Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·...

43
Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments James Feyrer and Bruce Sacerdote 1 Draft: September 2007 Using a new database of islands throughout the Atlantic, Pacific and Indian Oceans we find a robust positive relationship between the number of years spent as a European colony and current GDP per capita. We argue that the nature of discovery and colonization of islands provides random variation in the length and type of colonial experience. We instrument for length of colonization using variation in prevailing wind patterns. We argue that wind speed and direction had a significant effect on historical colonial rule but do not have a direct effect on GDP today. The data also suggest that years as a colony after 1700 are more beneficial than earlier years. We also find a discernable pecking order amongst the colonial powers, with years under US, British, French and Dutch rule having more beneficial effects than Spanish or Portuguese rule. Our finding of a strong connection between modern income and years of colonization is conditional on being colonized at all since each of the islands in our dataset spent some time under colonial rule. 1 Feyrer, Dartmouth College: [email protected] ; Sacerdote, Dartmouth College and NBER: [email protected] ; We thank Esther Duflo for superb editing and three anonymous referees for very useful comments. We thank Lauren Burrows, Katie Jaxheimer, and Celia Carmen for outstanding research assistance and the National Science Foundation for generous support. Seminar participants at MIT, NBER, Brown, University of Houston, Texas A&M, and other universities provided helpful comments. 1

Transcript of Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·...

Page 1: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments

James Feyrer and Bruce Sacerdote1

Draft: September 2007 Using a new database of islands throughout the Atlantic, Pacific and Indian Oceans we find a robust positive relationship between the number of years spent as a European colony and current GDP per capita. We argue that the nature of discovery and colonization of islands provides random variation in the length and type of colonial experience. We instrument for length of colonization using variation in prevailing wind patterns. We argue that wind speed and direction had a significant effect on historical colonial rule but do not have a direct effect on GDP today. The data also suggest that years as a colony after 1700 are more beneficial than earlier years. We also find a discernable pecking order amongst the colonial powers, with years under US, British, French and Dutch rule having more beneficial effects than Spanish or Portuguese rule. Our finding of a strong connection between modern income and years of colonization is conditional on being colonized at all since each of the islands in our dataset spent some time under colonial rule.

1 Feyrer, Dartmouth College: [email protected]; Sacerdote, Dartmouth College and NBER: [email protected]; We thank Esther Duflo for superb editing and three anonymous referees for very useful comments. We thank Lauren Burrows, Katie Jaxheimer, and Celia Carmen for outstanding research assistance and the National Science Foundation for generous support. Seminar participants at MIT, NBER, Brown, University of Houston, Texas A&M, and other universities provided helpful comments.

1

Page 2: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

I. Introduction

Understanding the variation in income across countries remains one of the most

important research questions in economics. This paper examines one potentially major

cause of long term income differences between countries – variation in the nature and

length of colonization by Europeans. We use a new dataset of islands in the Pacific,

Atlantic, and Indian oceans that were colonized during the Age of Discovery. The main

advantage of our new dataset is random variation in the colonial experience. We argue

that the finding and colonizing of the islands in our dataset has a large random

component and that the colonial experiences of our islands constitute a natural

experiment. We test this conjecture by using wind patterns as an instrument. Wind was

crucial during the Age of Discovery, but is not relevant to modern travel and therefore

provides an ideal instrument for the colonial experience.

The central finding in our paper is that the length of colonial period is strongly positively

related to modern outcomes.2 In order to asses the randomness of the colonial experience

(colonizers may settle the best places first and give them up last), we instrument for the

year of European discovery and subsequent length of colonial period using data on wind

patterns. The IV results are extremely similar to the OLS results, which is consistent

with our assertion that much of the variation in the colonization of islands is random.

Our finding is quite robust within our islands data set and we show it also holds within

the Acemoglu Robinson Johnson [2002] set of continental countries.3 We also find that

the impact of colonial regimes varies by the identity of the colonizer and the timing of

colonialism. Pre-enlightenment colonization (i.e. in the 1500 and 1600s) and

colonization by Spain and Portugal are found to be less beneficial than later colonization.

We are hardly the first to examine the relationship between colonial rule and modern

outcomes. Historians and political scientists have emphasized the long term negative

2 This is conditional upon being a colony at all. Since all of our islands had at least a short colonial period, we cannot identify the effect of "never a colony" on modern outcomes. 3 We define a colonial year as one in which Britain, France, the Netherlands, Germany, Spain, Portugal, Japan, or the US had political control of the island and had officially designated the island to be a colony, territory or protectorate.

2

Page 3: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

consequences of colonial rule including the possible inability of former colonies to

transition to a stable form of self government or the possible negative effects of resource

extraction.4 Recent economic work on the importance of institutions has emphasized the

colonial legacy. La Porta, Lopez de Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny [1997, 1998] show that

former colonies of English common law countries have more developed capital markets

than former colonies with French civil law. Banerjee and Iyer [2005] look at the effect of

differences in colonial property rights institutions in India. Acemoglu, Johnson and

Robinson [2001, 2002] show that the form of colonization (extractive versus heavy

settlement by Europeans) tended to determine the type of institutions created in the

country and therefore strongly affected modern outcomes. Engerman and Sokoloff

[2003, 2005] hypothesize that forms of colonialism which promoted severe inequality

hampered the future growth prospects of a colony.

Obviously causality is problematic in considering the effect of institutions on income.

The literature has attempted to deal with this reverse causality through the use of

instrumental variables, but finding appropriate instruments is difficult. Mauro [1995]

uses ethnolinguistic fractionalization to instrument for corruption. Hall and Jones [1999]

use the distance from the equator as an instrument, arguing that this determines the

degree of European influence. In neither case is it clear that the instrument does not have

a direct effect on output. In a paper focusing on Indian states, Iyer [2005] uses the deaths

of rulers lacking male heirs as an instrument for the degree of British colonial control.

She finds that direct British control had a negative impact on modern outcomes.

Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson [2001, 2002] argue that the death rates of settlers

provide a useful instrument for modern institutions. This approach has not been without

critics. McArthur and Sachs [2000] argue that settler mortality is related to the overall

disease environment and has a direct effect on output.

We bring two innovations to this debate. First, we have created a new database of 81

islands which contains a large number of additional data points beyond the usual cross

section of countries used by growth economists. Of the 136 countries in the Penn World

4 See for example Rodney [1974], Ashcraft [1973], Brett [1973], Howard [1978].

3

Page 4: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Tables with GDP data for 1989 only 13 are in our database.5 Islands provide an

interesting experiment in that our sample has more homogenous initial conditions than

the Penn World Tables group. Second we argue that variation in the colonial experience

of islands was relatively random and therefore constitutes a natural experiment.

We propose and implement a new source of exogenous variation in colonial history –

wind patterns. Wind speed and direction were crucial during the age of sail, and have

useful variation within each ocean and within given latitudes. Islands located near routes

in the prevailing winds made useful stopovers and were more easily revisited and

colonized. However, since the beginning of the age of steam began over 100 years ago,

the importance of wind patterns has disappeared. We argue that any effect of wind speed

on current GDP works only through wind's effect on European settlement.

II. The Random Component to Island Settlement and the Importance of Wind

The exploration and settlement of islands in the Pacific, Atlantic and Indian Oceans

entails hundreds of fascinating stories and historical accidents. Most of the Caribbean

islands were known to Europeans prior to most of the Pacific Islands. This was a matter

of distance from Europe and the incredible vastness of the Pacific.6 Meanwhile, certain

islands in the Pacific (in French Polynesia and the Cook Islands in particular) were not

sighted by Europeans until the late 1700s. Patterns of settlement were determined in part

by obvious economic factors like distance to the mainland. However, a fair amount of

colonization was due to unique historical accidents and due to historical trade routes and

wind patterns.

There are almost as many discovery stories as there are islands, particularly in the Pacific.

The infamous case of the Mutiny on the Bounty led to the discovery and colonization of

5 Barbados, Comoros, Dominican Republic, Fiji, Haiti, Jamaica, St. Kitts and Nevis, Mauritius, Philippines, Seychelles, Trinidad and Tobago, Puerto Rico, Vanuatu 6 For example, Columbus sighted the British Virgin Islands in 1493 and he had already sighted portions of the Bahamas, Hispaniola and Cuba a year before that. Of the 39 Atlantic islands in our database, 24 were first sighted by Columbus during one of his three voyages. By 1685 the Dutch were using St. Thomas (Virgin Islands) as a slave trading post and the island contained large sugar plantations by the mid 1700s.

4

Page 5: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Rarotonga, Kadavu, Pitcairn, and Norfolk islands.7 Penrhyn Island was accidentally

colonized in 1788 when Captain Sever smashed his ship (the Penryhn) into the shoreline

on his way to deliver convicts to Botany Bay. Palmerston was colonized by the British

mostly because it was empty when Captain Cook discovered it.8

Though random accident played a large role, we will also argue that wind speed and

direction were important factors in the pattern of island colonization. Unlike powered

boats, sailboats require steady wind to make headway. Islands located in areas where the

wind is weak were less likely to be discovered, revisited, and colonized by Europeans.

