Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

download Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

of 31

Transcript of Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    1/31

    Corporate finance and state enterprise reform

    in China

    Dongwei SU*

    Department of Finance, Jinan University, Guangzhou, Guangdong 510632, Peoples Republic of China

    Accepted 20 September 2004

    Abstract

    This paper uses a novel approach in addressing two puzzles in the field of corporate finance in

    China, where government is a major player. In addition to the traditional approach based on agency

    theory and information asymmetry, the paper uses the political costs approach in studying the stock

    dividend puzzle and rights issues puzzle. The paper finds that the extent of political interference,

    managerial entrenchment, and institutional control affects corporate financing choices and dividend

    distribution decisions. The result sheds new light on improving the important corporate governance

    aspects of state enterprise reform in China.

    D 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    JEL classification: G32; G35; O53; P21

    Keywords: Corporate finance; Dividend policy; Agency costs; Political costs; State enterprise reform

    1. Introduction

    The Chinese Communist government, wishing to avoid the political and economic

    turmoil that accompanied the mass privatization of the former Soviet Union and other

    Eastern European governments, has chosen, as a cornerstone of its political survival, the

    commercialization and partial privatization of claims over assets and profits and of its

    1043-951X/$ - see front matterD 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.chieco.2004.09.003

    * Tel.: +86 20 8522 4798.

    E-mail address: [email protected].

    China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    2/31

    state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Its SOE reform strategy hinges on the modern enterprise

    system (MES) characterized by the separation of ownership and control. Ownership of an

    SOEs assets is distributed among the government, institutional investors, managers,

    employees, and private investors. Effective control rights are assigned to the management,

    which generally has a very small, or even nonexistent, ownership stake.

    The separation of ownership and control creates a conflict of interest between

    management and newly enfranchised private investors that is the root cause of the

    principal-agent problem in traditional corporate finance theory (Jensen & Meckling,

    1976). Moreover, because government desires to retain some control, in part, through

    partial retained ownership of commercialized SOEs, further conflicts arise between

    politicians and firms (Shleifer & Vishny, 1994). In addition to agency costs of managerial

    discretion, the newly corporatized SOEs face political costs of government control,

    defined as the reduction in firm value due to government administrative interference. Thegames played by the government, management, and outside investors become more

    complex than those addressed in the traditional corporate finance models. The principle

    challenge of this paper is to assess whether and to what extent the unique ownership

    conflicts under the MES can serve as a foundation for solving two puzzles in corporate

    China.

    While stockholders respond positively to stock dividend announcements in the United

    States, which can be explained by the signaling theory, stockholders react negatively to

    stock dividend distributions in China. If stock dividend does not signal good news, why do

    so many Chinese firms bother to distribute stock dividends? While fewer and fewer firms

    issue uninsured rights in the United States and elsewhere, Chinese firms predominantlyuse uninsured rights in seasoned equity offerings (SEOs). Models of information

    asymmetry argue that firms issuing uninsured rights are of better quality, but Chinese

    firms using uninsured rights exhibit no evidence of superior investment opportunities and

    experience significant drop in their stock prices. The main contribution of this research is

    to analyze these apparent deviations from the prediction of the traditional corporate

    finance theory in terms of political and agency costs of the governmentmanagement

    investor conflicts unique to the state enterprise reform in China. The papers find that

    dividend policies and financing choices are affected by ownership conflicts (agency and

    political costs) and the effectiveness of monitoring.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses how earlier attemptsto commercialize SOEs without privatizing them created adverse incentives that defeated

    the intent to increase profitability and reduce the need for continual government subsidies.

    This failure led to the establishment of the MES, with its unique ownership conflicts and

    lack of effective monitoring. Section 3 contains theoretical discussions on the dividend

    policies and post-IPO equity financing choices of Chinese firms. It explores the rationale

    behind the frequent use of stock dividends and the predominant use of uninsured rights in

    seasoned equity offerings in China. Three testable hypotheses are then formulated. Section

    4 empirically investigates the stock dividend and rights issues puzzles, discusses the long-

    term performance of dividend distribution firms, and explains the negative valuation effect

    of stock dividends and rights issues announcements in terms of firm characteristics

    associated with agency and political costs. Section 5 concludes with a summary of

    findings.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 119

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    3/31

    2. Institutional framework surrounding SOE reform

    The reform of SOEs in China has been characterized by efforts to decentralize,

    commercialize, and, of necessity, to separate ownership and (effective) control. In general,

    the government is reluctant to initiate deep institutional reform and is loath to surrender its

    control over enterprises because doing so increases the cost of maintaining political

    support in the form of attaining worker satisfaction and a bquietQ population. At the same

    time, the inefficiencies and waste inherent in socialist economies, in practice, limit the

    governments ability to maintain its base without resorting to totalitarian controls that have

    proven impossible to sustain in a few societies. Therefore, the privatization of SOEs has

    been adopted only because it is the only viable means to assure the survival of the existing

    political order, which, in the case of China, means the survival of the Chinese Communist

    Party. The government, by reforming the agricultural industry, restructuring SOEs viapartial privatization, and encouraging rapid growth of Township and Village Enterprises,

    seeks to obtain the benefits of a market economy for the mobilization of private savings,

    economic growth and an improved standard of living, while retaining political control.

    SOE reform began with the Management Responsibility Contract System (MRCS) in

    1987, in which the government transferred management authority to the enterprises and

    allowed them to retain some of their profits.1 Under the MRCS, managers of SOEs were

    given specific control rights in production, investment, sales, profits, personnel manage-

    ment, and distribution of fringe benefits via contracts, therefore, managers have partial

    incentives to generate cash flows and expand wages in the form of bonuses and fringe

    benefits. However, the contractual relationship between managers and the government wasasymmetric and incomplete. A critical defect was that profit retention by management had

    no downside. The state, in fact, remained responsible for final losses, mainly through the

    state-owned banks, which were not contractual parties in the enterprise-commercialization

    process. Employee bonuses and welfare expenditures, including housing, medical and

    schooling expenses, and other fringe benefits, were deductible from enterprise revenue in

    calculating profits. Therefore, it is not difficult to see why profit maximization was not the

    managements primary objective and why SOEs continued to function as government

    agencies or social security institutions providing bcradle-to-graveQ services to employees

    rather than as even approximately profit-maximizing businesses.

    Grossman and Hart (1982, 1986) and Hart and Moore (1990) argue that residual rightsof control, not specific rights via contracts, are critical determinants of managerial

    incentives. Shleifer and Vishny (1994) also argue that commercialization without

    allocation of residual rights to management is unlikely to guarantee more productive or

    profitable uses of resources. Moreover, when the government can indirectly subsidize the

    management to maintain bloated employment levels, employee housing, schooling, and

    other political objectives through control over transfers from the treasury, thus creating a

    soft budget constraint, privatization alone is unlikely to enhance productivity. Under

    MRCS, managers had little residual rights of control and were subject to strong political

    influences to maintain SOEs social responsibilities. Consequently, they had little interest

    1 SOEs had to operate at state-controlled prices and remit all profits to the state before MRCS.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148120

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    4/31

    in technology investment, profit maximization, and efficient resource allocation, all of

    which inevitably led to high political costs of government control.

    Groves, Hong, McMillan, and Naughton (1994) provide evidence that MRCS

    strengthened workers incentives and increased productivity and workers compensation,

    but neither reduced government subsidies nor increased overall profits. With the adverse

    incentive structure as described above, SOEs were able to rely on easy bank credit to pay

    production and otherboperatingQ expenses. Thus, as of 1994, over 40% of SOEs were

    unprofitable, and while SOEs accounted for 34% of GDP, they absorbed three quarters of

    domestic credit. Their ever-increasing triangular debt (unpaid bills between state

    enterprises, state banks, and the government) had accumulated to over 4900 billion

    Renminbi Yuan (or 95% of GDP), and bad debt was estimated to be as much as 25% of

    state bank assets in 1996. Many troubled SOEs were unable to pay back these accrued

    loans, thus threatening the collapse of Chinas banking system. MRCS did not achieve thegoal of effectively reforming SOEs and was terminated nationwide in 1994. The process of

    partial privatization through the creation of joint-stock companies (corporatization) began

    through the establishment of Modern Enterprise System (MES), or Cooperative Share-

    holding System (CSS).2

    Under the MES, there are five types of shares. Those shares not retained by the

    government, state enterprises, managers, and employees are transferred to outside

    investors through initial public offerings (IPOs) and seasoned equity offerings (SEOs).3

    Each share type is entitled to the same voting rights and dividend. After corporatization,

    all shareholders have residual claims on the companys assets. Boards of directors are

    established to represent the interests of all shareholders. A major characteristic of Chinesejoint-stock companies is that share ownership is dominated by the state or legal person

    shareholders. The State Assets Management Bureau (SAMB) retains majority ownership

    for about one-third of the listed firms, and legal person shareholders have controlling

    shares for the other two-thirds.

