKRXVHKROGLQFRPH7KH

    second stage examined how the contribution of hog production to the two income variables had shifted over time to

    GHWHUPLQHZKHWKHUSURGXFLQJDGGLWLRQDOKRJVLQKDGWKHVDPHHHFWRQORFDOLQFRPHYDULDEOHVDVLWGLGLQ

    Snapshot of Results

    As expected, education and age played important positive roles in explaining local income in every year. But the

    VWRU\ZLWKKRJSURGXFWLRQZDVPXFKGLHUHQWQDQGDGGLQJPRUHKRJSURGXFWLRQWRDORFDOHFRQRP\

    KDGDVWURQJSRVLWLYHHHFW%XWEHJLQQLQJLQWKHORFDOHFRQRPLFEHQHWVRIDGGLWLRQDOKRJSURGXFWLRQEHJDQ

    to decline. For 1997, 2002 and 2007, local economies gained far less value from additional hog production than they

    had gained in 1982 and 1987. In fact, the results of the analysis strongly suggest that adding more hogs to rural Iowa

    counties loweredreal county-level personal income in 1997, 2002 and 2007.

    $GGLWLRQDOKRJSURGXFWLRQKDGDSRVLWLYHHHFWRQUHDOPHGLDQKRXVHKROGLQFRPHIRURZDFRXQWLHVEXWWKHPDJQL-

    tude of the contribution declined over time. The contribution of a given level of additional hog production in 1992

    was 59 percent lower than it was in 19821987. The contribution of additional hog production further declined during

    19972007 and was 76 percent lower than it was in 19821987.

    7KHVWRU\ZDVWKHVDPHIRUUHDOWRWDOSHUVRQDOLQFRPHZLWKRQHVLJQLFDQWH[FHSWLRQWKHFRQWULEXWLRQRIDGGLWLRQDO

    hog production in 19972007 was negative. The contribution of additional hog production was positive in 19821987

    and in 1992. The 1992 contribution, however, was 91 percent lower than it was in 19821987. By 19972007, thecontribution of additional hog production to real total personal income had turned negative. Adding an additional

    1,000 hogs in a county reduced total personal income in that county by $592.

    Conclusion

    Hog production can contribute to, or detract from, the level of overall economic activity in a rural county. In 1982 and

    1987, the contribution of hog production to Iowas rural economies was positive. But as time went on, and agribusi-

    QHVVFRQFHQWUDWLRQLQFUHDVHGWKHRZRIHFRQRPLFEHQHWVUHYHUVHG*URZWKLQWKHFRQVROLGDWHGKRJLQGXVWU\

    became a mechanism for draining value from, and not adding to, Iowas rural economies.

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    17/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 15

    o he vialiy o local economies and insead ended o

    hamper rural economic growh.95 The rural owns where

    hog arms became signiicanly larger beween he 1980s

    and 1990s appear o have had slower economic growh han

    owns wih less-rapid hog producion increases.96 A 2000

    Universiy o Minnesoa docoral hesis ound ha small

    hog-inishing operaions conribued more o he value-

    added income o local economies han large hog-inishing

    operaions.97 The 1996 Iowa sudy ound ha he counieswih more hog producers had ewer people relying on ood

    samps and ha counies wih more large-scale hog arms

    (over 1,000 head) had higher levels o ood samp use.98

    Local purchase

    Large-scale livesock operaions are more likely han smaller

    livesock arms o bypass local suppliers or inpus like eed

    and equipmen. Alhough larger arms make a smaller share

    o heir purchases locally, i could sill amoun o more local

    spending since large arms have higher oal expendiures.

    Bu he same number o hogs raised on a larger number osmall- and medium-sized arms would spend more locally

    han a ew gian arms.