Wind direction is also important. The technology available at the time of the voyage of

Columbus only allowed ships to sail about twenty degrees into the wind. This

technology improved slowly over time, but sailing into the wind remained difficult until

steamships became the norm in the twentieth century.9

Consistent downwind routes between useful destinations were therefore well traveled

while much of the globe went virtually untouched. Much of the east to west traffic across

the Pacific after Magellan’s 1521 crossing closely followed his pioneering voyage

because his path was the logical and efficient way to cross. Crossing in the opposite

direction turned out to be much more difficult due to prevailing wind patterns.10 At least

four Spanish expeditions attempted and failed to establish a west to east route across the

Pacific in the wake of Magellan’s voyage. It was not until 1565 that a west to east path

was found across the Pacific and this required sailing much farther north.

7 While fleeing Tahiti, the mutineers discovered Rarotonga in the Cook Islands. Captain Bligh discovered Kadavu in Fiji as he sailed his open boat 3,600 miles from the Friendly Islands to Java (without losing a single one of his 18 crewmembers). The mutineers settled on Pitcairn (with their Tahitian wives) precisely because no one lived there and it was not near any land mass of note. The mutineers' descendants became so numerous that the British government then moved some of them to Norfolk Island thereby creating a second new colony. 8 The first group of settlers took to murdering each other. However the second settlement was more successful; William Marsters moved there in 1862 with his three Polynesian wives and his descendants are still there. 9 Sailing ships were common for transoceanic voyages long after the introduction of steam powered ships because it was difficult for early steamships to carry enough fuel for long voyages. This was particularly true in the Pacific. 10 At the middle latitudes where most of our sample is located the prevailing winds are to the west in both the Pacific and the Atlantic.

5

Page 6: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

The net result of this history is that the pattern of colonization is related to the speed and

direction of the prevailing winds. Islands like Fefan and Pohnpei in the Federated States

of Micronesia have calm winds, were not located near the Spanish trade route and were

basically left alone, even after their discovery in the 1680s. At the other extreme, despite

also being quite isolated, Guam was directly on the Spaniard's Manila Galleon route due

to a favorable combination of wind and currents. Magellan found Guam in 1521 and by

the end of the century it was settled as a watering hole for Spanish ships on the Mexico-

Philippines route.

Once an island was discovered, the path to European settlement was made more difficult

by the crude state of mapping technology. Before the mid eighteenth century the

measurement of longitude at sea was extremely imprecise. Sailors had to rely on dead

reckoning to measure which became less and less precise the further the ship strayed

from known landmarks.11 There are many cases of islands appearing multiple times on

early maps because longitude was estimated differently by separate voyages. Revisiting

an island charted by a previous voyage was problematic. The known map of the world at

the dawn of the eighteenth century was therefore incomplete and inaccurate. Such was

the state of ignorance that many still held out hope of a large undiscovered land mass in

the Pacific.12 The main form of navigation was latitude sailing, which involved sailing

directly west along the latitude line of a known landmark.13 Utilizing this method of

navigation, east-west corridors of consistent winds are crucial.

11 Magellan’s voyage was predicated on the hope that the Spice Islands were on the Spanish side of the line described by the Treaty of Tordesillas. This uncertainty was made possible because the precise longitude of the islands was uncertain at the time. 12 This changed during the latter half of the eighteenth century with the solution of the longitude problem by Harrison. James Cook and others made voyages which filled in the remaining map of the Pacific. 13 Latitude sailing was the most common form of navigation before the solution to the longitude problem. Suppose you were trying to sail from Europe to a particular island in the Pacific without an accurate measure of longitude. You would head north after rounding Cape Horn until the vessel was at the same latitude as the destination. This was easy and effective because the ship’s latitude could be easily and accurately determined by measuring the height of the sun off the horizon at noon. Similarly, the latitude of your destination on charts was well measured even if the longitude was not. Once at the proper latitude, all that was needed to get to the destination was to sail due west until you arrived. In order for this strategy to work, it was important that you arrived at the target latitude to the east of your destination, forcing ships to sail north more rapidly than would be sensible on a direct route. With this style of navigation, east-west corridors with steady winds become more frequently traveled.

6

Page 7: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

This history makes wind speed an ideal instrument for colonization and settlement. Wind

was incredibly important during the age of sail, but its importance came to an abrupt halt

early in the twentieth century. Within our sample, wind speed should not have a direct

effect on an island's current level of GDP, but could have an important effect via the

island's history of colonization. The vast majority of our sample is in the westerly trade

winds. In a first stage regression, the average speed and variability of the westerly winds

are significant determinants of the number of years of colonization.

III. The Nature of Island Colonization

In the Atlantic islands, colonization generally consisted of several hundred or a few

thousand Europeans arriving and in some cases being granted large parcels of land for

farming. Early Spanish colonialism was governed by the encomienda system which

essentially introduced feudal institutions to the colonies. The conquistadors were given

trusteeship over the native peoples. In practice, natives (mostly Arawaks or Caribs) were

often enslaved to work on these plantations.

The English and French were more enterprising than the Spaniards in setting up the

sugar-slave economy and by 1673 there were 57 plantations in English controlled

Barbados. Jamaica was at one point in the 17th century (after the British captured it from

the Spaniards) the world's largest producer of sugar (Black [1881]). By 1700, the French

had established many sugar plantations on virtually all of their islands, including

Martinique, Guadeloupe, Grenada, St. Croix, and Saint-Domingue (present day Haiti).

Colonies in the Pacific Islands tended to involve fewer numbers of Europeans and far less

reliance on imported slaves. Missionaries were often the first colonial residents. For

example, Guam was first sighted by Magellan in 1521. In 1668 the Spanish installed a

group of Jesuit missionaries, a single garrison of soldiers and a colonial governor. The

Spanish mission totaled 50 people relative to the 12,000 Chamorros on Guam. (Douglas

[1994], Rogers [1995]).

7

Page 8: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

III.A. The Immediate Impact of Colonization: Loss of Native Peoples to Disease and Slavery

One of the most striking and terrible facts about colonization by Europeans is the degree

to which native populations on some islands were decimated either by brutal enslavement

or by diseases carried by Europeans and their animals (See Diamond [1997]). This is

most true in the Atlantic where certain islands lost their entire native population in a short

amount of time.14 The Pacific islanders also faced shocking mortality due to smallpox

and other diseases brought by the Europeans.15 However, unlike in the Atlantic only a

few of the islands saw a complete wiping out of the original inhabitants and there are

substantial native populations in the Pacific today.16

Any discussion of the effects of colonialism on economic output has to acknowledge the

devastation of native populations and cultures. Our results show that islands with a

longer colonial history (and more settlement by Europeans) have higher income per

capita and lower infant mortality than other similar islands. Is it sensible to measure the

positive effects on growth from European contact if in fact the original inhabitants are

partially or entirely wiped out because of that contact? Is the possibility of no European

contact a realistic counterfactual? Even without colonialism proper, any contact still may

have wiped out entire populations.

We do not intend to address these questions in this paper. Our results are simply an

examination of the standard of living of people currently alive on these islands relative to 14 For example, the Spaniards began to colonize Puerto Rico in 1505 under the leadership of Ponce de Leon. The native Tainos were enslaved as part of the encomienda system in which land grants to Spaniards included the right to extract tribute or labor from the natives assigned to that land. The original population of Tainos was estimated to have been 60,000. By 1515 this had fallen to 14,400 and by 1530 to 1,500 (Wagenheim [1998]). Prior to the arrival of Europeans, Jamaica was heavily settled and was home to tens of thousands of Arawaks. Not a single one of the natives were alive by the time the British took over from the Spanish in 1655 (Black [1881]). 15 Venereal disease brought by the Spaniards often lead to sterilization. 16 Perhaps the worst depopulation occurred in Guam and the Marianas. The number of pure blooded Chamorros on Guam fell from 12,000 in 1668 to 1,576 in 1742. (Rogers [1995]). The Tahitians saw a drop in their population as a result of the introduction of European disease, but this was followed by a partial recovery. One estimate puts the population of Tahiti at 24,000 around the time of Cook's visit but only 9,000-10,000 by 1800. The native population stabilized and remained around 9,500 at the time of the 1848 census. (Newbury [1980]).

8

Page 9: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

the colonial experience. We do, however, recognize that there are other measures of the

outcomes from colonialism that may generate different conclusions. It is certainly

plausible to argue that the accumulated utility of Pacific Islanders since first encountering

Europeans is lower than in the counterfactual even if the current standard of living on

these islands is significantly higher because of that contact.

IV. The Long Run Impact of Colonialism on Income

The central finding of our paper is that there is a robust positive relationship between

colonial tenure and modern outcomes. The obvious question is why? More intensive

involvement with Europeans or longer colonial rule might have left islands with a more

stable or better structured government. This theory is most associated with Acemoglu

Robinson and Johnson [2001]. Unfortunately, it is not easy to identify which

governmental institutions are the most critical, and measuring institutional quality is

extremely difficult. Furthermore, even if we had a modern index of say, expropriation

risk or corruption for these islands, one might worry that good modern institutions were

caused by high incomes rather than the other way around. We offer two partial (and

admittedly imperfect) solutions to this conundrum.

In order to examine whether the quality of governmental institutions matters we look at

variation in both who did the colonizing and when colonialism occurred. The work of La

Porta, Lopez de Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny [1997, 1998] suggests that the identity of

the colonizing country has important effects on modern income through the legal system.

The historical record also suggests that different countries varied in the manner in which

they ruled their holdings. The encomienda system of the Spanish may have had different

effects than French or British rule.