    To facilitate the privatization process and to wean doomed firms from eternal subsidies,

    the government set up an annual reserve fund to support mergers and bankruptcies, to train

    surplus workers for new jobs, to free enterprises from some of their responsibility to

    provide social services, and thus, to promote a system in which enterprise survival depends

    only on market-oriented performance. By the end of 1996, 675 SOEs had declared

    bankruptcy, 1801 had been merged or downsized, 9200 SOEs had been corporatized, and

    2 In November 1993, the 14th Central Communist Party of China issued the Decision on Issues Concerning the

    Establishment of a Socialist Market Economic Structure, which formally introduced the modern corporate system

    to the SOEs. The major reform objectives in the system include transforming the SOEs into corporations by the

    separation of ownership and control and the establishment of efficient corporate governance structure.3 Among the five share types, state shares are retained by the State Assets Management Bureau (SAMB) for

    central government or local government. Legal person shares are held by other SOEs and nonbank financial

    institutions (including investment companies, finance corporations, and mutual funds). Employee shares are those

    sold to managers and workers within a company and cannot be traded within the first 3 years. Domestic individualshares, or A shares, are those held and traded by private Chinese citizens in the two official exchanges in China.

    Foreign shares are those held and traded by foreign investors in security exchanges in China (B shares), in Hong

    Kong (H shares), or in NYSE (N shares).

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 121

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    5/31

    of these, 485 of the most profitable had been listed in the two stock exchanges with a total

    market capitalization of about 400 billion Renminbi Yuan (equivalent to approximately

    U.S. $50 billion).

    The extent to which SOE partial privatization leads to benefits in the form of more rapid

    productivity and GDP growth is limited by the political- and agency-cost problems. The

    games played by government, management, and investors become more and more

    complex than those addressed in traditional corporate finance theory.

    In traditional corporate finance theory, private firms are viewed as a nexus of contracts

    between various economic entities, particularly owners (principals) and managers (agents).

    In the absence of complete and fully enforceable contracts, principal-agent problems arise

    because owners want to maximize firm value while managers maximize their own utility,

    which, in general, reduces the value of the firm. When the government is also an actor, the

    traditional agency approach will not be the whole story because the government isinterested in its survival, which may require the use of resources that might otherwise

    contribute to the managements utility or the private investors wealth (firm value). These

    interrelationships are complicated by the fact that the government is by no means

    monolithic and constitutes a collection of agents with conflicting goals: politicians, civil

    employees, and citizens themselves (Hart, 1995). An exacerbating characteristic of the

    Chinese situation is that the vast majority of private shares are held by small investors.

    Dispersed public ownership creates a classic free-rider problem: Small shareholders do not

    have the incentive to monitor management because the benefit is enjoyed by all while the

    cost is totally borne by a few, active investors.

    Several factors can mitigate the agency costs of managerial discretion, including debt(in conjunction with appropriate bankruptcy procedures), takeover threats, legal protection

    of investors, product market competition, etc. Jensen (1986) and Stulz (1990) show that

    debt with the threat of bankruptcy imposes a hard budget constraint on managers and

    limits the managements control over firms free cash flows. When managers are faced

    with choices of reducing empire building and lavish perquisites or going bankrupt, they

    are likely to choose the first option. Therefore, leverage reduces agency costs of

    managerial discretion. Shleifer and Vishny (1986) show that takeover threats discipline the

    management in the presence of many small shareholders. The reason is that if a company

    is badly managed, then there is an incentive for someone to acquire a large stake of the

    company, improve its performance, and profit on the shares purchased. The threat of suchaction can persuade the management to act in the interest of shareholders. Weisbach

    (1988) shows that the level of investor protection, including the extent of board

    independence, the ability of a board to dismiss managers following poor performance, and

    the degree of shareholder activism, is negatively related to agency costs and positively

    related to firm performance. Maksimovic and Titman (1991) argue that product market

    competition makes profits more sensitive to managerial effort, reduces agency costs, and

    enhances investment efficiency. The reason is that temptation to retain cash and engage in

    less productive activities is less severe for firms in a more competitive environment.

    Unfortunately, because of the political nature of the privatization process itself, bank-

    debt financing of corporate investments is not a viable means to assure a hard budget

    constraint in transitional economies, such as China (Shleifer & Vishny, 1994). Bank loans

    have traditionally been viewed as grants from the state designed to bail out failing firms.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148122

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    6/31

    State-owned banks retain a monopoly in the Chinese banking sector, and profit is not their

    overriding objective. If political favor is deemed appropriate, subsidized loans,

    rescheduling of overdue debt, or even outright transfer of funds can be arranged with

    SOEs (soft budget constraints). A banking system that is so heavily controlled by the

    governments political objectives can hardly exert any real influence on management.

    Moreover, a market for private, nonbank debt has yet to be established. There is no active

    merger or takeover activity in stock markets to discipline management. Information

    available in the capital markets is insufficient to keep at arms length of the managerial

    decisions. Despite the existence of a bankruptcy law since 1986, the rate of bankruptcies

    has remained at a very low level. In light of the above peculiarities, direct control by

    (large) shareholders through the board of directors appears to be the only means for

    shareholders to monitor managers.

    With good corporate governance structure, boards of directors would consist ofdelegates of large institutional shareholders and minority investors, representing all

    shareholders interests. Such boards would make critical investment and reorganization

    decisions, select top managers, and provide managers with incentives and compensation

    appropriate to the investors interests. However, board members in Chinese joint-stock

    companies consist mainly of representatives or officials from the SAMB, local govern-

    ment, and other state enterprises, whose interests are not the same as those of outside

    investors. On average, 90% of the board members are government officials and delegates

    of other state enterprises.4 Moreover, there is, at best, an inadequately functioning

    managerial labor market that can discipline managers and help solve incentive problems

    caused by the separation of ownership and control. All top managers must be approved bythe Organization Department of the local or central government. The government

    maintains ultimate rights for changing managerial positions.5 With state-controlled stock

    companies, political considerations still dominate economic performance in the selection

    of managers and adversely affect managerial incentives. Managers, no doubt, care more

    about carrying out the wishes of the Party and the government, such as avoiding worker

    layoffs and maintaining some level of worker social security, than about the concerns of

    shareholders. As a result, many management decisions still reflect the old political

    concerns (political costs). In addition, managerial and board member compensation

    4 For example, in a report in Financial Times, Lin (1999) highlights the continued government interference in

    investment decisions of PetroChina, which has just gone public: bGiven the oil industrys strategic importance to

    the Chinese economy, it is particularly likely that political factors will play a major role in the future governance

    of PetroChina. In its role as controlling shareholder, the Chinese government will face many potential conflicts of

    interest inherent in its role as owner, regulator, tax authority and primary borrower. PetroChinas board of

    directors appears not to be structured so as to act as a check on the power and interests of the controlling

    shareholder and the Chinese government. The new board of directors will have 12 members, all have close ties

    with the governmentQ.5 For example, on January 19, 2000, the Wall Street Journal reported that Li Yizhong, the President of Sinopec,

    Chinas second major oil company listed in Shanghai Securities Exchange, had been removed from his post and

    appointed as the communist party secretary of the Gansu province in northwest China. The Journal commented:bThe managerial overhaul sends a confusing signal to the oil industry. The moves appear to be motivated by

    domestic political considerations and are seen as part of the governments strategy to accelerate the development

    of northwestern ChinaQ.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 123

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    7/31

    packages are determined by the government and are seldom directly linked to profits.

    Management is not severely constrained from self-dealing behavior, such as diverting SOE

    assets outside the state sector for private use, such as charging meals and travel expenses to

    company accounts, obtaining large apartments, and purchasing fancy cars and furniture for

    personal consumption. Spending cash flow on acquisitions or other unprofitable projects

    undertaken with the aid of unrealistically high forecasts of future profitability gives the

    management a bigger company to run, thereby increasing their power and prestige in the

    community (agency costs).

    The allocation of effective control rights to management without clearly defined

    corporate laws and bankruptcy procedures gives managers a chance to enrich themselves

    by such means as undervaluing state assets and spinning off subsidiaries to be controlled

    by the managers relatives. In a study conducted by Kernen (1997), some managers of

    SOEs admitted to have created a number of collective or private enterprises for theirrelatives using SOEs assets. Furthermore, Chinas embryonic regulatory regime and

    rudimentary accounting standards provide very little protection for investors rights

    because they limit the boards ability to monitor abuses of governmental influence and

    managerial discretion and thus limit political and agency costs that diminish the

    productivity-enhancing effects of privatization and reduce firm value.

    It should be noted, however, that agency and political costs do not imply that

    managers are totally insensitive to the performance of their firms. Boycko, Shleifer, and

    Vishny (1996) argue that managers are more concerned with profits than politicians are.