    These rends have been conirmed by academic sudies. A

    1993 survey o Iowa hog producers ound ha as arms go

    larger, hey were less likely o buy eed wihin 10 miles o

    heir arms. More han hree-ifhs o medium-sized and

    small hog producers bough eed wihin 10 miles (62.0 and

    68.8 percen, respecively), compared o 41.7 percen o large

    arms.99 The newer, larger, specialized hog operaions are

    mos likely o make purchases ouside he local area.100

    A 1990 sudy ound ha larger Michigan hog operaions

    spen less locally han smaller arms. Farms wih 500 hogs

    spen $67 per head locally compared o $46 per head spen

    by arms wih 5,000 hogs.101 Using hese values, a larger arm

    would spend $230,000 locally compared o he $33,550 by he

    smaller arm. Bu en 500-head arms would spend $100,000

    more locally han a single 5,000-head arm. (SeeFigure 10.)

    Income Lower in Counties With

    Higher Hog Sales and Larger Hog Farms

    Economic sudies o hog arming in Iowa ofen ocus only on

    he arm impacs or only on he meapacking and processing

    indusries. While valuable, such sudies miss an imporan

    poin: agribusiness concenraion in Iowa is so widespread

    ha i ripples hroughou he enire rural economy. Food &

    Waer Wach ound ha he counies wih he highes levels

    o hog sales (he op hal o counies based on he number

    o hogs sold or each year) and he larges hog arms (he

    op hal o counies based on he average number o hogs

    sold per arm or each year) in Iowa had lower couny real

    personal income, real median household income and real pe

    capia income han he saes oal income measuremens.

    Alhough he real oal personal income in Iowa grew

    seadily over he pas hree decades, i declined in he coun-

    ies where hog producion was he highes. Toal saewide

    real personal income grew by hal (53.9 percen), rom $73.3

    billion in 1982 o $112.9 billion in 2007, in inlaion-adjused2010 dollars.102 (SeeFigure 11.) In conras, oal couny real

    personal income declined by 1.7 percen in he counies wih

    he highes number o hog sales, rom $39.6 billion in 1982

    $38.9 billion in 2007. Almos all o Iowas increase in oal rea

    personal income occurred in he counies wih he lowes

    level o hog sales; real oal personal income more han

    Figure 10.Local Spending by Hog Farms

    SOURCE: Albeles-Alison & Conner 1990

    One 500-headhog operation

    One 5,000-headhog operation

    5,000 hogs on 10500-head farms

    $33,550

    $233,000

    $335,500

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA Census of Agricul-ture, Commerce Department Bureau of Economic Analysis data.

    Figure 11.Total Real Personal Income,Statewide and Counties With High Hog Sales

    (IN BILLIONS OF 2010 DOLLARS)

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    $73.3$78.6

    $82.1

    $93.4

    $102.3

    $112.9

    $39.6

    $47.0$42.3

    $37.1$33.8

    $38.9

    High Hog Sales Counties

    Statewide

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    18/55

    16 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    doubled in he hal o he counies wih he lowes level o

    hog sales.103

    Alhough oal real personal income dropped slighly in

    counies wih high hog sales, he decline was signiicanly

    seeper in counies wih large hog arms. Since 1982, he

    oal real personal income dropped 19.1 percen in large hog

    arm counies, rom $34.4 billion o $27.8 billion in 2007. (See

    Figure 12.) Hog arm size in he hal o counies wih he

    larges arms increased 13-old rom an average o 561 hog

    sales per arm in 1982 o 7,400 in 2007.

    Real household median income shows a similar patern.

    Median household income measures he economic well-

    being o households a he midpoin o he earnings curve

    and is a good represenaion o he economic success

    o ordinary amilies. Saewide, he couny real median

    household income rose 14.5 percen, rom $41,186 in 1982

    o $47,177 in 2007, in 2010 inlaion-adjused dollars.104 (See

    Figure 13.)