We also think that the timing of colonialism (holding colonizer constant) may be related

to institutional quality, with the later period representing both better governmental

institutions and better intentions on the part of colonizers. There was a distinct change in

the attitude of the explorers toward the world between the beginning of the period of

9

Page 10: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

exploration and the final filling in of the map of the world. A simple illustration of this

point can be seen in the differences between the voyages of Ferdinand Magellan and

James Cook.

When Magellan set sail on his famous circumnavigation in 1519 his goal was to find a

Spanish route to the Spice Islands. The Treaty of Tordesillas in 1494 split the world

between Spain and Portugal at 46°W longitude. The Spanish felt that a westward route

would allow them to lay claims on the Spice Islands. The agreement between Spain and

Portugal had the blessing of the Pope and along with their rights to these unfound lands

came a responsibility to spread Christianity. Magellan’s voyage was therefore explicitly

commercial with religious overtones.

This stands in stark contrast to the voyages of James Cook between 1768 and 1779.

Cook’s missions had explicit scientific aims. On all three voyages, Cook brought artists

and scientists to record and study all that he found. Unlike Magellan, who was driven to

bring Christianity to the natives, Cook had a much more romantic view of the Pacific

islanders.

“We debauch their morals already too prone to vice and we introduce among them wants and perhaps diseases which they never before knew and which serves only to disturb that happy tranquility they and their forefathers have enjoyed … If anyone denies the truth of this assertion let him tell me what the natives of the whole extent of America have gained by the commerce they have had with Europeans.”17

There is evidence that the more enlightened attitude of the later explorers is correlated

with a more enlightened approach to administering colonies. Some of the Pacific Islands

were not colonized until the mid-19th Century (for example Tahiti and the Marquesas).

No enslavement of the natives took place there and representative local governments

were set up within 70 years of colonization.

More generally, many of the institutional features considered to be important for modern

outcomes were not well developed in European countries in the earlier period and

17 Hough [1994].

10

Page 11: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

therefore not available for transfer. The primacy of parliaments, the importance of the

rule of law, and the protection of property rights advanced significantly between the

sixteenth and eighteenth centuries. To the extent that we find that later colonial years (for

example those after 1700) are more beneficial than earlier colonial years (e.g. those

before 1700), we take this as another indicator that institutional quality partly explains the

colonialism-income connection.

V. Data Description

The data on island colonization, GDP, and infant mortality are assembled from a large

number of sources. Our starting point was a database of islands maintained by the UN.18

This dataset provided us with a comprehensive list of individual islands along with

nation, population and area. We sorted the islands by size and investigated islands that

satisfied two criteria. First, we only included islands that require open ocean sailing to

reach them from Europe. Second, we limited the sample to relatively small landmasses,

specifically those less than 150,000 square kilometers.

These selection criteria are intended to generate a sample of islands that fit our story of

random variation in colonial experience. We are particularly interested in the

randomness associated with the age of exploration. Islands that were unavoidably found

as Europeans made their way down the coast of Africa clearly have a less random history

than the islands of the Pacific.19 The size criterion is intended to make the sample as

homogeneous as possible. Large landmasses like Australia are fundamentally different

than the islands in our sample. Within the group of islands fitting these criteria we

researched islands in order of population using any islands for which data were available.

Islands that are part of a group are only included as independent data points if there is

some independent information for the individual island. For example, the majority of the

islands in the Maldives have an identical colonial history and we only have one GDP data 18 http://islands.unep.ch/ 19 The islands that make up Indonesia and Papua New Guinea are excluded for this reason: they were found and settled quite early and there was nothing random about this process. Our results are however robust to including these two countries as an additional two data points.

11

Page 12: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

point for the entire group. In this case, there is only one island in the Maldives included

in our dataset. On the other hand, the islands of the Netherlands Antilles have

heterogeneity of both colonial history and GDP, so the individual islands in the group are

included separately. We do, however, recognize that these may not be completely

independent data points so all the econometric analysis is clustered at the islands group

level.

Where available, we obtained GDP per capita for the year 2000 from the United Nations.

Per capita GDP figures were available for 39 island nations covering 61 of the islands in

our dataset. Twenty islands are possessions of other countries, for example Guam is a

US possession. In those cases we obtained island level income per capita and infant

mortality numbers for the island from the statistical agency of the relevant country.20 In

the case of islands that are currently part of an island group (such as the Cook Islands),

we disaggregated country level data into the component islands where possible. For

example Yap and Pohnpei are both states in the Federated States of Micronesia, but the

two islands have different histories, wind patterns, and economic output and are located

more than 1,000 miles apart. In some of these cases we were able to obtain separate GDP

breakdowns from a series of reports on Pacific island groups produced by the Asian

Development Bank.21

The colonial and settlement histories for each island come from a myriad of sources. For

the Pacific islands we relied heavily in the Pacific Islands Yearbook [Douglas, 1994].

For Atlantic and Indian Ocean islands, we used Encyclopedia Britannica, Wikipedia, and

supplemented these sources with the individual island histories listed below in the

references section22. We collected the entire history of each island, including the first

20 In these cases we will be using income per capita as a proxy for GDP per capita. We recognize that this is an imperfect measure. We report robustness checks where we limit ourselves to the GDP data. 21 We used the breakdowns by island in the following way: The island group level data was used to establish relative income levels. For example, the disaggregated data tells us that Yap in the FSM has twice the per capita income of Moen in the same group. Using the relative income and population data we calculated the per capita income for each island so that the relative income levels were correct and that the population weighted group average was equal to the GDP per capita figure for the group from the UN. 22 Not all of the references are explicitly cited in the text since many of these references were used to establish colonial histories for individual islands.

12

Page 13: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

European sightings, the first settlements, the extent of such settlements, and the political

history of the island's colonization if any.

We define colonialism as those years during which an island is claimed politically by one

of the European countries, the US, or Japan. This requires that the colonizing country has

not only landed on the island and claimed it, but that the central government of the

European power has ratified a law stating that the island is one of its possessions.23 We

take any of the words territory, possession, protectorate or colony to signify an islands

status as a colony. Disputes of ownership were relatively short lived and in the case of a

dispute we always code as the colonizing the country that power which maintained

physical (eg military and administrative) control of the majority of the islands' people.

Wind speeds measured in average knots are from satellite data taken from CERSTAT.24

The satellites measure wind speeds over water for the entire globe, reported on a one

degree longitude latitude grid. The data we utilize are reported monthly and consist of

the average wind vector in knots in the north-south direction and the average wind vector

in the east-west direction. These two vectors completely describe the average wind speed

and direction in a given month. Given monthly average observations on both vectors, we

are able to look at the variability of the wind speed as well as the average intensity. Thus

the most parsimonious set of instruments is the average of the raw monthly data and its

standard deviation. In other words, we have the average annual wind speed to the north

and its monthly variability and the average annual wind speed to the east and its monthly

variability.

Alternatively the raw data can be transformed into a set of compass directions and wind

speeds. In a regression this requires using a set of 4, 8 or 16 compass point dummies and

23 We also coded New Zealand's ownership of Niue from 1904 to 1974 as colonial years. We did the same for Australia's ownership of Nauru during 1914-1968. We did this following a referee's suggestion, and it makes sense given that New Zealand and Australia were highly developed "neo-Europes" by the twentieth century. 24 The CERSAT (Centre ERS d'Archivage et de Traitement - French ERS Processing and Archiving Facility) is part of IFREMER (French Research Institute for Exploitation of the Sea. It was created in 1991 as a node of the ESA (European Space Agency) ground segment for the ERS-1 and ERS-2 Earth observation satellites. http://www.ifremer.fr/cersat/

13

Page 14: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

possibly interacting these dummies with the wind speed. We have also tried specifying

our instrument in this form and we obtain similar results.

Given the direction of travel from Europe, the east-west component of the wind should be

particularly important for sailing voyages and our first stage regressions confirm this.

But we report results using a variety of combinations of the instruments.

Table I contains summary statistics for the data. Forty of the eighty one islands are

located in the Pacific. Thirty five are in the Atlantic and the remaining islands are in the

Indian Ocean. The median population on our islands is about 14,000 people. This ranges

from as few as 102 people on Palmerston Island (in the Cook Islands) to more than 11

million people in Cuba. Our results are robust to dropping islands with fewer than

10,000 people. The median land area for the islands is 130 square kilometers. The mean

2000 GDP per capita on the islands in the sample is $8,279 with a high of $53,735 for

Bermuda.

The average number of centuries of colonization (using our political definition) is 2.32.

But there are many islands with relatively limited colonial experience. Twenty two

countries in the sample were a colony for one hundred years or less and eleven for less

than fifteen years. In general the Atlantic islands were the first to be colonized by

Europeans and some islands including Bonaire, Curacao, and Barbados have 400 years of

colonial history.

One possible criticism of our approach is that islands tend to be small and have different

natural resources than continental nations and are therefore not "real countries" of interest

to macroeconomists. Since many successful islands focus on tourism, one could also

make the case that this also makes them different from "real" countries. We have several

responses to this. First, the islands in the sample have significant variation in levels of

income and industry mix. Appendix Table V shows that agriculture is a large fraction of

the economy for islands like Dominica and some of the Federated States of Micronesia

like Pohnpei. Bermuda and the Virgin Islands tend to focus on services, though this can

14

Page 15: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

mean banking and insurance in addition to tourism. More importantly, even if all the

islands in the South Pacific or the Atlantic had beautiful beaches, we still would need to

ask why certain islands have a subsistence level of income while others have a standard

of living that rivals Sweden and the US. Grand Cayman is a tourist paradise while

Hispaniola (Haiti plus the Dominican Republic) is not, despite the fact that both islands

have tropical breezes and the beauty of the Caribbean Sea.25

VI. Results

Figure 1 shows a scatter plot of log GDP per capita versus number of centuries as a

colony. The circles are for islands in the Atlantic. The triangles are for islands in the

Pacific and the squares are for islands in the Indian Ocean. The regression line shows a

positive relationship between length of colonial period and modern GDP. While there is

a large amount of variation around the regression line (we certainly don't think colonial

history explains everything), the t-statistic for the slope is 6.1. The coefficient is 0.42

meaning that every additional 100 years of colonial history is associated with a 42

percent increase in GDP. Remarkably the upward slope holds within each of the oceans.