    Bai, Li, Tao, and Wang (2000) posit that, during transition, SOEs are charged with the

    multitasks of social welfare provision and efficient production. One implication is thatSOEs are given low profit incentive, and the governments concern for income

    distribution and wage regulation is the root cause for the imperfection in managerial

    market. Another implication is that, depending on the speed of emergence of supporting

    institutions, managers may be able to escape government monitoring and divert efforts

    from providing social services to seeking higher profits. Chang and Wong (2003) find

    that the decision-making power of local Party committees relative to the largest

    shareholders is positively associated with firm performance, indicating that political

    control may help improve firm performance through the mitigation of large shareholders

    agency costs. On the other hand, the decision-making power of local Party committees

    relative to managers is negatively associated with firm performance, suggesting that theexisting level of political control is excessive when viewed from the perspective of

    managers. On net, they find that reducing political control tends to improve the

    performance of listed firms.

    In summary, the partial privatization and separation of ownership and control have

    transferred residual rights of control from government to managers but have not provided

    effective monitoring mechanisms. The traditional government goals characterized by the

    biron rice bowlQ concept still exert some control through the selection of managers and

    board members. Profit is not the overriding objective for the managers, and the

    management has considerable leeway to seek its own self-interest at the expense of

    shareholders. In the next two sections, we present theories and empirical evidence bearing

    on the influence of agency and political costs revealed in the dividend distributions and

    corporate financing choices of Chinese joint-stock companies.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148124

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    8/31

    3. Dividend policy and equity financing choices

    3.1. Agency costs, political costs, and stock dividend puzzle

    The separation of ownership from control inevitably leads to agency problem among all

    Chinese SOEs. Dividends can play a role in reducing agency costs because they remove

    corporate wealth from insider control. Jensen (1986) suggests that managers, motivated by

    compensation and human capital considerations, have incentives to overinvest free cash

    flows, even in the absence of profitable growth opportunities. Dividend payout policy can

    be a vehicle for monitoring the use of funds by the management. Thus, the observed positive

    stock-market reaction on dividend increases is consistent with a reduction in agency costs.

    La Porta, Lopez-DeSilanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (2000) also argue that corporate

    dividend policies reveal agency problems and vary across legal regimes, with differentlevels of shareholder rights protection. Under an effective corporate governance system,

    shareholders have the legal power to prevent insiders (managers) from using a large

    proportion of the companys free cash to benefit themselves. This implies that cash

    dividends are an outcome of less serious agency conflicts. Cash dividends are paid because

    shareholders are able to pressure corporate insiders to disgorge cash.

    Lu and Wang (1999) and Wei (2000) find that both cash and stock dividends are

    important forms of dividend distribution in China. This empirical result is puzzling: While

    fewer and fewer firms distribute stock dividends in the United States, why are stock

    dividends widely used in China?

    Taken at their face value, stock dividends are small-scale stock splits and bfiner slicingof a given cakethe total market value of a firm Q. They do not generate funds for the firm

    nor alter the proportional ownership of the firm on the part of the existing shareholders.

    But if stock dividends are merely cosmetic changes in a firms balance sheet, why do a lot

    of firms continue to engage in such financial manipulation, particularly when there are

    costs of doing so? Grinblatt, Masulis, and Titman (1984) propose the bsignaling

    hypothesisQ (or bretained earnings hypothesisQ). They argue that accounting principles

    require that stock dividend distributions be accompanied by a reduction in retained

    earnings in the balance sheet. In the presence of information asymmetry, i.e., when

    managers (insiders) know more about the future prospects of the firm than investors

    (outsiders) do, managers of high-quality firms can use stock dividend distributions toconvey favorable information to the investors. These managers can afford to signal

    because they do not expect the reduction in the balance of retained earnings to constrain

    future cash dividend payments. On the other hand, managers who anticipate poor future

    earnings will find it costly to mimic the signal of a high-quality firm. An empirical

    implication is that stock prices, on average, react positively to stock dividend announce-

    ments, ceteris paribus. Grinblatt et al. (1984) document significantly positive abnormal

    returns on and around the announcement day of stock dividends. Their results are further

    substantiated in a recent article by Rankine and Stice (1997), who find additional evidence

    of positive relationship between abnormal returns around stock dividend distributions and

    subsequent earnings growth.

    In China, information asymmetry may not be the entire story because dividend policy is

    severely influenced by agency problem and political interference. Managers of a number

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 125

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    9/31

    of firms own a very small percentage of shares. They have virtually no incentive to

    increase the stock prices of their firms. In addition, institutional investors have little voice

    in some of the boards, bank debt does not provide monitoring on management, the market

    for public debt is yet to be developed, and there is no active merger or takeover activity in

    the stock market to discipline managers. Moreover, in the process of privatizing SOEs, the

    government cannot withhold the temptation to control managers. Political interference by

    the government leads to political costs of government failure. Under these circumstances,

    managers could and would hold on cash as much as possible for the purpose of covering

    their own mistakes, consuming perks, doing favors for politicians, or having financial

    flexibility. Because cash dividends reduce the free cash level in the firm and add

    disciplines to the management, managers will try to avoid distributing cash dividends to

    shareholders as much as possible.

    Therefore, we propose theb

    agency/political cost hypothesisQ dividend policies in

    corporate China are direct consequences of ownership conflicts and monitoring (as

    opposed to consequences of differential investment opportunities).6 Firms with very high

    agency and political costs and without effective monitoring have neither the pressure nor

    the incentive to distribute any dividend. On the contrary, firms with low agency and

    political costs and effective institutional monitoring are more likely to pay cash dividends.

    Firms with mild agency and political costs may use stock dividend as a substitute for cash

    dividend. They are willing to incur costs associated with stock dividends because they

    have the incentive to separate themselves from the worst firms (firms plagued with high

    agency/political costs).7

    The alternative to the agency/political costs hypothesis is the bliquidity/investmentopportunities hypothesisQ. Because firms with good investment opportunities have less

    free cash at hand, they would distribute stock dividend or no dividend rather than paying

    cash dividend. Furthermore, firms with the best investment opportunities will distribute

    stock dividends to separate themselves from those that pay no dividends.

    Therefore, we hypothesize that:

    H3.1. Managers will have the incentive to distribute cash dividends when the agency and

    political costs are small. Between the choices of cash dividend and no dividend, or

    between the choices of cash dividend and stock dividend, the probability that a firm will

    distribute cash dividend is positively related to management and institutional ownershipand negatively related to government ownership and nonessential expenditures.

    6 We acknowledge that the impacts of agency and political costs on firms dividend policies and financing

    decisions can be quite different. However, we do not delineate agency costs from political costs in our

    econometric investigations because we do not have good enough proxies. We plan to conduct further research on

    this topic in the future.7 The reason that stock dividends can also serve as credible signals is as follows: Given information asymmetry

    between managers and investors, stock dividends are costly signals that convey the managements private

    information about the firms level of agency/political costs. Specifically, in China, firms must maintain a

    minimum level of retained earnings to qualify for future share issues. For instance, prior to 1998, the CSRC

    requires firms to have at least 10% return on assets for three consecutive years to issue new shares. Therefore,managers would transfer retained earnings to common stock (and issue free shares) only if they expect future

    earnings to increase and do not need to keep large amount of free cash. Investors, therefore, may interpret stock

    dividends as good news, although not as good as they do for cash dividends.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148126

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    10/31

    The alternative hypothesis is that managers issue cash dividends because they do not

    have very profitable net present value projects. The probability of cash dividend

    distribution is negatively related to the firms investment opportunities, such as market-to-

    book ratios, and long-term investment to total asset ratios, and positively related to its

    liquidity measured by leverage ratios.

    H3.2. Firms with mild agency/political costs distribute stock dividends (compared with

    doing nothing) to separate themselves from firms with high agency/political costs.

    Between the choices of stock dividend and no dividend, the probability that a firm will

    distribute stock dividend is positively related to management and institutional ownership

    and negatively related to government ownership and nonessential expenditures.

    The alternative hypothesis is that stock dividends are signals of better investment

    opportunities. The probability of stock dividend distributions is positively related to thefirms investment opportunities, but negatively related to its liquidity.

    3.2. Agency costs, political costs and rights issues puzzle

    Myers and Majluf (1984) argue that when managers know more about the future

    prospects of the firm than outside investors do, managers may convey positive news to the

    investors by means of the financing method chosen, with internal financing being the

    highest in the pecking order, riskless debt the next highest, followed by equity issues (the

    so-called bpecking order paradigmQ). Because new bank debt is likely to be a signal of bad

    news in the Chinese situation (and in transitional economies with soft budget constraints,in general), and because markets for private nonbank debt have not yet emerged, loan

    financing of new, profitable investment projects does not appear in the pecking order for

    newly privatized SOEs. Consistent with this argument, we observe no corporate debt issues

    over the period covered in this study. Therefore, we focus on equity financing choices.