    Counies wih he larges hog sales saw smaller increases

    in real median income. Real median household income

    Figure 12.Total Real Personal Income, Statewide and Counties With Large Hog Farms(IN BILLIONS OF 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA, Bureau of Economic Analysis data

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    $73.3

    $78.6$82.1

    $93.4

    $102.3

    $112.9

    $34.4$37.8 $37.0

    $32.3$27.1 $27.8

    Statewide Large Hog Farm Counties

    Average Hogs Sold Per Farm in Large Hog Farm Counties

    $45,698

    $42,588

    $44,339

    $48,697

    $45,823

    $46,852

    Figure 13.Real Median Household Income, Statewide and Counties With High Hog Sales(IN 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA, BEA data

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    Statewide High Hog Sales Counties

    Average Hogs Sold per Iowa Farm

    $44,091

    $41,186

    $43,550

    $47,838

    $46,174

    $47,172

    470 584747

    1,454

    3,582

    5,068

    5,102

    7,406

    561 703906

    1,978

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    19/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 17

    increased only 10.0 percen or counies wih he highes

    number o markeed hogs. There was a similar rend or

    large hog arm counies, which had real median household

    income increase only 8.7 percen beween 1982 and 2007.

    The economic downurn in he early 2000s drove median

    incomes down, bu he weak economic recovery beween

    2002 and 2007 sill lef median household incomes lower

    han in 1997. From 1982 o 1997, when he average-sizedarm sold ewer han 1,500 hogs a year, he real median

    income was higher in he counies wih he highes hog

    sales han he sae average. Bu afer he 1998 crash in

    hog prices, he number o arms ell urher and he size

    o arms swelled considerably. From 2002 o 2007, when

    he average arm size opped 3,500 hogs sold annually,

    he saewide real median income exceeded he larges

    hog-producing counies. Saewide, real median household

    incomes declined 3.5 percen beween 1997 and 2002, bu

    he decline was nearly wice as seep (5.9 percen) in he

    larges hog-producing counies.The real per capia earnings are growing in he coun-

    ies wih he larges hog sales while he real household

    median incomes are declining, which suggess ha income

    inequaliy is growing in he counies selling he mos hogs.

    (See Figure 14.) Income inequaliy can be demonsraed

    when average income growh exceeds median income

    growh.105 Beween 1982 and 2007, he real average house-

    hold income (based on per capia income and household

    size) rose by 33.0 percen rom $66,217 in 1982 o $88,068

    in 2007, bu he real median household income rose by only

    10.0 percen, abou a hird as as as he average household

    income. The rise in real per capia income alongside a less

    robus increase in median household income suggess ha

    earnings are being capured by a smaller porion o more-

    well-o people in counies wih high hog sales.

    Retail and Small Businesses

    Decline in Counties With Higher

    Hog Sales and Larger Hog Farms

    Food & Waer Wachs analysis o Iowa small business and

    reail paterns and hog arms conirms ha larger armsand increased numbers o hog sales are associaed wih

    declining numbers o small businesses, ewer reail esab-

    lishmens and lower reail sales. High hog sales counies

    and large hog arm counies had a sharp decline in small

    businesses (based on he Census Bureaus couny business

    survey number o non-arm esablishmens), reail sales

    esablishmens (based on Iowa Deparmen o Revenue

    sales ax records) and oal reail sales. (Seemehodology

    and daa secion, page 41.)

    Over he las hree decades, he oal number o small

    businesses in Iowa (non-arm esablishmens) increased

    by 29.7 percen, rom 64,000 in 1982 o 83,000 in 2007. In

    conras, he number o small businesses in he counies

    wih he op hal o hog sales ell by 10.8 percen. (See

    Figure 15.) The decline also shows a saewide relocaion o

    small businesses away rom areas wih he mos hog sales.

    In 1982, more han hal o small businesses (54.6 percen)

    were locaed in high hog sales counies, bu by 2007, only ahird (37.5 percen) o small businesses were locaed in he

    op hog sales counies.

    Figure 14.Real Median Household Incomeand Real Average Household Income,

    Counties With High Hog Sales (IN 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: USDA, BEA, Census Bureau; average household incomebased on per capita income and household size.