The relationship is not driven simply by the fact that Atlantic islands were discovered by

Europeans earliest and are the richest.

Table II shows nine different cross sectional regressions with our basic result. For

columns (1) through (7) log GDP per capita is the dependent variable. Column (1) shows

the basic correlation illustrated in Figure (1). A longer period under colonial rule is

associated with higher per capita GDP. Each additional hundred years is associated with

GDP per capita that is 42 percent higher.

Column (2) adds additional controls. We include dummies for each ocean and we control

for island land area and absolute value of latitude (distance from the Equator). As in

Gallup, Sachs and Mellinger [1999] and Sachs [2003], the absolute value of latitude is

25We are not claiming that the length and nature of the colonial period explains the Grand Cayman Hispaniola income gap specifically but rather that even within Caribbean islands, there is massive and interesting variation in economic performance.

15

Page 16: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

strongly related to current levels of income. Every 10 degree increase in latitude (i.e.

moving roughly 700 miles away from the equator) is associated with a 53 percent

increase in GDP. Those authors find that latitude works through the efficiency of

agriculture and disease prevalence. Acemoglu et al [2001] provide evidence that

latitude's effects work through variation in the nature of European settlements and

institutions that were established. Island area is also significant with larger islands doing

more poorly than smaller islands. Interestingly, the Pacific and Atlantic Ocean dummies

are not significantly different from each other. Including the geographic controls does

not substantially alter the results for colonial tenure.

One important possibility is that Europeans simply chose to settle the best islands first

and hence the more successful islands have a longer colonial history. In column (3) we

instrument for the number of years as a colony using data on prevailing wind patterns.

As discussed in a previous section, wind patterns make an appealing instrument because

they were incredibly important during 1500-1890 (and determined discovery and

settlement), but have little direct effect on GDP today.

Column (3) of Table I shows the second stage of the two stage least squares regression.

The results are similar to the OLS results and the coefficient on years of colonization

remains very significantly away from zero with a t-statistic of 2.8. Each additional

hundred years of colonization is associated with 71 percent larger GDP per capita.

Utilizing a Hausman test, one cannot reject the null hypothesis that the OLS and IV

results are the same.

The first stage for this regression is contained in Appendix Table I column (1) which uses

our preferred set of instruments. We use the east west vector of wind and its standard

deviation. Both instruments are significant predictors of centuries of colonialism. As

expected stronger westerly winds are associated with more years as a colony. A larger

standard deviation is also associated with more years as a colony.

16

Page 17: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix Table II shows the possible first stages from various combinations of our raw

wind data. In all cases the average east-west component is a significant predictor of years

as a colony. The variability of the east-west vector adds a modest amount of explanatory

power. The north-south components do not seem to matter very much. All combinations

of instruments are significant at the 5% level. However, the instrument sets using only

east-west information are significant at the 1% level. For this reason all our standard

results use the east-west wind speed and standard deviations as instruments. Appendix

Table III shows the second stage results for each of the instrument sets. The results are

insensitive to the particular combination used. First stages and reduced forms for all of

the IV regressions in Table II are included in Appendix Table I.

One objection to our IV strategy is that the instrument is well suited to describing the

beginning of colonial rule, but is not a good instrument for the end of colonial rule. In

columns (4) and (5) of Table II we switch our key right hand side variable to the first year

that an island fell under colonial rule.26 For this specification, we do not include any

regressors describing the end date of colonial rule. Our IV strategy assumes that the

instruments affect the beginning of colonial rule through the ability to reach each island

during the age of sail. The end dates of colonial rule all fall well after the beginning of

the age of steam, so our instrument should not have a direct effect on colonial end date.

The results are extremely similar to the length of colonial rule results. Again a Hausman

test does not reject the hypothesis that the IV and OLS coefficients are identical.

We also run regressions where we control explicitly for the end date of colonialism in

columns (6) and (7) in Table II. We also add a dummy for islands which currently have a

colonial relationship with a developed country (e.g. Puerto Rico, Guam, or the

Netherlands Antilles). It is possible that current transfers from the colonizing country to

these islands are important.27 Interpretation of these additional controls is difficult since

the end point of colonial rule is endogenous. We include these regressions largely to 26 The first and last year of colonization are divided by 100 to make the coefficients compatible with the centuries of colonial rule coefficients. 27 Our preferred specification excludes these controls for the end of colonialism since the end or continuation of colonialism is endogenous AND a continuing colonial relationship may be an important part of the overall causal effect of being colonized early.

17

Page 18: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

show that these channels appear to only "explain" a modest portion of our results. Only

the initial date of colonialism is instrumented in column (7).

The results in columns (6) and (7) indicate that it is the start date of colonialism that is

driving our results, not the end date. The coefficients on the beginning year of

colonialism are similar in magnitude (though as expected, opposite in sign) to the

coefficients in the previous regressions. The coefficient on the last year of colonialism is

not statistically significant. Whether the island was still a colony in 2000, however, is

significant and positive. Being a colony in 2000 is associated with 80-95% higher

income. The inclusion of this dummy has no significant impact on the coefficient on the

first or last year of colonialism, suggesting that our base result is not being driven by

current transfers, but that transfers may be incredibly beneficial for a modern island

colony's income.28

As an additional outcome measure we use infant mortality as the dependent variable in

Columns (8) and (9). These results mirror the results for GDP per capita. The number of

centuries that an island was a colony is a negative and significant predictor of infant

mortality in all the specifications. This result is also robust to our IV strategy.

The regressions in Table III examine whether our results are being driven by sample and

data selection. Column (1) repeats our base result. Column (2) excludes islands for

which there is no direct GDP data available from the UN. These excluded islands are

generally territories of developed countries such Guam and the British Virgin Islands.

This column does allow for adjustments to GDP within island groups as described in the

data section. Column (3) does not include these adjustments. The results for these three

columns are similar, suggesting that our particular sample choices are not driving the

results.

28 Including a late colonialism dummy alone in any of the earlier columns does not significantly affect the central results.

18

Page 19: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Columns (4) through (7) show the results of running our base regression on sub samples

of islands limited to the Atlantic and Pacific Oceans. Columns (4) and (5) are estimated

with OLS. Columns (6) and (7) instrument the number of centuries of colonialism with

wind data as described above. The results are fairly similar within each ocean. In the

Pacific, where we have the most variation in years of colonization, the coefficient on the

number of years of colonialism is statistically significant.29

VI.A. Timing and Identity of Colonizing Powers

In Table IV we split out the effects of centuries of colonialism by the identity of the

colonizer. The "omitted" category is years spent not as a colony. We wish to examine

whether the effects differ across the colonizers. Of course, identification in these

regressions is less clear than in the regressions identifying the number of years as a

colony; we are not claiming that these regressions are necessarily causal. However,

given the previous literature on differences in colonizers we feel that the correlations are

interesting. In addition, our earlier results suggest a large degree of randomness in the

colonial experiences of islands. If true, the OLS results are informative.

For the OLS results the coefficients on centuries of British, French, and Dutch rule are all

in the .5 to .6 range and are statistically indistinguishable. However, centuries of Spanish

rule have a statistically significantly lower coefficient (at .20) and the Portuguese

coefficient is significantly negative. We find this to be quite consistent with the

hypothesis that colonialism's effects on income work through institutional quality. The

Spanish and Portuguese legacy may still affect GDP per capita today (Landes [1994]).

The positive coefficient on centuries of US rule is very large. This is not surprising given

the direct benefits to Guam, Puerto Rico, the Northern Mariana, the US Virgin Islands

and Hawaii of current US ownership and of the ability of these islanders to migrate to the

mainland US. The US federal government has invested heavily in these places in

infrastructure, schools, and health care systems. 29 In the first stage regressions (not reported), the p values for the joint significance of the instruments are .04 in the Pacific regression and .01 in the Atlantic.

19

Page 20: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

In column (2) we add dummies for having ever been colonized by each of the eight

colonial powers. In other words, we allow for the possibility that the sets islands ruled by

each power may be fundamentally different or that there may be different level effects

transmitted by each colonizer irrespective of length of colonial period. The results in

column (2) are qualitatively similar to those in column (1) which does not control for the

set of colonial power dummies. For instance, the slope on centuries US is still quite large

though no longer statistically significant. This makes sense given that there is only

modest variation in years of US rule once we condition on having ever been a US colony.

The coefficients on years of British, French and Spanish rule remain about the same,

though the coefficient on Spanish rule loses statistical significance.

Column (3) and (4) repeat this exercise using IV. The instruments for each country are

the east-west speed and standard deviations interacted with a set of country dummies.