    When a firm wishes to raise capital through outside equities, it can choose a number of

    flotation methods, including uninsured rights issues, rights issues with standby underwriters,

    and fully underwritten offers. The direct flotation costs (e.g., registration fees, mailing costs,

    and underwriting fees) are generally smaller for rights issues than they are for firm

    commitment underwritten offers. However, managers have to set a sufficiently low

    subscription price to guarantee the full subscription of rights, which may lead to prohibitively high indirect flotation costs for rights issues. When choosing a flotation

    method in the absence of information asymmetry, managers typically weigh the costs of

    underwriter certification and the costs of a rights offer subscription discount. Under

    information asymmetry, the true value of a firm is unobservable to the market. Heinkel and

    Schwartz (1986) show that managers who know of profitable investment projects and are

    willing to incur investigation costs will ensure the success of their rights issues with

    underwriters standby offer; managers who have profitable investment projects but are

    unwilling to incur additional investigation costs will signal their true value in the choice of a

    subscription price in an uninsured rights offer; while managers with lower-quality projects

    make fully underwritten offers. Their signaling model implies that the quality of a firm is

    revealed through the financing method chosen, with firms using standby rights being the

    highest, those using uninsured rights the next, and those using firm commitment the lowest.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 127

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    11/31

    Eckbo and Masulis (1992) argue that issuers expecting low shareholder take-up of

    rights offers will turn to underwriters for quality certification to avoid the large adverse-

    selection costs of a deep subscription discount. As a result, a deep discount in an uninsured

    rights issue signals more positive information about firm quality than standby rights do

    and should be followed by significantly positive announcement day abnormal returns.

    Bohren, Eckbo, and Michalsen (1997) find empirical evidence consistent with the adverse-

    selection argument using data on rights offers on the Norwegian stock market.

    One common assumption among models of equity financing choices under information

    asymmetry is that managers of an issuing firm maximize the value of the firm, which may

    not be valid in the Chinese case. In fact, a number of studies have shown that Chinese

    firms predominantly use uninsured rights in floating SEOs and that their announcements

    are, on average, followed by significantly negative market reactions (Han & Li, 2002;

    Yuan, 2003; Zhang & Wang, 2001). Therefore, we conjecture the possibility that, becauseof high agency and political costs, uninsured rights offerings in China (having low direct

    flotation costs but large indirect costs of share depreciation) represent an attempt by the

    management to exploit existing shareholders. That is, uninsured rights are not the outcome

    of firms value-maximization behavior, but rather a result of ownership conflicts and low

    monitoring. Managers of firms that are subject to low agency and political costs will act

    upon the shareholders interests. When these managers foresee profitable investment

    projects but are unable to use internal financing, they will maximize the value of the firm

    by choosing the least expensive (in terms of direct and indirect costs) flotation method,

    i.e., firm commitment underwritten offers under the Chinese situation. We hypothesize that

    H3.3. In the existence of agency conflicts and political interference, equity financing

    choices reveal the extent of agency and political problems and the effectiveness of

    shareholder monitoring. The probability that a firm will issue uninsured rights offers is

    negatively related to managerial and institutional ownership and positively related to

    government ownership and nonessential expenditures.

    The alternative to the agency/political costs hypothesis is the binvestment opportunities

    hypothesisQ that firms employ underwriters for public offerings of seasoned equities

    because they have more profitable investment projects than do those that issue uninsured

    rights. Therefore, the probability that a firm will use rights offer is negatively related to

    proxies of investment opportunities but positively related to leverage ratios.In the next section, we discuss empirical irregularities surrounding announcements of

    dividend distributions and SEOs and conduct empirical tests of the agency/political costs

    null against the investment opportunities alternative.

    4. Empirical evidence

    4.1. Data

    We examine dividend policies and post-IPO equity financing choices for a sample of

    508 SOEs that went public before December 31, 1996. Over the period from January 1996

    through July 2000, 377 of these firms recorded a total of 1095 annual dividend

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148128

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    12/31

    announcements, including 513 stock dividends and 582 cash dividends.8 Each cash

    dividend announcement is compared with the previous dividend (if there is any) and is

    then classified as an increase, a decrease, or a no-change in dividends. Forty-three cash

    dividend announcements that have no previous dividend announcements for comparison

    are eliminated from the sample. Of the total 539 cash dividend announcements remained

    in the sample, 226 are dividend increases, 191 are dividend decreases, and 122 have no

    changes. The sample classification is detailed in Table 1.

    Over the period from January 1996 through July 2000, 348 of our sample firms

    recorded a total of 547 announcements of seasoned equity offerings (SEOs) after their

    IPOs, including announcements of 469 uninsured rights issues and 78 firm commitment

    underwritten offers.9 The sample classification presented in Table 2 is striking. While there

    is a trend toward using underwriter certification in issuing SEOs across countries (Bohren

    et al., 1997), uninsured rights continue to be very popular (representing about 87% of allSEOs) in corporate China.

    We use the following variables to proxy agency costs, political costs, liquidity, and

    investment opportunities:

    Because managers will be more likely to strip assets and transfer resources from SOEs

    to themselves if the managers fractional investment is small, we use the number of shares

    held by managers and board members as a fraction of total shares outstanding

    (MANAGER) as one of the proxies for agency costs of managerial discretion.

    Because large shareholders may have more incentive to monitor management, which

    may, in turn, reduce agency costs, we use the percentage of shares held by the top 10

    shareholders (TOPTEN), including institutional and private investors but excluding stategovernment, as the second proxy for agency costs of managerial discretion.

    With large government ownership and heavy presence of government officials in the

    board, managers are more likely to try to please politicians by maintaining high fringe

    benefits and other social responsibility programs rather than to maximize firms residuals

    (Chang & Wong, 2003). We use the percentage of shares retained by the local, state, and

    8 There are three principal reasons for choosing the January 1996 to July 2000 sample period. First, information

    on corporate fundamentals, such as earnings and dividends, may not be reliable in the early stage of development

    of an emerging market. Second, the traditional Chinese accounting system was brought from the former SovietUnion in early 1950s for the highly centralized economy and was quite different from the generally accepted

    accounting principles (GAAP) in the market economies. Different industries have different accounting regulations

    enforced by their own ministries. On July 1, 1993, the new bEnterprise Accounting StandardsQ and bEnterprise

    Financial Accounting PrinciplesQ came into effect and brought the Chinese accounting practices more close to the

    international standards. The January 1996 cut-off allows us to compute financial variables from the new

    standardized financial statements. Third, the stock price data end in July 2002. To calculate buy-and-hold returns

    over a 2-year period, the July 2000 cut-off is necessary. All data are compiled from China Securities Market and

    Accounting Research (CSMAR) data base produced by Shenzhen Guo Tai An Information and verified with

    information from www.cninfo.com.9 We note that a Chinese joint-stock company, subject to certain regulations and approval, can issue equities in

    the form of A shares (available only to domestic investors and traded in Chinese exchanges), B shares (available

    only to foreign investors and traded in Chinese exchanges), H shares (listed and traded in Hong Kong), N shares(listed and traded in New York), or a combination of these share types. Because of the small number of

    observations associated with the issuance of B-, H-, and N-shares through alternative flotation methods, we focus

    only on A-share decisions in this paper.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 129

    http:///reader/full/www.cninfo.comhttp:///reader/full/www.cninfo.comhttp:///reader/full/www.cninfo.comhttp:///reader/full/www.cninfo.com
  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    13/31

    central government (GOVNT) as a proxy for the political costs of government interference

    on enterprises.

    We use welfare expense ratio (WELFARE) as a common proxy for agency and political

    costs.10 WELFARE measures the extent of perquisite consumption, employee welfare

    expenses (such as housing subsidies and schooling), and other nonessential expenses.

    Welfare expenses provide managers opportunities to divert firms assets to their private use

    and to politicians social responsibility programs.

    We use two proxies for a firms investment opportunities: market-to-book ratio (MTB),

    calculated as the average market value of equity 3 months prior to the event day plus book

    value of assets in the previous year minus book value of equity in the previous year

    divided by the book value of total assets in the previous year, and long-term investment to

    total assets ratio (LONGINV).

    We use two proxies for a firms liquidity: cash flow to total assets ratio (CASHTA),

    defined as the operating income before depreciation minus total taxes adjusted for changes

    in deferred taxes minus gross interest expenses and dividends and divided by total assets,and leverage (LEVERAGE), defined as the ratio of long-term debt and the book value of

    total assets.

    4.2. The determinants of dividend distribution decisions

    In the spirit of Grinblatt et al. (1984), we compare the valuation effect of stock

    dividends and cash dividends on and around the day of the China Security Daily

    announcement of dividend distributions. If shareholders react positively to the announce-

    10 Welfare expenses are total expenses minus costs of goods sold, wage expenses, and interest expenses. Welfare

    expense is listed as a separate item on the balance sheet for a Chinese firm. Welfare expense ratio is welfare

    expenses divided by total expenses.