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    $66,217$72,383 $71,649

    $80,049 $80,176$88,068

    $42,588$45,698 $44,339

    $48,697$45,823 $46,852

    Real Median Household Income

    Real Average Household Income

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA, Census Bureau data

    Figure 15.Average Number of Non-FarmEstablishments per Iowa County

    Statewide High Hog SalesCounties

    Large Hog FarmCounties

    647

    722 7

    67 8

    14

    818

    839

    699

    849

    806

    678

    597

    624

    615

    702

    719

    589

    461

    464

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    20/55

    18 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    There is a similar patern or he counies wih he larges

    average hog arm size, which conirms he indings rom

    he academic lieraure ha smaller arms are more likely o

    buy and shop locally and ha his local purchasing rever-

    beraes hroughou Main Sree business communiies. The

    large hog arm counies los a quarer (24.4 percen) o heir

    small businesses over he pas hree decades (again, while

    he number o small businesses saewide increased).

    A similar patern holds rue or reail esablishmens

    (businesses ha ile sae sales ax receips) and real reail

    sales. Alhough he number o reailers in Iowa declined

    by 2.7 percen beween 1982 and 2007, he high hog sales

    and large hog arm counies had a much sharper decline

    in reailers. High hog sales counies los 29.0 percen o

    reail esablishmens, and large hog arm counies los 38.0

    percen o reailers. (SeeFigure 16.)

    Much o he decline in reailers may be he resul o super-

    sores driving ou independen grocery, hardware and oher

    independen reailers,106 bu heoreically he level o reailsales should coninue o grow wih he broader economy.

    Iowa saewide real reail sales increased by 11.4 percen

    rom $29.7 billion in 1982 o $33.0 billion in 2007, bu real

    reail sales dropped by a hird (35.3 percen) in high hog

    sales counies and by hal (53.5 percen) in large hog arm

    counies. (SeeFigure 17.) By 2007, consumers were spending

    $5.5 billion less in high hog sales counies and $7.3 billion

    less in large arm counies han hey spen in 1982, in

    inlaion-adjused 2010 dollars. This suppors he Illinois

    Sae Universiy sudy ha ound ha owns surrounded by

    larger hog arms had lower levels o reail spending.107

    Total Employment and

    Farm Jobs Decline in Hog Counties

    The value o hog sales conribues o employmen on arms,

    in meapacking plans and hroughou he economy. Bu

    he levels o local employmen and he qualiy o he jobs

    are inerrelaed wih he srengh o independen amily

    arms in rural areas.108 More workers would be employed i

    he same number o hogs were raised on smaller arms.109

    Fewer, bu larger, arms reduce he number o arm jobopporuniies in rural communiies.110

    Farm jobs in Iowa have declined seadily, and mos o

    hese losses are likely on hog arms. In he Midwes, hog

    arms (and dairy arms, a minor acor in Iowa) employ

    he majoriy o arm workers because bee catle and crop

    operaions require less labor.111 Saewide, Iowa los 41.6

    percen o is arm jobs beween 1982 and 2007, shedding

    almos 64,000 jobs. Mos o he arm job losses were in he

    counies wih he highes levels o hog sales. (See Figure

    18 on page 19.) High hog sales counies los 42,600 arm

    jobs (46.0 percen), and large hog arm counies los almos

    36,400 (44.3 percen).

    Food & Waer Wach ound ha he rising number o hog

    sales has no increased oal employmen. High hog sales

    counies and large hog arm counies had declining numbers

    o wage and salary jobs. Saewide, Iowa gained nearly hal

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA, Iowa Departmentof Revenue data

    Figure 16.Average Number of Retail

    Establishments per Iowa County

    Statewide High Hog SalesCounties

    Large Hog FarmCounties

    3,4

    80

    3,5

    65

    3,5

    64

    3,6

    48

    3,4

    43

    3,3

    85

    3,7

    76

    4,1

    96

    3,8

    03

    3,2

    12

    2,7

    46

    2,6

    81

    3,3

    77

    3,5

    87

    3,4

    47

    2,8

    35

    2,1

    95

    2,0

    95

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    Figure 17.Iowa Real Retail Sales(IN BILLIONS OF 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA, Iowa Departmentof Revenue data

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    Statewide High Hog Sales Counties

    Large Hog Farm Counties

    $29.7

    $29.5

    $29.9

    $32.9

    $33

    .8

    $33.0

    $15.6

    $17.1

    $14.6

    $11.5

    $

    9.7

    $10.1

    $13.6

    $13.3

    $12.7

    $9.9

    $7.2

    $6.3

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    21/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 19

    a million (460,000) wage and salary jobs beween 1982 and

    2007, a 41.0 percen increase. Bu high hog sales counies

    los 52,300 jobs (an 8.8 percen drop), and large hog arm

    counies los 164,400 jobs (a 31.8 percen drop). (See Figure

    19.) In conras, he mos-rural hal o counies wih he

    lowes populaion densiy gained 40,700 jobs (a 21.6 percen

    increase). The counies wih he mos hogs and larges hog

    arms have lower or negaive job growh, even compared o

    he mos rural counies wihou major hog producion.