This leaves us with two instruments for each country measurement. Since our IV

strategy is only valid for determining the number of years as a colony, the results are

somewhat difficult to interpret. Intuitively, our instruments are allowing wind speed to

have different effects for each of the colonizers in the first stage. Given the limited

sample size this leads to relatively weak first stage regressions. The results are not

significantly away from OLS, but in many cases this is due to much larger standard

errors. In column (3) the relative weakness of years of Portuguese rule and the relative

strength of years of Dutch rule remains significant. This significance disappears in

column (4) once we add to the second stage the dummies for "ever colonized" by each of

the eight colonial powers.

In column (3) we ask whether we can detect any difference in incomes among islands

that use the British versus French legal system and the answer is no. Incomes in the two

types of islands look quite similar.

Table V examines the timing of the colonial experience. Again, this set of regressions is

not as well identified as our central result. We feel that the early colonial experience was

20

Page 21: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

significantly random and therefore the pre-1700 and post-1700 results are potentially

causal. On the other hand, it is clear that the end of colonialism is potentially

endogenous. For this reason, the 20th century results should be viewed with caution.

The differences in the effects of pre and post enlightenment colonialism are evident in

our data. Column (1) splits the number of years of colonialism into years before 1700 and

years after 1700.30 The results suggest that only the years after 1700 are positively

associated with modern outcomes. An additional 100 years of post-1700 colonialism is

associated with much higher per capita income (though this includes the very rich places

that are still colonies). The coefficient is highly significant and significantly different

than the coefficient on pre-1700 colonial years. This suggests that the colonial era of

Cook was indeed different from that of Columbus and Magellan. Column (2) instruments

the pre and post 1700 colonialism years with the east-west and north-south wind vectors

and their standard deviations. The results are very similar with pre and post 1700 years

being significantly different.31

Column (3) breaks the years into three eras, pre-enlightenment, post-enlightenment, and

post 1900. Once again, the pre and post enlightenment years are significantly different

from each other. The 20th century years are significantly better than either earlier era. In

Column (4) we add a dummy for whether an island was a colony in 2000 in order to

isolate the effect of transfers from other mechanisms. With this additional control, years

of 20th century colonialism become statistically worse than years between 1700 and 1900.

This shows that the positive 20th century result of column (3) is entirely driven by islands

which remained colonies at the end of the century. Being a colony at the end of the 20th

century remains very positively associated with income. Conditional on making it to the

end of the century as a colony, years as a colony in the 20th century are negatively

associated with income.

30The results are robust to moving the cutoff to 1750. 31 In the first stage regressions (not reported) the p-values on the F statistics for the joint significance of the instruments are .03 and .025.

21

Page 22: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

VI.B. A Broader Sample of Countries Our results suggest that the length of colonial experience is positively correlated with per

capita GDP in a sample of islands. The IV results further suggest that these results are

not being driven by the selective colonization of islands that have features conducive to

good modern outcomes. Given the similarity of the IV and OLS results, it may be

instructive to check the basic results against a larger more traditional sample of countries.

Table VI shows the results from regressing per capita GDP against the number of years a

country was a colony for a sample of non-island developing countries. This sample is

consistent with the countries included in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson.

The basic results match quite nicely with our island results. Each additional century of

colonial tenure is associated with a 40 percent increase in GDP. This is not statistically

significantly different from the 42 percent coefficient found in the island sample.

Including latitude as a control does not significantly change this coefficient. One

advantage of using this sample is that standard measures of modern institutional quality

can be included. Column (3) of Table VI includes expropriation risk as an additional

regressor. Expropriation risk is significant and negative, as expected. This reduces the

point estimate on colonial tenure, but it remains large and significant. In column (4) we

include the Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson measure of log settler mortality with

similar results.

While the results from this sample are not as well identified as from the islands sample,

they are still instructive. The basic correlation appears to extend beyond our island

sample. The results are robust to the inclusion of standard modern institutional measures

and geographic controls.

VII. Concluding Remarks

We have argued for an "islands as experiments" approach where random variation in the

colonial experiences of islands can be used to think about the long run effects of colonial

history on economic performance. The most interesting fact in our sample of island

22

Page 23: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

colonies is a robust positive relationship between the years of European colonialism and

current levels of income. While some of this relationship could be driven by smart

selection of islands by colonizers, we suspect that part of the relationship is causal.

When we instrument for colonization and settlement using wind patterns, we obtain

coefficients on years of colonization that are identical to our OLS results.

While the basic results suggest that longer European colonial exposure is good for the

modern inhabitants of the islands in our sample, we also bring additional facts to bear to

think about why. First, quality differences in the colonial experience seem to matter.

These findings are consistent with the Acemoglu et al. result that the quality of the

colonial experience is important for modern outcomes. There is a discernable pecking

order amongst the colonizers. Years under US and Dutch colonial rule are significantly

better than years under the Spanish and Portuguese.

Second, later years of colonialism are associated with a much larger increase in modern

GDP than years before 1700. It is not difficult to believe that colonialism in the post-

enlightenment era led to more efficient and beneficial institution transfer than colonialism

under the encomienda system and its contemporaries. This is not to say that we find the

early colonial years to be detrimental to modern GDP – we do not.

While any attempt to get at root causes of the paper's central fact are partly speculative,

we hope that the basic facts and data generated by this examination of islands will further

the understanding of long run growth.

23

Page 24: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review 91(5): 1369-401. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Development in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 1231-1294. Aldrich, Robert, France and the South Pacific Since 1940, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, 1993. Ashcraft, Norman, Colonialism and Underdevelopment: Processes of Political Economic Change in British Honduras, Teachers College Press, New York, 1973. Aten, Bettina, Alan Heston and Robert Summers. 2002. Penn World Tables Version 6.1. Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer, 2005. “History Institutions and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,” American Economic Review 95(4), 1190-1213. Beckles, Hilary, A History of Barbados: From Amerindian Settlement to Nation-State, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1990. Black, Clinton V., The Story of Jamaica from Prehistory to the Present, Collins Clear-Type Press, London, 1965. Brett, E. A., Colonialism and Underdevelopment in East Africa: The Politics of Economic Change 1919-1939, NOK Publishers, Ltd., New York, 1973. Campbell, Gwyn, An Economic History of Imperial Madagascar, 1750-1895: The Rise and Fall of an Island Empire, Cambridge University Press, New York, NY, 2005. Campbell, I. C., A History of the Pacific Islands, University of California Press, Berkeley, 1989. Carano, Paul and Pedro C. Sanchez, A Complete History of Guam, Charles E. Tuttle Company, Rutland, VT, 1964. Carrión, Arturo Morales, Puerto Rico: A Political and Cultural History, W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., New York, NY, 1983. Dietz, James L., Economic History of Puerto Rico: Institutional Change and Capitalist Development, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1986.

24

Page 25: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Diamond, Jared M., Guns, Germs, And Steel : The Fates Of Human Societies, New York : Norton, c2005. Dominican Republic and Haiti: Country Studies, Richard A. Haggerty (ed.), Federal Research Division, Library of Congress, Washington D.C., 1991. Douglas, Norman and Ngaire Douglas (eds.), Pacific Islands Yearbook, 17th ed, Fiji Times Ltd., Fiji, 1994. Dupay, Alex, Haiti in the World Economy: Class, Race, and Underdevelopment Since 1700, Westview Press, Inc., Boulder, Co, 1989. Engerman, Stanley L, Kenneth L. Sokoloff, "Institutional and Non-Institutional Explanations of Economic Differences," National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Paper Number 11057, 2003. Engerman, Stanley L, Kenneth L. Sokoloff, "Colonialism, Inequality, and Long-Run Paths of Development," National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Paper Number 11057, 2005. Fieldhouse, D.K., The West and the Third World: Trade, Colonialism, Dependence and Development, Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, UK, 1999. Gallup, John Luke; Sachs, Jeffrey D; Mellinger, Andrew D, "Geography and Economic Development." International Regional Science Review, vol. 22, no. 2, August 1999, pp. 179-232. Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and, Andrei Shleifer, "Do Institutions Cause Growth?," National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10568, June 2004. Graham, Norman A. and Keith L. Edwards, The Caribbean Basin to the Year 2000: Demographic, Economic, and Resource-Use Trends in Seventeen Countries, Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, 1984. Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1999, 83-116. Hezel, Francis X., Strangers in Their Own Land: A Century of Colonial Rule in the Caroline and Marshall Islands, University of Hawai’i Press, Honolulu, 1995. Hope, Kempe Ronald, Economic Development in the Caribbean, Praeger Publishers, New York, NY, 1986.

25

Page 26: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Hough, Richard, Captain James Cook, W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., New York, 1994 Howard, Rhoda, Colonialism and Underdevelopment in Ghana, Africana Publishing Company, New York, 1978. Howe, K R, Where the Waves Fall: A New South Sea Islands History from First Settlement to Colonial Rule, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, 1984. Huxley, Anthony (ed.), Standard Encyclopedia of the World’s Oceans and Islands, G.P. Putnam’s Sons, New York, NY, 1962. Indian Ocean: Five Island Countries, Helen Chapin Metz (ed.), Federal Research Division, Library of Congress, Washington D.C., 1995. Islands of the Commonwealth Caribbean: A Regional Study, Sandra W. Meditz and Dennis M. Hanratty (eds.), Federal Research Division, Library of Congress, Washington D.C., 1989. Iyer, Lakshmi. "The Long-Term Impact of Colonial Rule: Evidence from India." Harvard Business School Working Paper, No. 05-041, 2005. Knight, Franklin W., The Caribbean: The Genesis of a Fragmented Nationalism, Oxford University Press, New York, 1978. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1997. “Legal Determinants of External Finance,” Journal of Finance 52(3), 1131-1150. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1998. “Law and Finance,” Journal of Political Economy 106(6), 1113-1155. Landes, David S., The Wealth and Poverty of Nations, W.W. Norton & Company, New York, 1998. Lyons, Martyn, The Totem and the Tricolour: A Short History of New Caledonia Since 1774, New South Wales University Press, Kensington NSW Australia, 1986. McArthur, John W. and Jeffrey D. Sachs, “Institutions and Geography: Comment on Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2000),” NBER Working Paper No. 8114, 2000. Malcolm, George A., The Commonwealth of the Philippines, D. Appleton-Century Company, Inc., New York, 1936. Maude, H. E., Of Islands and Men: Studies in Pacific History, Oxford University Press, Melbourne, 1969.