    Table 1

    Sample classification for dividend distributions

    Year Types of distribution

    Stock dividend Cash dividend All

    Increases No changes Decreases

    1996 121 30 45 26 222

    1997 98 52 41 38 229

    1998 135 74 28 19 256

    1999 104 53 54 28 239

    2000 (first half) 55 17 23 11 106

    Total 513 226 191 122 1052

    The sample consists of 508 SOEs that went public before December 31, 1996. Over the period from January 1996

    through July 2000, 377 of these firms recorded a total of 1095 annual dividend announcements including 513

    stock dividends and 582 cash dividends. Each cash dividend announcement is compared with the previousdividend (if there is any) and is then classified as an increase, a decrease, or a no change in dividends. Forty-three

    cash dividend announcements that have no previous dividend announcements for comparison are eliminated. Of

    the total 539 cash dividend announcements remained in the sample, 226 are dividend increases, 191 are dividend

    decreases, and 122 have no changes.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148130

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    14/31

    ments of stock dividends, then the signaling theory can potentially explain the stock

    dividend puzzle in China. Appendix A details the method used in computing the abnormal

    return (AR) and cumulative abnormal return (CAR) in this paper. Table 3 presents average

    AR and CAR on and around the stock dividend and cash dividend distributions.

    The examination of the table reveals a striking result. The mean 2-day abnormal return

    is significantly negative at the 5% level for stock dividend announcements, significantly

    Table 3

    Average abnormal and cumulative abnormal returns on and around dividend announcement days

    Event day Stock dividends Cash dividends

    AR CAR t-statistic Increases No change Decreases

    (%) (%)AR

    (%)

    CAR

    (%)

    t-statistic AR

    (%)

    CAR

    (%)

    t-statistic AR

    (%)

    CAR

    (%)

    t-statistic

    10 0.13 0.13 1.21 0.19 0.19 1.17 0.08 0.08 0.16 0.14 0.14 0.269 0.11 0.02 0.23 1.07 0.26 1.29 0.10 0.18 0.69 0.06 0.20 0.428 0.25 0.27 1.69 0.21 0.05 0.21 0.12 0.30 1.16 0.11 0.31 1.067 0.12 0.15 1.26 0.13 0.18 1.15 0.13 0.17 0.59 0.08 0.39 1.196 0.30 0.15 1.29 0.03 0.21 1.22 0.08 0.09 0.24 0.20 0.19 0.38

    5 0.39 0.54 2.25 0.08 0.29 1.35 0.11 0.20 0.73 0.07 0.26 0.65

    4 0.21 0.75 2.68 0.10 0.39 1.46 0.17 0.37 1.21 0.08 0.18 0.343 0.12 0.87 2.87 0.19 0.20 1.21 0.26 0.11 0.32 0.13 0.05 0.122 0.16 0.71 2.63 0.13 0.07 0.25 0.08 0.19 0.73 0.04 0.09 0.201 0.15 0.56 2.27 0.14 0.21 1.22 0.11 0.30 1.24 0.16 0.07 0.160 1.02 0.46 2.16 0.93 1.14 3.55 0.28 0.58 1.56 0.15 0.22 0.511 0.18 0.64 2.52 0.27 1.41 3.82 0.19 0.39 1.32 0.06 0.28 0.732 0.16 0.80 2.79 0.24 1.17 3.59 0.12 0.51 1.49 0.11 0.17 0.353 0.29 1.09 3.46 0.11 1.06 3.47 0.09 0.60 1.61 0.08 0.09 0.214 0.18 0.91 2.95 0.26 1.32 3.73 0.16 0.44 1.38 0.10 0.19 0.385 0.24 0.67 2.57 0.19 1.13 3.54 0.13 0.31 1.19 0.16 0.03 0.106 0.17 0.50 2.20 0.16 1.29 3.68 0.14 0.45 1.40 0.04 0.01 0.06

    7 0.10 0.40 2.01 0.20 1.49 3.90 0.16 0.29 1.22 0.14 0.13 0.218 0.15 0.55 2.26 0.25 1.24 3 .62 0.12 0.41 1.35 0.09 0.22 0.529 0.18 0.37 1.95 0.08 1.16 3.57 0.17 0.24 0.78 0.12 0.10 0.2610 0.11 0.26 1.65 0.12 1.04 3.44 0.05 0.19 0.65 0.13 0.23 0.56

    Table 2

    Sample classification for corporate financing choices

    Year Types of offering

    Uninsured rights Underwritten All

    1996 82 11 93

    1997 66 24 90

    1998 114 16 130

    1999 159 18 177

    2000 (first half) 48 9 57

    Total 469 78 547

    The sample consists of 508 SOEs that went public before December 31, 1995. Over the period from January 1996

    through July 2000, 348 of these firms recorded a total of 547 announcements of seasoned equity offerings (SEOs)

    after their IPOs, including announcements of 469 uninsured rights issues and 78 firm commitment underwritten

    offers.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 131

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    15/31

    positive at the 5% level for dividend increases, insignificantly positive for no-change in

    dividends, and insignificantly negative for dividend reductions. Fig. 1 portrays the

    behavior of the daily average cumulative abnormal returns around dividend announce-

    ments. A large and pronounced decline in CAR is observed for stock dividends, and a

    large and pronounced increase is observed for cash dividend increases during the event

    window. On average, Chinese investors react negatively to stock dividend distributions but

    positively to cash dividend distributions. Therefore, the bsignaling/retained earning

    hypothesisQ of Grinblatt et al. (1984) cannot explain the predominant use of stock

    dividends in China. This begs the question: If stock dividends cannot signal good news on

    the future prospects, why do firms in China bother to distribute stock dividends?

    To shed some light on the answer to this question, we first examine sample statistics for

    proxies of firms agency and political costs, liquidity, and investment opportunities. The

    results are presented in Table 4. Two important regularities emerge from the table: (1)Firms distributing cash dividends have, on average, larger managerial and institutional

    ownership of shares, smaller fractional government ownership, and less nonessential

    expense ratio than do firms issuing stock dividends or no dividend. (2) Firms distributing

    stock dividends appear to have, on average, larger managerial and institutional share

    ownership, smaller government control, and less welfare expenses than do firms that pay

    no dividend.

    We then proceed to test the agency/political costs versus the liquidity/investment

    opportunities hypotheses by estimating multinomial logit regressions predicting whether a

    firm will distribute cash dividend, stock dividend, or no dividend. These regressions allow

    us to observe important nonlinear effects while simultaneously controlling for a variety offactors, which are hypothesized to affect corporate dividend policies in China. Table 5

    presents empirical results from the multinomial logit regressions. The first two sets of

    regressions in the table estimate the determinants of cash dividend distributions, while the

    Fig. 1. Cumulative abnormal returns on and around the dividend announcement day.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148132

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    16/31

    last set of regressions estimates the determinants of stock dividends. To account for

    possible multicollinearities among independent variables, each set of regressions is

    estimated with and without MTB and LEVERAGE.11

    In regression sets 1 and 2, the coefficient estimates for MANAGER are significantly

    positive at the 5% and 10% level, respectively, no matter whether MTB and LEVERAGE

    are included in the regressions. The coefficient estimates for TOPTEN are significantly

    positive at the 5% level in regression set 1 but are only significantly positive at the 10%

    when all variables are included in regression set 2. If either MTB or LEVERAGE, or both,

    is dropped from the regression, TOPTEN is insignificant, although it has the right sign.

    The coefficient estimates for GOVNT and WELFARE are significantly negative, all at the

    5% level. These results, by and large, are consistent with the prediction of theb

    agency/political costs hypothesisQ. Firms with higher managerial and institutional stock owner-

    ship, smaller government control, and lower nonessential expenditures are more likely to

    distribute cash dividends. The coefficient estimates for MTB, LONGINV, CASHTA, and

    LEVERAGE have the same signs as predicted by the alternative liquidity/investment

    opportunities hypothesis, but none is statistically significant. There is little evidence that

    firms with better investment opportunities withhold cash dividends.

    In regression set 3, the coefficient estimates for MANAGER is significantly positive at

    the 10% level when only MTB is omitted or when all variables are included in the

    regression. The coefficient estimates for GOVNT are significantly negative at the 5% level

    Table 4

    Sample statistics for variables used in studying corporate dividend policy

    Cash dividend (N=539) Stock dividend (N=513) No dividend (N=54)

    Mean S.D. Median S.D. Mean S.D. Median S.D. Mean S.D. Median S.D.

    MANAGER 1.44 1.20 1.53 1.64 0.57 1.25 0.69 1.85 0.10 0.35 0.08 0.21

    TOPTEN 24.54 14.15 27.64 19.22 16.25 14.49 17.88 20.07 11.48 10.96 13.10 15.94

    GOVNT 13.39 17.21 15.60 20.85 19.24 21.93 18.66 24.64 31.03 19.74 28.41 22.80

    WELFARE 1.26 0.85 1.44 2.06 3.35 1.57 2.96 3.55 4.84 1.77 4.29 2.90

    MTB 1.68 1.14 2.04 2.96 1.29 0.83 1.55 1.18 1.10 0.76 1.26 1.14

    CASHTA 9.27 2.14 11.13 8.62 8.54 2.33 9.30 7.26 8.32 2.09 9.14 7.51

    LEVERAGE 10.17 4.35 13.02 8.44 11.30 3.69 10.80 6.58 12.16 5.77 11.04 7.33

    LONGINV 10.22 1.72 9.09 5.27 9.07 1.55 8.25 5.29 9.29 2.16 7.92 4.51

    MANAGER is the number of shares held by managers and board members divided by the total number of shares

    outstanding. TOPTEN is the percentage of shares held by the top 10 shareholders, including institutional and

    private investors but excluding the state government. GOVNT is the percentage of shares retained by the state

    government. WELFARE is the nonessential expenditures (total expenses minus costs of goods sold, wage

    expenses, and interest expenses) as a fraction of total expenses. CASHTA is cash flow to total assets ratio,

    calculated as the operating income before depreciation minus total taxes adjusted for changes in deferred taxes

    minus gross interest expenses and dividends and divided by total assets. LEVERAGE is the long-term debt as a

    fraction of the book value of total assets. MTB is the market-to-book ratio, calculated as the average market value

    of equity 3 months prior to the event day plus the book value of assets in the previous year minus book value of

    equity in the previous year divided by the book value of total assets in the previous year. LONGINV is long-term

    investment expenditure to total asset ratio.