    Meatpacking

    The meapacking and processing indusry provides jobs in

    rural areas, including or arm amily members, and hese

    workers spend heir earnings a local reailers and on local

    services.112 Alhough Iowa Sae Universiy atribued a

    considerable porion o he impac o he hog secor on

    personal income o workers in he mea processing secor,113

    he oal real earnings o meapacking and processing

    workers declined 16 percen beween 1982 and 2007.114

    The meapacking indusry has shifed o ewer, larger and

    more remoe plans.115 The number o ederally inspeced

    hog packing plans (ypically, he larges plans ha can

    ship pork naionwide) in Iowa ell by abou a sixh (16

    percen) beween 1982 and 2007.116 (See Figure 20.) In 2010,

    Smihield closed a 14,000-hog per day John Morrell plan

    in Sioux Ciy.117 The oal number o Iowa pork packing

    and processing plans wih a leas 20 employees declined

    slighly (by 4 percen) over he same period, according o

    U.S. Census Bureau igures (which do no separae hog andbee plans).118 The modes decline conceals a sharp decline

    in packing plans, which dropped 42 percen beween 1982

    and 2007, while he number o processing plans grew.

    (Packing plans handle and slaugher live animals and end

    up wih a carcass. Processing plans urn carcasses ino

    oher processed producs.)

    A larger impac o he economies o rural communiies

    has been he decline in real wages or meapacker and

    processing workers. Mea manuacurers paid sharply lowerSOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA and BEA data

    Figure 18.Iowa Farm Jobs

    Statewide High Hog SalesCounties

    Large Hog FarmCounties

    153,7

    52

    137,6

    53

    125,6

    52

    115,9

    19

    96,3

    40

    89,8

    63

    92,7

    19

    83,9

    48

    75,5

    82

    64,7

    15

    51,7

    16

    50,1

    14

    82,0

    32

    7

    6,3

    44

    66,8

    45

    56,5

    67

    49,6

    35

    45,6

    56

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    Figure 19.Total Iowa Wageand Salary Jobs, Statewide, High Hog Sales,

    Large Hog Farm and Most Rural Counties

    SOURCE: Food & Water Watch analysis of USDA and BEA data

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    1,800,000

    1,400,000

    1,000,000

    600,000

    200,000

    Statewide

    High Hog Sales Counties

    Large Hog Farm Counties

    Most Rural Counties

    Figure 20.Federally InspectedIowa Pork Packing Plants

    SOURCE: USDA NASS

    Number of Plants Average Plant Capacity(000 head/year)

    25

    23

    20 20

    18

    21

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    743

    917

    1,471

    1,239

    1,593

    1,425

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    22/55

    20 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    wages as he secor consolidaed and ocused on larger

    manuacuring plans in more rural areas.119 Wih declining

    real wages, workers a meapacking plans provide less o a

    boos o local economies.120

    In Iowa, real meapacker and processor (boh bee and

    pork) wages have allen seadily over he pas hree

    decades. (See Figure 21.) Real, inlaion-adjused mea-

    packer wages dropped 44 percen beween 1982 and 2007,and mea processing wages dropped by 24 percen (in real