26

Page 27: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Mauro, Paolo. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1995, 100:3, 681-712. Moreira, M. 2002. Tests with Correct Size in the Simultaneous Equations Model. PhD Thesis, UC Berkeley. Newbury, Colin, Tahiti Nui: Change and Survival in French Polynesia 1767-1945, The University Press of Hawaii, Honolulu, 1980. Pacific Islands, Naval Intelligence Division, Geographical Handbook Series: General Study, Volume I, 1945. Pacific Islands, Naval Intelligence Division, Geographical Handbook Series: Eastern Pacific, Volume II, 1943. Pacific Islands, Naval Intelligence Division, Geographical Handbook Series: Western Pacific (Tonga to Solomon Is.), Volume III, 1944. Pacific Islands, Naval Intelligence Division, Geographical Handbook Series: Western Pacific (New Guinea and Islands Northward), Volume IV, 1945. Parsons, James J., San Andrés and Providencia: English-Speaking Islands in the Western Caribbean, University of California Publications in Geography (Vol. 12), University of California Press, Berkeley, 1956. Philippines: A Country Study, Frederica M. Bunge (ed.), Federal Research Division, Library of Congress, Washington D.C., 1984. Pons, Frank Moya, The Dominican Republic: A National History, Hispaniola Books, New Rochelle, NY, 1995. Rodney, Walter, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, Howard University Press, Washington, D. C., 1974. Rogers, Robert F., Destiny’s Landfall: A History of Guam, University of Hawai’i Press, Honolulu, 1995. Sachs, Jeffrey D., "Institutions Don't Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income," National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Papers: 9490, 2003. Wagenheim, Olga Jiménez de, Puerto Rico: An Interpretive History from Pre-Columbian Times to 1900, Markus Wiener Publishers, Princeton, NJ, 1998.

27

Page 28: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

28

Table I Summary Statistics

These are summary statistics for the variables in the islands database. See the text for details on variable sources and construction.

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Island's GDP per Capita 2000 81 8,279 9,327 264 53,735 Log (GDP Capita) 81 8.45 1.14 5.58 10.89 Infant Mortality 2002 81 18.53 15.17 4.00 79.00 Number of Centuries as a Colony 81 2.32 1.42 0.61 5.11 First Year a Colony / 100 81 17.43 1.48 14.92 19.16 Last Year a Colony / 100 81 19.85 0.22 19.01 20.05 Remained a Colony in 2000 81 0.46 0.50 0.00 1.00 Easterly Vector of Prevailing Wind 81 -4.20 2.01 -6.88 4.42 Northerly Vector of Prevailing Wind 81 0.17 1.27 -1.55 4.20 Std Dev. Easterly Vector of Wind 81 1.36 0.56 0.58 2.99 Std Dev. Northern Vector of Wind 81 1.34 0.65 0.63 4.02 Number of Centuries British 81 0.98 1.23 0.00 3.95 Number of Centuries French 81 0.44 0.89 0.00 3.70 Number of Centuries Spanish 81 0.38 0.94 0.00 4.05 Ever British 81 0.64 0.48 0.00 1.00 Ever French 81 0.31 0.46 0.00 1.00 Ever Spanish 81 0.25 0.43 0.00 1.00 Absolute Value of Latitude 81 15.73 7.68 0.50 51.92 Island Area (1000s sq km) 81 0.01 0.02 0.00 0.11 Island Population 70 302,720 1,394,832 102 11,000,000 Island is in Pacific 81 0.49 0.50 0.00 1.00 Island is in Atlantic 81 0.43 0.50 0.00 1.00 Island is in Indian 81 0.07 0.26 0.00 1.00

Page 29: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

29

Table II Outcomes Regressed on Years of Colonization

We regress Log GDP per capita and infant mortality on the number of years the island spent as a colony of a European power. Columns (1), (2), (4), (6) and (8) are OLS. Columns (3), (5) , (7) and (9) are two stage least squares where we instrument for centuries of colonial rule or the first year as a colony using the 12 month average and standard deviation of the east-west wind speed for each island. In the IV columns, we do not instrument for final year a colony or "remained a colony" in 2000. Similar IV results obtain when we use LIML rather than two stage least squares.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Log GDP

Capita Log GDP

Capita Log GDP

Capita - IV

Log GDP Capita

Log GDP Capita-

IV

Log GDP Capita

Log GDP Capita-

IV

Infant Mortality Per 1000

Infant Mortality Per 1000-

IV Number of Centuries a Colony 0.42 0.491 0.712 -3.885 -13.47 (0.076)** (0.110)** (0.253)** (1.472)* (5.434)* First Year a Colony -0.456 -0.883 -0.342 -0.626 (0.112)** (0.354)* (0.108)** (0.304)* Final Year A Colony 0.409 0.527 (0.755) (0.874) Remained A Colony in 2000 0.954 0.81 (0.311)** (0.373)* Abs(Latitude) 0.053 0.054 0.06 0.068 0.038 0.046 -0.797 -0.841 (0.012)** (0.011)** (0.012)** (0.016)** (0.012)** (0.015)** (0.207)** (0.225)** Area in millions of sq km -20.374 -21.738 -26.34 -34.764 -15.071 -20.769 266.288 325.479 (3.894)** (3.970)** (5.142)** (8.252)** (5.383)** (7.148)** (147.186)+ (138.716)* Island is in Pacific 0.752 1.018 0.782 1.364 0.664 1.043 -8.476 -20.036 (0.464) (0.559)+ (0.510) (0.762)+ (0.491) (0.641) (9.329) (14.379) Island is in Atlantic 0.425 0.188 0.471 0.019 0.319 0.043 -5.161 5.14 (0.395) (0.477) (0.396) (0.568) (0.383) (0.481) (8.540) (8.501) Constant 7.472 6.033 5.484 15.026 22.302 4.879 7.406 44.914 68.754 (0.205)** (0.552)** (0.834)** (1.872)** (5.894)** (15.218) (17.308) (11.085)** (21.610)** Observations 81 81 81 81 81 81 81 81 81 R-squared 0.273 0.527 0.498 0.488 0.396 0.655 0.616 0.371 0.063

Robust standard errors in parentheses. We cluster at the island group level since several of the islands (e.g. the Cook Islands and the Federated States of Micronesia) are used as separate observations from a cluster of politically related yet geographically distinct islands. + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 30: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Table III Comparison of different Samples

Column (1) is the base sample used in the rest of the paper. Column (2) uses only GDP figures obtained from the UN, but includes disaggregation of islands that are part of a group. Column (3) uses only the raw UN GDP data. Columns (4) and (5) limit the sample to the Pacific and Atlantic Oceans. Columns (6) and (7) are two stage least squares for each ocean where we instrument for centuries of colonial rule using the 12 month average and standard deviation of the east-west wind vector for each island.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita Log GDP

per Capita

Sample Base UN data - disaggregated

groups

UN data Pacific Atlantic Pacific - IV Atlantic-IV

Number of centuries a colony 0.491 0.636 0.503 0.599 0.268 0.652 0.754 (0.110)** (0.174)** (0.148)** (0.129)** (0.191) (0.294)* (0.281)* Abs(Latitude) 0.053 0.062 0.067 0.069 0.042 0.068 0.054 (0.012)** (0.016)** (0.020)** (0.021)** (0.017)* (0.019)** (0.014)** Area in millions of sq km -20.374 -20.966 -21.838 -19.471 -21.549 -20.208 -22.178 (3.894)** (3.992)** (3.845)** (3.506)** (6.715)** (4.763)** (6.286)** Island is in Pacific 0.752 0.957 1.086 (0.464) (0.702) (0.575)+ Island is in Atlantic 0.425 0.216 0.177 (0.395) (0.559) (0.527) Constant 6.033 5.526 5.535 6.437 7.471 6.389 5.532 (0.552)** (0.803)** (0.643)** (0.272)** (0.709)** (0.416)** (1.118)** Observations 81 62 62 40 35 40 35 R-squared 0.527 0.563 0.509 0.492 0.398 0.49 0.211

Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the island group level. + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

30

Page 31: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Table IV The Effect of Colonialism by Colonizing Countries

Columns (1), (2), and (5) are OLS. Years under British, French, and German legal systems are constructed by categorizing the colonizers legal system using the definitions in LaPorta et al (1997). Columns (3), (4) and (6) are instrumental variables regressions in which the instruments are the interactions between dummies for having ever been colonized by the US, Dutch, British, French, Spanish, Portuguese, Germans, or Japanese interacted with easterly wind speed and standard deviation of easterly wind. We interact the 8 country dummies with each of the two wind variables. Column (3) includes the eight country dummies in the OLS regression. Column (4) includes the eight dummies in the first and second stages of the IV regression.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Log GDP per