    11 Xu and Wang (1999) documents a significantly positive relation between market-to-book ratios and

    ownership concentration. Leverage ratios are also suspected to be correlated to both ownership structures and

    market-to-book ratios.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 133

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    17/31

    Table 5

    Multinomial logit regression on corporate dividend decisions

    (1) Cash dividend vs. no dividend (2) Cash dividend vs. stock dividend (3) StoIntercept 2.261*

    (5.250)1.637*(3.966)

    1.908*(4.607)

    1.162*(3.438)

    2.600*(5.861)

    3.288*(6.522)

    2.039*(1.925)

    1.735*(4.193)

    2.11(4.62

    MANAGER 0.840*

    (2.044)

    0.868*

    (2.183)

    1.207*

    (2.642)

    0.923*

    (2.349)

    0.720y

    (1.825)

    0.615y

    (1.870)

    0.795y

    (1.863)

    0.866*

    (2.106)

    0.42

    (1.388

    TOPTEN 0.507*

    (2.182)

    0.581*

    (2.609)

    0.484*

    (2.366)

    0.410*

    (2.204)

    0.109

    (1.085)

    0.241

    (1.482)

    0.200

    (1.399)

    0.323y

    (1.858)

    0.08

    (0.863

    GOVNT 1.307*(3.014)

    1.622*(3.960)

    0.874*(2.533)

    0.791*(2.362)

    1.382*(2.961)

    1.490*(3.225)

    0.925*(2.530)

    0.724*(2.141)

    1.09(2.30

    WELFARE 1.911*(2.860)

    2.240*(3.244)

    1.828*(2.715)

    1.465*(2.165)

    2.019*(3.007)

    1.258*(2.013)

    1.833*(2.450)

    1.503*(2.220)

    0.70(1.16

    MTB 1.119

    (1.299)

    0.719

    (1.189)

    1.065

    (1.220)

    0.834

    (1.305)

    LONGINV 0.229

    (0.797)

    0.304

    (0.824)

    0.105

    (0.400)

    0.141

    (0.584)

    0.344

    (0.975)

    0.120

    (0.522)

    0.086

    (0.603)

    0.195

    (0.733)

    0.24

    (0.755

    CASHTA 0.144

    (0.650)

    0.285

    (1.232)

    0.160

    (0.750)

    0.206

    (0.932)

    0.315

    (1.264)

    0.466

    (1.380)

    0.207

    (0.965)

    0.293

    (1.114)

    0.24

    (1.180

    LEVERAGE 0.404(0.922)

    0.247(0.719)

    0.370(0.950)

    0.318(0.802)

    Pseudo R2 0.220 0.247 0.195 0.163 0.207 0.225 0.210 0.180 0.18

    The dependent variable is zero for firms that distribute no dividend in a given year, one for firms that distribute stock dividen

    dividends. The independent variables consist of the proportion of shares held by managers and directors (MANAGER), the prop

    shareholders, excluding the government (TOPTEN), the proportion of shares held by the government (GOVNT), the ratio o

    (WELFARE), market-to-book ratio (MTB), long-term investment expenditure to total asset ratio (LONGINV), cash flow to todebt to total asset ratio (LEVERAGE). Figures in parentheses are t-statistics.

    * Level of significance: 5%.y Level of significance: 10%.

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    18/31

    for all regressions, while the coefficient estimates for WELFARE are significant when all

    variables are included in the regression. Although the coefficient estimates for TOPTEN

    are of the right sign, they are not statistically significant. We also interpret this result as, by

    and large, consistent with the prediction of the agency/political costs hypothesis. Firms

    with higher insider share ownership, smaller government control, and lower nonessential

    expenses are more likely to distribute stock dividends. Again, the coefficient estimates for

    MTB, LONGINV, CASHTA, and LEVERAGE have the same sign as predicted by the

    liquidity/investment opportunities hypothesis, but are not statistically significant. There is

    sufficient evidence that stock dividends are not signals of better investment opportunities,

    but rather signals of mild agency problem and political influence in the Chinese case.

    4.3. Long-term performance of dividend distribution firms

    The agency/political costs hypothesis predicts that firms with low agency and political

    costs and effective shareholders monitoring will distribute cash dividend, and those with

    moderate agency and political costs may use stock dividends in lieu of cash dividends to

    separate themselves from firms having high agency and political costs. This indicates that

    cash dividend firms will face better long-term stock-market valuation of their shares than

    stock dividend firms will.

    Under the alternative liquidity/investment opportunities hypothesis, firms that have the

    best investment opportunities signal their quality through stock dividends. The short-term

    negative market reaction to stock dividends announcements simply reflects under-

    valuation of firms shares by investors. After the firms have successfully implementedtheir projects, their stock prices will eventually go up. A reversal of their fortune will be

    expected in the market in the long run. Therefore, firms issuing stock dividends will have

    better long-term stock performance than will those distributing cash as dividends.

    We measure a firms long-term stock performance using the average and median buy-

    and-hold abnormal return during 6-, 12-, 18-, and 24-month horizons after the dividend

    announcement date (BHARs

    ). Appendix A details the methodology used in computing

    BHARs

    . The null hypothesis of no abnormal buy-and-hold return is tested using

    skewness-adjusted t-statistics. A nonparametric Wilcoxon signed-rank test is also

    constructed to test the null hypothesis that the median BHARs

    is zero.

    As shown in Table 6, the average and median buy-and-hold abnormal returns aresignificantly positive for firms paying cash dividends at the 6-, 18-, and 24-month holding

    periods, while they are significantly negative for firms paying stock dividends at the 12-,

    18-, and 24-month holding periods. The average and median buy-and-hold abnormal

    returns are negative for firms with neither cash dividends nor stock dividends but are only

    statistically significant for the 18-month holding period. We view the empirical evidence

    described here as consistent with the bagency/political costs hypothesisQ.12

    12 According to the agency/political cost hypotheses, firms distributing stock dividends have milder agency/

    political costs than do firms distributing no dividends. Table 6 also shows that firms paying no dividends havenegative mean abnormal returns, although they are often not statistically significant and the magnitudes are often

    smaller than that for the firms paying stock dividends. These kinds of results do not seem to be totally consistent

    with the implication of the agency/political costs theory.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 135

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    19/31

    Some researchers may be skeptical about the use of market-based performance

    measures because Chinese stock markets are often plagued with speculative activities. To

    illustrate, at the end of 1999, more than 99% of the participants in the Shanghai SecuritiesExchange consisted of small individual investors rather than institutional investors. In

    addition, share turnover (defined as trading volume divided by the total number of

    outstanding shares, a measure for trading activities) exceeded 400%; that is, on average,

    each stock changed hands more than four times per year, which is more than 10 times as

    high as that of international markets. Therefore, it is of no surprise that Chinese stock

    markets have been described as a bcasinoQ because of the tremendous short-term

    speculation that takes place within it (Chang & Wong, 2003). For this reason, we

    complement market-based performance measures with accounting-based ratios including

    return on asset (ROA), return on equity (ROE), and return on sales (ROS).

    Table 7 presents the mean and standard deviation of ROA, ROE, and ROS for cashdividend, stock dividend, and no-dividend firms in 1997, 1998, and 1999, respectively. As

    shown in the table, the mean ROA, ROE, and ROS for cash dividend firms is higher than

    those for stock dividend and no-dividend firms each year, suggesting that, on average,

    firms paying cash dividends have better performance than do firms issuing stock dividends

    or no dividends. However, the mean ROA, ROE, and ROS for stock dividend firms are

    similar to those for no-dividend firms. The overall evidence seem to support the view that

    dividend policies are value relevant in China.