    2010 dollars).121 Even wih a rise in mea processing workers

    and he sligh decline in packing plan workers, he oal

    real earnings rom mea manuacuring workers dropped by

    16 percen, rom $853.9 million in 1982 o $720.2 million in

    2007 (in 2010 dollars). Some large meapackers had hosile

    relaionships wih unions represening packing plan and

    mea processing workers, and broke srikes and cracked

    unions o drive down wages o 25 percen below average

    manuacuring wages by 2002.122

    Conclusion

    A 2006 Iowa Sae Universiy repor described he changes

    in Iowas hog producion secor over he pas decades as

    dramaic and proound.135 The number o Iowa hog arms

    plummeed, producion had shifed rom arms ha raised

    hogs rom birh (arrow-o-inish operaions) o arms ha

    atened hogs or slaugher (inishing operaions), and

    conrac hog producion became more prevalen.136

    Tax Revenue and Property ValuesLarger or more vertically integrated hog farms can

    undermine property values and the local tax base.

    Proponents of large-scale hog operations contend that

    livestock operations can be associated with generally

    higher property values in a region or county.123 Theo-

    retically, the increased housing demand from addi-

    tional hog farm workers helps to drive up property

    values. But in Iowa, the counties with the highest hog

    production lost almost half the farm workers between

    1982 and 2007, which suggests a reduced demand for

    housing.

    Several studies have found that large hog operations

    FDQKDYHVLJQLFDQWQHJDWLYHHHFWVRQORFDOSURSHUW\

    values. A 1997 study of home sales in high hog-

    producing North Carolina counties found that homes

    sold for 9.5 percent less if there were 5,000 hogs

    within half a mile (or 15,000 hogs within a mile) than

    homes with only a few hogs within half a mile.124 A

    1990 Michigan study found that home sales within 1.6

    miles of hog operations would reduce home prices by

    $1,740 for every 1,000 hogs.125 This might not seem like

    a big impact, but a $1,700 drop in price is a 2 percent

    decline in the average Michigan home price in 1990126

    and that is for every 1,000 hogs.

    The studies also found that the addition of new hog

    operations reduced the property values of neigh-

    boring homes. The North Carolina study found that

    adding a new 2,400-head hog operation within half a

    mile of a community without hog farms would reduce

    property values by 8.4 percent.127 A 2003 Iowa State

    University study found that a new, large livestockoperation could reduce nearby and downwind prop-

    erty values by about 10 percent.128

    $54,1

    62

    Figure 21.Average Real Iowa Meatpackerand Processor Annual Earnings (IN 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau

    1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007

    Meatpacker Wages

    $38,0

    43

    $36,8

    15

    $3

    7,6

    89

    $29,6

    29 $

    37,8

    59

    $27,8

    83

    $33,9

    16

    $29,8

    41

    $34,578

    $30,4

    51

    $28,9

    39

    Meat Processing Wages

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    23/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 21

    Food & Waer Wach ound ha as consolidaion has risen,

    he conribuion o he hog secor o overall economicaciviy in Iowa has declined. Counies wih more hog sales

    and larger arms end o have lower oal incomes, slower

    income growh, ewer Main Sree businesses and less reail

    aciviy. General employmen levels have suered, wages

    in meapacking have declined and arm job opporuniies

    are more diicul o ind. In spie o wha Big Pork boosers

    have said, here is litle evidence ha he rends in Iowa hog

    producion have been good or Iowas rural economies.

    The mos likely culpri or he decline in economic well-

    being in he ace o seeply rising hog producion is hesigniican consolidaion in he pork packing indusry.

    Today, he bigges our Iowa packers slaugher nine ou o

    every 10 hogs produced. Iowas pork economy has devolved

    rom one ha suppored rural communiies o one ha

    exracs value and uels prois or irms ar rom he Iowa

    counryside. Rebalancing he value o hog producion

    back o arms and rural communiies will require resoring

    genuine compeiion o he hog secor.