Capita Log GDP per

Capita Log GDP per

Capita IV

Log GDP per Capita

IV

Log GDP per Capita

Log GDP per Capita

IV Centuries US 2.145 1.959 1.320 5.641 (0.394)** (1.352) (0.842) (10.135) Centuries Dutch 0.660 0.442 0.483 0.874 (0.117)** (0.304) (0.245)+ (1.433) Centuries British 0.512 0.579 0.096 0.163 (0.155)** (0.214)** (0.294) (1.240) Centuries French 0.586 0.547 0.324 0.177 (0.144)** (0.188)** (0.263) (0.632) Centuries Spanish 0.204 0.157 -0.006 0.425 (0.089)* (0.130) (0.178) (0.877) Centuries Portuguese -0.813 -1.237 -0.575 -0.348 (0.169)** (0.737)+ (0.226)* (1.391) Centuries German 1.332 -3.788 -3.181 -23.81 (1.199) (1.581)* (4.814) (28.012) Centuries Japanese -1.170 -7.113 1.536 -8.691 (0.781) (4.014)+ (2.705) (42.118) Centuries British Legal 0.255 -0.190 (0.192) (0.204) Centuries French Legal 0.392 0.214 (0.141)** (0.143) Centuries German Legal 0.406 -0.017 (0.629) (0.776) Abs(Latitude) 0.054 0.048 0.052 0.053 0.055 0.056 (0.013)** (0.016)** (0.018)** (0.029)+ (0.014)** (0.017)** Area in millions of sq km -13.940 -15.128 -13.184 16.814 -22.117 -24.496 (5.851)* (8.578)+ (4.975)* (76.659) (4.054)** (5.303)** Island is in Pacific 0.703 1.025 0.488 0.401 0.626 0.431 (0.530) (0.723) (0.610) (1.145) (0.539) (0.634) Island is in Atlantic 0.472 0.666 0.893 0.826 0.738 1.216 (0.444) (0.686) (0.538) (1.984) (0.493) (0.558)* Constant 5.849 5.952 6.574 6.488 6.348 6.948 (0.636)** (0.873)** (1.000)** (1.622)** (0.654)** (0.765)** Dummies for Identity of Colonizers?

NO YES NO YES NO NO

Observations 81 81 81 81 81 81 R-squared 0.645 0.685 0.539 0.456 0.497 0.413

Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the island group level.

31

Page 32: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

+ significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

32

Page 33: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Table V The Timing of Colonialism

Columns (1), (3) and (4) are OLS. Column (2) instruments for Centuries a Colony before and after 1700 using the east and north vectors of wind and their standard deviations.

(1) (2) (3) (4) Log GDP per

Capita Log GDP per

Capita IV

Log GDP per Capita

Log GDP per Capita

Centuries a Colony before 1700 -0.152 -1.338 -0.020 -0.097 (0.177) (0.810) (0.210) (0.221) Centuries a Colony after 1700 1.146 1.915 (0.163)** (0.604)** Centuries a Colony 1700-1900 0.840 0.875 (0.244)** (0.233)** Centuries a Colony after 1900 2.246 -0.354 (0.536)** (0.975) Remained a Colony in 2000 1.070 (0.346)** Abs(Latitude) 0.049 0.032 0.044 0.036 (0.011)** (0.018)+ (0.011)** (0.011)** Area in millions of sq km -14.990 0.660 -6.892 -17.582 (6.370)* (16.164) (7.547) (6.425)** Island is in Pacific 1.295 1.709 1.005 1.090 (0.391)** (0.618)** (0.429)* (0.415)* Island is in Atlantic 0.316 0.455 0.310 0.304 (0.337) (0.573) (0.336) (0.338) Constant 4.843 3.827 4.353 6.218 (0.493)** (1.174)** (0.580)** (0.759)** Observations 81 81 81 81 R-squared 0.638 0.385 0.663 0.693

Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the island group level. + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

33

Page 34: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Table VI GDP and Colonialism within Non-island Developing Countries

We started with the Acemoglu-Robinson-Johnson [2001] database and added our own measure of length of colonial period. We dropped the three island countries that were in AJR and our islands database.

(1) Log GDP Per Capita

(2) Log GDP Per Capita

(3) Log GDP Per Capita

(4) Log GDP Per Capita

Number of Centuries a Colony 0.401 0.358 0.287 0.232 (0.097)** (0.090)** (0.072)** (0.084)** Abs(Latitude) 2.952 1.406 1.825 (0.883)** (0.746)+ (0.822)* Mean Temperature -0.023 -0.013 0.005 (0.023) (0.019) (0.021) Expropriation Risk 0.404 (0.067)** Log Settler Mortality (AJR) -0.403 (0.093)** Constant 7.276 7.344 4.873 9.034 (0.215)** (0.686)** (0.682)** (0.728)** Observations 64 64 64 60 R-squared 0.22 0.40 0.63 0.56

Robust standard errors in parentheses. + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

34

Page 35: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix Table I IV First Stage and Reduced Form Regressions

Columns (1), (3) and (5) are the first stage regressions corresponding to columns (3), (5), and (7) in Table II. Columns (2), (4), (6), and (7) are the reduced forms for columns (3), (5), (7), and (9) in Table II. Table II Column (9) has the same first stage as Table II column (3). F-Statistics in the first stage columns are for the instruments alone. Similar IV results obtain when we use LIML rather than two stage least squares.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Number

Centuries A Colony

Log GDP Per Capita

First Year A Colony

Log GDP Per Capita

First Year A Colony

Log GDP Per Capita

Infant Mortality Per 1000

East-West Vector Of Wind -0.236 -0.167 0.184 -0.167 0.173 -0.11 3.198 (0.070)** (0.071)* (0.073)* (0.071)* (0.069)* (0.062)+ (0.884)** Monthly StDev of East-West Vector 0.508 0.395 -0.273 0.395 -0.258 0.193 -6.296 (0.238)* (0.271) (0.208) (0.271) (0.222) (0.246) (3.444)+ Final Year a Colony 0.615 0.083 (1.370) (0.991) Remained A Colony After 2000 -0.472 1.122 (0.532) (0.381)** Abs(Latitude) 0.015 0.064 0.002 0.064 0.009 0.04 -1.045 (0.013) (0.014)** (0.015) (0.014)** (0.016) (0.014)** (0.189)** Area in millions of sq km 8.532 -15.606 -21.322 -15.606 -19.914 -8.544 211.544 (4.671)+ (4.664)** (4.251)** (4.664)** (8.585)* (5.757) (150.690) Island is in Pacific -1.494 -0.033 1.625 -0.033 1.579 0.063 0.292 (0.354)** (0.524) (0.422)** (0.524) (0.420)** (0.498) (8.445) Island is in Atlantic 0.782 0.778 -0.716 0.778 -0.678 0.494 -4.836 (0.362)* (0.553) (0.409)+ (0.553) (0.427) (0.531) (8.572) Constant 0.756 5.968 18.172 5.968 6.008 4.746 57.651 (0.833) (0.913)** (0.926)** (0.913)** (27.032) (19.224) (14.206)** Observations 81 81 81 81 81 81 81 R-Squared 0.681 0.435 0.737 0.435 0.744 0.62 0.425 F Statistic for Instruments 5.81 3.06 3.18 3.06 3.15 1.61 6.75 p-value .005 .055 .049 .055 .050 0.208 .002

Robust standard errors in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered at the island group level. + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

35

Page 36: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix Table II First Stages Regressions for Alternative Sets of Wind Based Instruments

These are the first stage regressions for various combinations of the raw wind data. A positive number for wind blowing on the east (north) vector is blowing TOWARDS the east (north).

(1) (2) (3) (4) number of

centuries a colony

number of centuries a

colony

number of centuries a

colony

number of centuries a

colony East-West Vector of Wind -0.172 -0.236 -0.192 -0.24 (0.060)** (0.070)** (0.068)** (0.087)** East-West Standard Dev. 0.508 0.453 (0.238)* (0.238)+ North-South Vector of Wind -0.116 -0.069 (0.115) (0.118) North-South Standard Dev. -0.01 (0.286) Abs(Latitude) 0.013 0.015 0.019 0.018 (0.014) (0.013) (0.015) (0.016) Area in millions of sq km 7.157 8.532 6.416 8.01 (5.129) (4.671)+ (4.880) (5.058) Island Is In Pacific Ocean -1.526 -1.494 -1.708 -1.616 (0.375)** (0.354)** (0.405)** (0.504)** Island Is In Atlantic Ocean 0.526 0.782 0.255 0.58 (0.374) (0.362)* (0.496) (0.590) Constant 1.884 0.756 1.926 0.934 (0.598)** (0.833) (0.593)** (1.251) Observations 81 81 81 81 R-Squared 0.659 0.681 0.668 0.683 F statistic for instruments 8.2 5.81 4.11 3.58 p-value 0.006 0.005 0.022 0.011

36

Page 37: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

37

Appendix Table III IV Results Using Alternative Sets of Wind Based Instruments

These are the second stage results based on the 4 different instrument sets from Appendix Table I. Instruments used are as follows: (1) East-West vector of wind, (2) East-West vector and standard deviation, (3) East-West vector of wind and North-South vector of wind, (4) East-West vector of wind and North-South vector of wind plus their standard deviations. (1) (2) (3) (4) Log GDP Capita