    4.4. The determinants of equity financing decisions

    To explore in greater depth the financial characteristics of firms that use rights issues,

    we first compare the liquidity and investment opportunities of firms that issue uninsured

    Table 6

    Long-term market-based performance of dividend distribution firms

    Period

    (months)

    Average buy-and-hold abnormal return (%)

    No dividend firms Cash dividend firms Stock dividend firms

    Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

    6 1.21 (1.09) 1.08 [1.16] 2.93* (3.05) 2.28* [2.12] 1.79 (1.51) 1.39 [1.27]12 1.42 (1.15) 1.33 [1.18] 1.48 (1.36) 1.19 [1.04] 2.47* (2.75) 1.83y [1.82]18 2.18* (2.18) 1.80y [1.86] 2.36* (2.58) 1.95y [1.88] 3.12* (3.36) 2.16* [2.37]24 0.78 (0.91) 0.63 [0.84] 3.29* (3.61) 2.45* [2.31] 2.61* (3.18) 2.08* [2.24]The average buy-and-hold abnormal return (BHAR) for s months is calculated as BHARs 1N

    PNi1

    jst1 1 ri ; t jst1 1 rc ; i ; t , where ri,t is the monthly stock return for announcement firm i and rc,i,t is

    the monthly return on control portfolio for firm i. The test statistic for the null hypothesis of no average buy-and-

    hold abnormal return (figure in parentheses) is the skewness-adjusted t-statistic calculated as

    adjusted tBHARs tBHARs 13ffiffiffiNp tBHARs 2skews ffiffiffiNp6 skews, where tBHARs is the usual t-statistic for BHARsand skew

    sis the skewness of the BHARt series (t=1,2,. . .,s). The test statistic for the null hypothesis of the

    median buy-and-hold abnormal return (figure in brackets) is the nonparametric Wilcoxon signed-rank test

    statistic, calculated as sign ps 0:5 =ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

    ps 1 psNp

    , where ps

    is the percentage of positive abnormal buy-

    and-hold returns during s months.

    * Statistically significant at the 5% level.y Statistically significant at the 10% level.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148136

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    20/31

    rights with those that use firm commitment underwritten offers.13 We calculate the average

    of CASHTA and LEVERAGE ratios, which represent a firms liquidity and debt capacity,

    and MTB and LONGINV, which represent its investment opportunities. If a firm issues

    new shares in 1996, we include it in computing the financial ratios of 1995, and so on and

    so forth.

    As shown in Table 8, cash flow as a fraction of total assets is slightly higher for firms

    that use underwritten offers than it is for those that issue uninsured rights in every year

    from 1995 through 1999, with the gap growing from one percentage point in 1995 to about

    two percentage points in 1999. The average long-term debt as a fraction of total assets is

    lower for firms that use underwritten offers than it is for those that issue uninsured rights

    over the period covered. The market-to-book ratio, a measure of investors evaluation of a

    firms investment opportunities and future profitability, and the expenditures on long-term

    investment projects as a fraction of total assets are also higher for firms using underwritten

    offers than they are for firms issuing uninsured rights. These comparative statistics are

    inconsistent with the predictions of the signaling model.

    We then compute the abnormal returns and cumulative abnormal returns on and aroundthe announcements of SEOs. Table 9 presents average AR and CAR, and Fig. 2 portrays

    the behavior of the average CAR during the event window. A large and pronounced

    decline in CAR is observed for uninsured rights issues, and a large and pronounced

    increase is observed for underwritten offers. In fact, the mean abnormal returns over a 2-

    day period that includes the day of the China Security Daily announcement and the day

    preceding the announcement for underwritten offers and rights issues (t-statistics) are

    4.40% (6.87) and 2.57% (4.36), respectively. On the average, investors react favorablyto firm commitment underwritten offers but negatively to uninsured rights issues. The

    results are inconsistent with the predictions of the adverse-selection model.

    Table 7

    Accounting-based performance measures for dividend distribution firms

    Accounting ratio No-dividend firms Cash dividend firms Stock dividend firms

    Mean S.D. Mean S.D. Mean S.D.

    ROA1997 0.046 (0.049) 0.060 (0.071) 0.044 (0.058)

    ROA1998 0.038 (0.041) 0.065 (0.083) 0.031 (0.042)

    ROA1999 0.044 (0.058) 0.055 (0.070) 0.049 (0.066)

    ROE1997 0.074 (0.095) 0.082 (0.127) 0.069 (0.106)

    ROE1998 0.072 (0.108) 0.086 (0.133) 0.073 (0.115)

    ROE1999 0.068 (0.096) 0.080 (0.109) 0.058 (0.098)

    ROS1997 0.087 (1.262) 0.104 (0.173) 0.091 (0.188)

    ROS1998 0.092 (1.437) 0.115 (0.205) 0.086 (0.167)

    ROS1999 0.085 (1.394) 0.108 (0.190) 0.082 (0.159)

    Definitions of the performance variables are as follows: ROA (return on assets) is after-tax profits divided by thebook value of total assets. ROE (return on equity) is after-tax profits divided by the book value of shareholders

    equity. ROS (return on sales) is after-tax profits divided by gross sales revenue. Figures in parentheses are

    standard deviations.

    13 Note that no standby rights issues are observed on Chinese stock markets over the period covered in this

    study.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 137

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    21/31

    We believe that agency/political costs consideration can help explain why rights issues

    and underwritten offers are followed by significantly negative and positive stock-market

    valuations, respectively.

    This leaves us with the following puzzle: If uninsured rights do not signal good news to

    the market, why are they predominantly used by Chinese firms in floating SEOs?

    To enhance the search for the underlying causes of the rights issue anomaly, Table 10 isconstructed to present the mean and median statistics for fractional managerial,

    institutional, and government ownership, as well as the ratio of nonessential expenses

    to total expenses, categorized by SEO flotation methods. An beyeball analysisQ ofTable 10

    yields comparisons that are important regularities predicted by agency/political costs

    paradigm: Firms using underwriter certification have, on average, larger managerial and

    institutional ownership of shares than do firms using uninsured rights. The only exception

    is that rights issuers have a slightly larger managerial ownership in 1997. Another

    distinguishing feature of firms that issue uninsured rights is that the variable GOVNT, the

    proportion of shares owned by the state government, is far larger than for firms using

    underwritten offers. Moreover, firms using underwritten offers have, on average, less

    nonessential expense ratio than do those issuing uninsured rights in every year during the

    sample period.

    Table 8

    Liquidity and investment opportunities for firms classified by SEO flotation choices

    Year Uninsured rights Underwritten offers

    Mean S.D. Median S.D. Mean S.D. Median S.D.

    CASHTA 1995 7.48 5.21 6.95 8.22 8.41 7.20 8.86 10.13

    1996 7.33 5.10 7.08 8.29 9.11 7.86 9.39 11.20

    1997 9.04 7.25 8.27 11.31 11.25 9.82 10.81 14.25

    1998 9.58 6.84 8.92 11.26 11.60 9.00 10.73 13.51

    1999 8.80 6.92 8.33 10.10 10.69 7.88 11.05 13.62

    LEVERAGE 1995 11.84 6.02 12.07 7.55 8.43 5.31 7.91 5.10

    1996 9.16 6.05 8.93 7.14 9.12 5.00 8.66 6.03

    1997 9.55 5.39 8.82 5.80 6.18 3.95 5.83 4.41

    1998 9.08 5.23 9.63 6.10 8.64 5.27 8.95 6.38

    1999 10.14 6.38 10.52 7.33 8.94 6.12 8.50 6.60

    MTB 1995 1.09 0.95 1.22 1.60 1.38 1.18 1.26 1.721996 1.28 1.04 1.31 1.66 1.48 1.23 1.44 1.70

    1997 1.41 1.15 1.37 1.81 1.64 1.20 1.58 1.93

    1998 1.31 0.97 1.28 1.70 1.35 1.06 1.39 1.82

    1999 1.12 0.88 1.09 1.31 1.26 1.06 1.30 1.44

    LONGINV 1995 8.02 2.37 6.91 4.55 10.93 3.60 9.84 6.11

    1996 8.28 3.30 7.53 4.31 10.45 4.26 9.36 4.90

    1997 9.54 4.02 9.18 5.33 11.93 3.89 11.08 6.00

    1998 7.36 2.74 7.19 4.01 9.44 3.65 9.06 5.14

    1999 8.62 3.43 8.95 5.06 10.25 3.11 9.68 4.62

    CASHTA is the cash flow to total assets ratio, calculated as the operating income before depreciation minus total

    taxes adjusted for changes in deferred taxes minus gross interest expenses and dividends and divided by totalassets. LEVERAGE is the long-term debt as a fraction of the book value of the total assets. MTB is the market-to-

    book ratio, calculated as the average market value of equity 3 months prior to the event day plus the book value of

    assets in the previous year minus the book value of equity in the previous year divided by the book value of total

    assets in the previous year. LONGINV is the long-term investment expenditure to total asset ratio.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148138

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    22/31

    Based on the preliminary analysis on statistics reported in Tables 10 and 11, the

    more favorable characteristics belong to firms with underwritten offers, which exhibit

    more liquidity, less leverage ratio, better investment opportunities, and evidence of

    lower agency/political costs than do firms issuing uninsured rights. Perhaps, the most

    striking feature is that the average abnormal return is distinctly positive for theissuers of firm commitment public offerings but negative for the issuers of uninsured

    rights.