    The Myth of&RQVXPHU%HQHW

    Although pork packer consolidation

    has pushed down the real prices

    that farmers receive for their hogs,

    few of these savings are passed

    on to consumers; the meatpackers

    and retailers are pocketing the

    GLHUHQFH7KH86'$IRXQGWKDW

    although large-scale hog farms and

    SURFHVVRUHFLHQF\JDLQVPD\KDYH

    reduced the cost of production

    between 1992 and 2004, consumer

    prices for retail pork nonetheless

    increased substantially.129

    Because pork is a small share of

    food expenditures, even a 5 percent

    reduction of production costs on

    industrial-scale hog operationswould reduce total food expendi-

    tures by only 0.2 percent.130

    Although the price of hogs has been trending downward, the consumer price of pork products has been less

    responsive to the declining hog prices. Some studies have found that increases in farmgate prices are passed on

    to consumers completely and immediately, but when farmgate prices fall, the grocery store prices do not fall as

    rapidly or completely.131

    When the prices that farmers received for hogs plummeted in 1998, the prices that consumers paid at the

    supermarket for pork products in 1998 and 1999 did not decline very much.132 Real hog prices dropped by about

    two-thirds between June and December of 1998, but real pork chop prices fell by only 8 percent and bacon prices

    actually rose by 5 percent.133 (See Figure 22.)

    Increased consolidation in the pork industry nationwide means that consumers face not only rising prices but also

    diminishing choices at the supermarket. Although consumers see a wide variety of brands at the meat counter,

    PDQ\ODUJHPHDWSDFNHUVPDUNHWDUDQJHRIEUDQGVWKDWDOOFRPHIURPWKHVDPHFRPSDQ\)RUH[DPSOH6PLWKHOG

    )RRGVVHOOVSRUNSURGXFWVXQGHUWKHEUDQGQDPHV6PLWKHOG)DUPODQG-RKQ0RUUHOO*ZDOWQH\$UPRXU(FNULFK

    Margherita, Carando, Kretschmar, Cooks, Curlys and Healthy Ones, as well as under private-label brands.134

    7KLVPDUNHWLQJHRUWWRPDLQWDLQPXOWLSOHEUDQGVDQGODEHOVREVFXUHVWKHUHDOLW\RIWKHLQFUHDVLQJFRQWURORIWKH

    meat case by just a few players and makes it hard or impossible for consumers to understand the dramatic

    structural changes that have taken place in the pork industry over the last three decades.

    $0

    $1

    $2

    $3

    $4

    $5

    $6

    $0

    $10

    $20

    $30

    $40

    $50

    $60

    $70

    $80

    $90

    Figure 22.Real Farmgate Hog and Retail Pork Prices(IN 2010 DOLLARS)

    SOURCE: USDA, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

    $90

    $80

    $70

    $60

    $50

    $40

    $30

    $20

    $10

    $6

    $5

    $4

    $3

    $2

    $1

    RetailPorkPrices

    Farm

    gateHogPrice

    Jan-97 Jul-97 Jan-98 Jul-98 Jan-99 Jul-99 Jan-00 Jul-00

    ($/CW T Right Axis)

    Retail Pork Chop ($/LB L eft Axis)

    Retail Bacon ($/LB Left Axis)

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    24/55

    22 Food & Water Watch tXXXGPPEBOEXBUFSXBUDIPSH

    Consolidation and Collusion

    in the New York Dairy Industry

    The U.S. dairy indusry has experienced increasing urmoil

    or several decades. Farm numbers have allen dramaically;

    new arms are ofen mega-dairies many imes larger han

    radiional arms; and prices are requenly oo low and oo

    unsable o suppor amily-sized operaions. Alhough he

    number o arms has allen dramaically, because manyarms have grown o garganuan proporions, U.S. dairy

    arms coninue o produce large volumes o milk.

    Milk is sold ino a sysem ha is dominaed by ewer and

    larger processors ha in urn sell milk o a highly consoli-

    daed reail indusry. The U.S. General Accouning Oice

    repored in 2001 ha, A each level o he markeing chain,

    including dairy arms, cooperaives, wholesale milk proces-

    sors, and reail grocery sores, here are ewer, bu larger,

    players in he indusry.137

    This agribusiness concenraion endangers he uure oindependen dairy armers naionwide, including in upsae