(2SLS) Log GDP Capita

(2SLS) Log GDP Capita

(2SLS) Log GDP Capita

(2SLS) Number Centuries a Colony 0.681 0.712 0.853 0.786 (0.291)* (0.253)** (0.304)** (0.262)** Abs(Latitude) 0.054 0.054 0.055 0.055 (0.011)** (0.011)** (0.011)** (0.011)** Area in millions of sq km -21.55 -21.738 -22.612 -22.196 (4.019)** (3.970)** (4.284)** (4.065)** Island is in Pacific 0.982 1.018 1.189 1.108 (0.594) (0.559)+ (0.611)+ (0.570)+ Island is in Atlantic 0.22 0.188 0.036 0.108 (0.460) (0.477) (0.493) (0.488) Constant 5.559 5.484 5.131 5.299 (0.891)** (0.834)** (0.953)** (0.864)** Observations 81 81 81 81 R-squared 0.505 0.498 0.449 0.475 Robust standard errors in parentheses + significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

Page 38: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix Table IV List of Islands in Our Dataset

Island Island Group Country First Year

Colony

Last Year

Colony

Number Years

Colony

GDP Capita

2000 Aitutaki Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,814 Andros, North Bahamas Bahamas 1494 1973 479 14,296 Anguilla Anguilla United Kingdom - Anguilla 1650 2004 354 9,617 Antigua Antigua and Barbuda Antigua and Barbuda 1632 1981 349 7,653 Ascension Ascension United Kingdom - Ascension Island 1501 2004 189 2,500 Atiu Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 1,930 Barbados Barbados Barbados 1500 1961 384 9,739 Bermuda Bermuda Bermuda 1609 2004 395 53,735 Bonaire Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1526 2004 478 15,931 Cuba Cuba Cuba 1511 1901 389 2,535 Curacao Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1527 2004 492 15,931 Dominica Dominica Dominica 1763 2004 246 3,484 East Falkland East Falkland Falkland Islands (United Kingdom) 1764 2004 231 25,000 Efate Vanuatu Vanuatu 1887 1980 186 1,164 Fefan Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1885 1986 101 1,335 Funafuti Tuvalu Tuvalu 1916 1978 62 1,204 Futuna Futuna France - Wallis and Futuna 1888 2005 117 3,700 Grand Cayman Grand Cayman United Kingdom - Cayman Islands 1635 2004 369 34,173 Grande Comore Comoros Comoros 1886 1974 88 264 Grande Terre Guadeloupe France - Guadeloupe 1635 2004 376 7,900 Grenada Grenada Grenada 1650 1974 344 3,440 Guam Guam United States - Guam 1565 2005 443 21,000 Hawaii hawaii United States 1900 2005 105 34,364 Hispaniola DOM Dominican Republic Dominican Republic 1495 1924 313 3,029 Hispaniola HTI Hispaniola Haiti 1492 1934 331 485 Huvadu Huvadu Maldives 1558 1965 335 2,151

38

Page 39: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix IV List of Islands in Our Dataset (continued)

Jamaica Jamaica Jamaica 1494 1962 468 3,056 Kadavu Fiji Fiji 1875 1970 95 2,031 Kosrae Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1885 1986 101 2,751 Lifou Loyalty Islands France - Loyalty Islands 1774 2005 231 12,455 Luzon Philippines Philippines 1565 1945 297 1,002 Mahe Seychelles Seychelles 1756 1976 220 7,764 Majuro Marshall Islands Marshall Islands 1886 1986 100 1,896 Malaita Solomon Islands Solomon Islands 1893 1978 86 791 Mangaia Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,171 Mangareva Gambier Is France - French Polynesia - Gambier Is. 1881 2005 124 13,955 Manihiki Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,895 Martinique Martinique France -Martinique 1635 2005 371 14,400 Mauke Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,493 Mauritius Mauritius Mauritius 1638 1968 319 3,839 Mayotte Mayotte France - Mayotte 1843 2004 161 2,600 Mitiaro Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,734 Moen Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1899 1986 87 1,335 Montserrat Montserrat United Kingdom -Montserrat 1632 2004 372 8,919 Nauru Nauru Nauru 1888 1968 78 2,702 New Britain Papua New Guinea Papua New Guinea 1870 1945 61 729 New Caledonia New Caledonia France - New Caledonia 1774 2005 231 12,455 Niue Niue Niue 1901 1974 73 3,600 North Caicos Turks and Caicos Islands United Kingdom - Turks and Caicos Is. 1766 2004 238 9,600 Oreor Palau Palau 1885 2005 120 6,076 Palmerston Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 2,493 Penrhyn Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 989 Pohnpei Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1885 1986 101 2,711 Puerto Rico Puerto Rico United States - Puerto Rico 1493 2004 511 18,047 Pukapuka Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 724 Rakahanga Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 1,528

39

Page 40: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Appendix IV List of Islands in Our Dataset (continued)

Rarotonga Cook Islands Cook Islands 1888 1965 77 6,433 Reunion Reunion France - Reunion 1663 2004 341 6,200 Rurutu Austral Is France - French Polynesia - Austral Is. 1889 2005 116 13,955 Saba Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1632 2004 372 15,931 Saipan Northern Mariana Islands United States – Northern Mariana Islands 1565 2005 440 12,500 Sint Maartin Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1648 2004 356 16,000 St Croix US Virgin Islands United States - Virgin Islands 1666 2004 250 11,868 St Eustatius Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1632 2004 375 15,931 St Helena St Helena United Kingdom - St Helena 1502 2004 494 2,500 St John US Virgin Islands United States - Virgin Islands 1666 2004 250 18,012 St Kitts St. Kitts and Nevis St. Kitts and Nevis 1623 1983 360 8,132 St Lucia St Lucia St Lucia 1650 1967 481 4,424 St Martin Netherlands Antilles Netherlands - Netherlands Antilles 1648 2004 356 9,200 St Thomas US Virgin Islands United States - Virgin Islands 1666 2004 250 14,061 St Vincent St Vincent St Vincent 1680 1979 299 2,891 Tahiti Society Is France - French Polynesia - Society Is. 1843 2005 162 13,955 Tahuata Marquesas France - French Polynesia -Marquesas Is 1842 2005 163 13,955 Tarawa Kiribati - Line Islands Kiribati 1896 1979 85 538 Tol Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1885 1986 101 1,335 Tongatapu Tonga Tonga 1900 1970 70 1,430 Tortola British Virgin Islands United Kingdom - British Virgin Islands 1648 2004 356 33,671 Trinidad TTO Trinidad and Tobago Trinidad and Tobago 1687 1976 289 6,347 Tristan da Cunha Tristan da Cunha & Gouh United Kingdom - Tristan da Cunha 1816 2004 188 2,500 Tutuila American Samoa United States - American Samoa 1900 2005 105 8,000 Yap Federated States of Micronesia Federated States of Micronesia 1885 1986 101 2,751

40

Page 41: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

41

Appendix V GDP by Sector

This is for a subsample of islands in the database. Source is CIA World Factbook 2002, which in turn uses both UN Data and national government statistics from the relevant countries.

island ocean GDP Agriculture Industry Services Bermuda Atlantic 36 B 1% 10% 89% Grand Cayman Atlantic 1.27 B. 1% 3% 95% Jamaica Atlantic 10.21 B. 6% 24% 70% Anguilla Atlantic 104 Mill 4% 18% 78% New Britain Pacific 11.4 B. 32% 36% 32% Majuro Pacific 115 Mill 14% 16% 70% Mauritius Indian 13.85 B. 6% 33% 61% US Virgin Islands Atlantic 2.4 B. 1% 19% 80% Tongatapu Pacific 236 Mill 26% 12% 62% Pohnpei Pacific 277 Mill 50% 4% 46% Montserrat Atlantic 29 Mill 5% 14% 81% New Caledonia Pacific 3.158 B. 5% 30% 65% Guam Pacific 3.2 B. 7% 15% 78% Cuba Atlantic 31.59 B. 8% 35% 58% British Virgin Islands Atlantic 320 Mill 2% 6% 92% St Vincent Atlantic 339 Mill 10% 26% 64% Dominica Atlantic 380 Mill 18% 24% 58% Barbados Atlantic 4.496 B. 6% 16% 78% Grenada Atlantic 440 Mill 8% 24% 68% Kadavu Pacific 5.007 B. 17% 22% 61% Martinique Atlantic 6.117 B. 6% 11% 83% Puerto Rico Atlantic 65.28 B. 1% 42% 57% Antigua Atlantic 750 Mill 4% 19% 77% Tarawa Pacific 79 Mill 30% 7% 63% Malaita Pacific 800 Mill 42% 11% 47% St Lucia Atlantic 866 Mill 7% 20% 73% Reunion Indian 9.387 B. 8% 19% 73%

Page 42: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Figure 1

GDP Per Capita versus Years of Colonialism Circles represent islands in the Atlantic, triangles are islands in the Pacific and squares are islands in the Indian Ocean.

42

Page 43: Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments …jfeyrer/islands_2007_09.pdf ·  · 2007-10-31Colonialism and Modern Income -- Islands as Natural Experiments ...

Figure 2 Years of Colonialism Versus Easterly Vector of Wind

Circles represent islands in the Atlantic, triangles are islands in the Pacific and squares are islands in the Indian Ocean.

43