    To test the above hypotheses, we test a logit model of a firms choice of alternative

    SEO flotation methods. The dependent variable equals to 1 if a firm issues uninsured

    rights, and 0 otherwise. The independent variables consist of proxies for agency costs,

    political costs and investment opportunities, leverage ratio, the initial IPO return (IPOR),

    and the logarithm of the proceeds from SEOs (SEOVALUE). IPOR is included in the

    logit regression to proxy the quality of a firm. Su and Fleisher (1999) show that Chinese

    firms of better quality tend to underprice more and return to the secondary market to

    issue SEOs in greater amount more quickly. SEOVALUE is included to control for the

    size effect. Perhaps, sheer size has an informational advantage in that economies of scale

    increase the likelihood that investors will know something about these firms, enabling

    Table 9

    Average abnormal returns (ARt) and cumulative abnormal returns (CARK,L) on and around SEO announcement

    days

    Event day Rights issues Underwritten offers

    ARt CARK,L t-statistic AR t CARK,L t-statistic

    10 0.14 0.05 0.16 0.17 0.17 0.529 0.07 0.12 0.38 0.13 0.30 0.748 0.15 0.03 0.11 0.22 0.52 1.597 0.13 0.16 0.44 0.39 0.13 0.416 0.10 0.06 0.19 0.15 0.02 0.115 0.15 0.09 0.29 0.20 0.18 0.554 0.18 0.09 0.30 0.14 0.32 0.793 0.11 0.20 0.57 0.11 0.43 1.37

    2 0.26 0.06 0.20 0.18 0.05 0.22

    1 0.74 0.68 1.71 2.93 2.98 4.580 1.83 2.51 5.75 1.47 4.45 6.951 0.10 2.41 5.46 0.33 4.12 6.442 0.09 2.32 5.14 0.64 3.48 5.433 0.31 2.01 4.08 0.28 3.76 5.874 0.44 1.57 2.61 0.30 4.06 6.345 0.27 1.84 3.40 0.16 4.22 6.596 0.11 1.95 3.82 0.15 4.07 6.367 0.15 1.80 3.27 0.11 3.96 6.188 0.33 1.47 2.32 0.52 4.48 7.029 0.08 1.39 2.04 0.36 4.84 7.5610

    0.09

    1.48

    2.35 0.21 5.05 7.89

    The abnormal return for firm i on day t is ARi,t=Ri ,tRc,i,t, where Ri,t is the return for firm i on day t, andRc,i,t is the return for the control portfolio of firm i on day t. The average abnormal returns for each trading

    day is ARt 1NPN

    i1 ARi;t, where N is the number of stocks. The average cumulative abnormal returnsfrom day K to L is CARK;L 1N

    PNi1 CARi;K;L.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 139

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    23/31

    them to make better informed investment decisions when opportunities to purchase new

    shares arise.

    Empirical results from three logit estimations of the probability of rights issues are in

    Table 12. The coefficient estimates on the MANAGER variable have the correct sign but

    are insignificant in all three regressions. That is, the probability of rights issues does notdecrease directly with a firms managerial ownership. However, the coefficient estimates

    for TOPTEN are significantly negative at the 5% level, as predicted by the agency/political

    costs hypothesis. Firms that are more closely monitored by large institutional shareholders

    are less likely to issue uninsured rights. The coefficient estimates for GOVNT are

    significantly positive at the 5% level, indicating that firms with larger government

    ownership and more political intervention are more likely to use uninsured rights in

    issuing SEOs. In addition, the probability of rights issues are positively related to the

    nonessential expenses, and the relationship is statistically significant at the 10% level. This

    renders further support to the agency/political cost approach to explain rights issues puzzle

    in China.The coefficient estimates for LONGINV and LEVERAGE are of the correct signs, as

    predicted by the alternative investment opportunities hypothesis, but they are not

    statistically significant. The coefficient estimates for MTB is not only of incorrect sign

    but also statistically insignificant. The evidence presented in Table 12 provides no support

    for the investment opportunities hypothesis.

    It is interesting to note that the coefficient estimate for IPOR is insignificant, suggesting

    that there is no relationship between the probability of using rights issues in floating SEOs

    and the degree of IPO underpricing, which is consistent with Su (2003) and Su (2004).

    However, the coefficient estimate for SEOVALUE is significantly negative, implying that

    the probability of using a underwriter increases in the size of the issue. This is probably

    because larger issues have more diverse ownership of shares and less government

    interference.

    Fig. 2. Cumulative abnormal returns on and around the SEO announcement day.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148140

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    24/31

    4.5. Valuation effect of SEO announcements

    We now study the stock price reaction to SEOs made by Chinese firms. A larger

    number of studies on U.S. firms have convincingly showed that SEOs are associated

    with a decrease in announcement firms stock price, especially when the flotation

    method used is firm commitment underwritten offers. However, some studies (Bohrenet al., 1997; Kang & Stulz, 1996) document positive investors reaction to uninsured

    rights issues in other countries. As mentioned in Section 4.1, on average, investors

    respond negatively to uninsured rights offers but positively to underwritten offers in

    China.

    To explain the abnormal returns surrounding SEO issue announcements, we estimate

    the following cross-section regression using generalized least squares (GLS):

    CARi;1;0 a1 a2SEOVALUEi a3CARi;11;2 a4STDi a5SHAREi a6MANAGERi a7TOPTENi a8GOVNTi a9WELFAREi a10DUMMYi ni 1

    Table 10

    Agency and political costs for firms classified by SEO flotation choices

    Year Uninsured rights Underwritten offers

    Mean S.D. Median S.D. Mean S.D. Median S.D.

    MANAGER 1995 0.46 0.51 0.52 0.60 1.63 1.67 1.49 1.73

    1996 0.81 0.69 0.70 1.03 1.34 1.15 1.22 1.40

    1997 1.09 0.96 1.10 1.22 1.07 0.98 1.05 1.31

    1998 1.26 1.00 1.08 1.33 1.55 1.36 1.47 1.75

    1999 1.14 0.96 1.07 1.24 1.83 1.47 1.68 2.05

    TOPTEN 1995 5.05 6.22 5.28 8.15 14.62 12.30 13.20 15.17

    1996 12.64 11.05 11.38 16.31 17.10 15.46 15.83 18.75

    1997 9.82 8.61 9.39 13.05 21.44 18.20 19.60 25.13

    1998 10.77 8.35 9.62 11.00 19.85 17.26 18.35 23.28

    1999 8.83 7.18 8.40 11.33 24.06 20.26 22.39 31.05

    GOVNT 1995 34.08 29.55 37.50 51.33 14.24 16.29 13.20 18.411996 30.03 27.60 32.85 46.34 12.62 14.08 14.80 19.36

    1997 28.25 26.42 29.71 41.66 13.48 15.17 14.63 19.83

    1998 31.50 34.00 34.62 52.04 11.60 13.52 12.48 16.00

    1999 27.58 24.10 29.01 42.61 10.94 12.87 11.40 15.99

    WELFARE 1995 5.72 1.73 5.48 6.91 2.36 1.03 2.08 3.44

    1996 5.14 2.30 4.80 6.21 2.52 1.12 2.37 3.10

    1997 6.03 3.22 5.64 7.84 1.82 0.90 1.65 2.10

    1998 5.33 3.05 4.96 6.32 1.62 0.85 1.47 2.25

    1999 4.85 2.68 4.61 5.96 1.73 1.01 1.50 2.24

    MANAGER is the number of shares held by managers and board members divided by the total number of shares

    outstanding. TOPTEN is the percentage of shares held by the top 10 shareholders, including institutional andprivate investors but excluding the state government. GOVNT is the percentage of shares retained by the state

    government. WELFARE is the nonessential expenditures (total expenses minus costs of goods sold, wage

    expenses, and interest expenses) as a fraction of total expenses.

    D. Su / China Economic Review 16 (2005) 118148 141

  • 8/14/2019 Corporate financenext term and state enterprise reform in previous termChinanext term

    25/31

    where DUMMYi is a dummy variable that takes value one if the issue uses uninsuredrights and zero otherwise; CARi,1,0 is the cumulative abnormal return during the 2-day

    announcement window for the ith issue; SHAREi is the ratio of the number of shares

    offered to the number of shares outstanding prior to the offer, a proxy for the extent of

    share dilution in the case for underwritten offers and the degree of potential shareholder

    take-up in the case of rights issues; CARi, 12,2 is the cumulative daily abnormal

    returns during a 10-day period, beginning at 12 days before the issue announcement day,

    a proxy detecting possible stock price run-up prior to the event day; and STDi is

    standard deviation of stock returns calculated over a period from 122 days before the

    announcement day and 122 days after the announcement, a proxy for the risk of the

    issue.The results contained in Table 12 indicate that the proportion of shares retained by

    state government and held by institutional investors are two important variables to

    explain the cross-section variation in abnormal returns around SEO announcements. The

    coefficient estimate for GOVNT is significantly negative at the 10% level in regressions

    I, II, and IV and significantly negative at the 5% level in regression II when

    SEOVALUE is added to the list of independent variables. There is strong evidence that

    investors reaction more posit