    New York, he ocus o his analysis. New Yorks indepen-

    den dairy armers have long been he oundaion o a dairy

    indusry ha provided 6,000 jobs in he sae and generaed

    $300 million in sales in he mid-2000s.138 Consolidaion was

    acceleraed in he lae 1980s when New York eliminaed

    New Deal-era rules designed o saeguard local milk

    processors.139 The deregulaion brough new, ou-o-sae

    milk processors ino New York supermarkes and spawned

    a price war ha iniially reduced prices, bu consumer

    savings evaporaed as big processors consolidaed heirmarke power and exraced more o he value beween

    dairy armers and consumers.140

    Individual irms pursuing marke power over compeiors,

    cusomers, suppliers and armers have largely driven he

    consolidaion hroughou he ood and arm secor. Bu in

    some circumsances, compeiors work wih one anoher

    o squeeze greaer prois rom he oher seps in he ood

    chain. Federal anirus law prohibis he collusion beween

    compeiors o subver he markeplace or suppress

    compeiion, including price-ixing agreemens, dividing upgeographic or consumer markes, or coordinaed boycots

    or blackliss agains suppliers or consumers.141

    A lawsui brough in 2009 by Vermon and New York dairy

    armers alleges jus such coordinaion beween some o

    he larges players in he dairy indusry.142 The class-acion

    anirus sui conended ha he naions larges milk

    processor, Dean Foods; he larges co-operaive, Dairy

    Farmers o America; and Dairy Markeing Services (a milk

    markeing parnership beween DFA and New York-based

    Dairylea Cooperaive) were colluding o conrol access o

    milk processing hrough mergers, plan closings and eec-ively requiring armers o marke heir milk hrough DFA

    and DMS.143 The allegaions mirror how Dean Foods Chie

    Execuive Gregg Engles described he companys sraegy

    in 2002: We acquire (rivals), we close smaller plans and

    consolidae heir operaions ino our large, more eicien

    aciliies.144

    In Augus 2011, Dean setled is case wih many o he

    dairy armers (a ew asked o be excluded rom he class)

    or $30 million wihou admiting any wrongdoing.145

    Alhough Dean iniially consened o buy 10 o 20 percen

    o is milk rom non-DFA sources or 30 monhs, he inal

    setlemen deleed his injuncive relie.146 (Similar claims

    agains milk processor HP Hood were dismissed.147) Some

    o he claims iled agains boh DFA and DMS were sill

    pending as o summer 2012.

    Consolidation and Concentration

    In 2010, a hird o all milk produced in he Unied Saes

    came rom indusrial dairies wih over 2,000 cows, abou

    14 imes larger han he naional average herd size.148 The

    number o arms wih over 2,000 cows more han doubledbeween 2000 and 2006,149 while smaller arms were los

    a an alarming rae. Beween 2000 and 2010, an average o

    3,850 U.S. dairy arms were los each year, or a oal loss o

    over 42,500 dairies in jus a decade.150

    In spie o hose losses, milk producion remained consan

    because he scale o he arms increased signiicanly.151

    From 1980 o 2010, he average size o a dairy arm more

    han quadrupled, rom 32 o 146 cows.152 As lae as 1998,

  • 7/31/2019 Cost of Food Monopolies

    25/55

    The Economic Cost o Food Monopolies 23

    he majoriy o milk was produced on small arms wih

    ewer han 200 cows; by 2007, he majoriy o milk was

    produced on large dairies wih over 500 cows.153

    The milk produced by dairy arms, wih very ew excep-

    ions, is no sold direcly o consumers. I mus irs be

    processed ino cheese, buter, ice cream and oher producs.

    Even he luid milk on grocery sore shelves is processed

    beore i is sold o consumers. Some armers sell heir milkdirecly o processors, bu i is more common or dairy

    armers o join cooperaives ha handle (or deliver) heir

    milk rom he arm o he milk processing plan. Some o

    hese armer-owned cooperaives own processing plans,

    some collec members milk and sell i o oher processors,

    and some do boh.154

    The number o dairy cooperaives has allen dramaically

    over he las hal-cenury, rom 2,300 in he early 1940s o

    155 in 2007.155 Hisorically, he so-called brick and morar

    cooperaives ha owned processing plans and processed

    mos o heir members milk were inended o give armersa share o processing prois. This worked well or decades,

    bu now he cooperaives have in large par given way o

    privaely owned processors.