Children Time and Poverty

download Children Time and Poverty

of 18

Transcript of Children Time and Poverty

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    1/18

    Children, time and poverty:

    The Impact on Children of Easing

    Poor Families Credit Constraints

    Paola Pereznieto

    Javier Escobal

    Paper presented at the XVI ISA World Congress of Sociology, 23 29 July, Durban, SouthAfrica, Research Committee 53, Sociology of Childhood

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    2/18

    1

    Introduction

    A number of economic models have studied childrens time use, adopting a primarily

    utilitarian approach which looks at the value accrued to households of childrensinvolvement in labour and/or education. These models are important to understand poor

    families decision-making processes when facing economic constraints, including the use of

    different household members time, particularly children, for productive purposes.

    However, regarding children as purely economic actors undermines childrens basic rights tosurvival, development, protection and participation. Children who engage in labour activities

    (either formal or informal, domestic or external) to complement family livelihoods run the

    risk of dropping out of school, not having time for studying or leisure and in many cases,falling into harmful forms of labour which undermine their physical, emotional or mental

    development. This is not always the case, however. In some contexts, particularly when it

    does not interfere with schooling, work is not harmful to a childs development and where

    her/his opinion has been considered in the decision-making, childrens work is accepted aspart of the childs upbringing, and can contribute positively to the households improved

    economic status.

    This paper draws on examples from Young Lives1quantitative and qualitative research and

    analyses to illustrate how household decisions and the policy context can underpin

    childrens role as economic actors. It focuses on how credit constraints can influence

    household decisions to either invest in childrens schooling or engage them in economicactivities, with potential medium- to long-term repercussions for their wellbeing and level of

    human capital accumulation. Additionally, the paper briefly explores the contexts under

    which childrens agency, including combining school with work activities, can be positivefor their own development through greater socialisation, strengthening of useful skills,

    interaction with family members, as well as contributing to their households livelihood

    strategies.

    The paper refers to the literature which analyses how factors like credit constraints and

    livelihood shocks faced by households tend to limit their ability to invest in activities with

    greater medium- to long-term returns, prioritising lower return, short-term gains eg

    childrens increased time allocation to work instead of school. The paper then goes on toidentify the gaps in this existing literature, explaining how Young Lives is uniquely placed

    to carry out this analysis and draw policy relevant conclusions on the factors enabling

    childrens economic agency.

    To illustrate Young Lives contribution to this knowledge set, insights will be drawn from

    Young Lives quantitative and qualitative research data, to explore the reasons for economicdecisions regarding childrens time allocation, examining childrens perceived roles as

    economic actors in relation to their poverty status. The examples are drawn from three of thefour Young Lives countries: Peru, India and Ethiopia facilitating a broader perspective of the

    factors that contribute to childrens engagement in economic activities.

    Results are consistent with the literature, suggesting that the choice between childrens

    schooling and work time allocation is influenced by multiple factors, one of which is

    1Young Lives is an international longitudinal study on childhood poverty and policy in Ethiopia, India (Andhra Pradesh),

    Peru and Vietnam. Young Lives is funded by the UK Department of International Development, DFID.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    3/18

    2

    households credit constraints. Understanding these linkages is essential for identifying

    specific policy measures and compensatory mechanisms that could be put in place to offsetthe adverse consequences of increased pressures on childrens time to allocate to competing

    priorities, mainly school, work and leisure and allow them to exert more agency over this

    decision.

    Models for childrens time use

    Childrens time use has been analysed using a variety of economic models which focus on

    the value accrued to households of childrens time allocation to schooling and/or labour in

    the short run, with respect to returns on investment in human capital (Becker, 1965). In this

    utilitarian approach, the decision on how much time to allocate to these two activitiesdepends on expected returns to work relative to future income. The key variables are the

    expected rate of return to human capital accumulation in the future relative to a householdsvaluation of income today. The marginal return to income is higher for poorer households,

    so only when their valuation of education (the main component of human capital) issufficiently great (the valuation includes expected returns from more highly skilled jobs,

    parents appreciation of education and social acceptance), will they forgo present income for

    schooling. This model highlights the fact that, in the presence of inefficient credit markets -

    as is often the case in developing countries - households are unable to smooth consumption

    in the long run, which influences their inter-temporal decisions2 over work and schooling

    (Becker, 1993).

    Psacharopoulos (1999) developed a more specific model for time use, based on a

    households utility function whereby adult family members and children contribute to

    household income with the aim of maximising benefits, subject to time and budgetconstraints. In cases where the optimum utility includes the income derived from childrens

    work, the opportunity costs for children is their time for schooling and leisure.

    Other models focus on intra-household bargaining (Bourginon and Chiappori, 1994, in

    Dehejia and Gatti, 2002 and Basu, 1999), where the time children allocate to work is a result

    of a bargaining process within the household, and where the relative power of each family

    member depends on her/his contribution to total household resources. In this case, childrenmight find it useful to work because they are awarded more authority within the household.

    Although for simplicity these models take into consideration school and work as the two

    only possible activities for children, it is important to consider the time children should

    spend on leisure activities: eg playing, socialising in the community, or studying, whichcontribute positively to their psycho-social development (Bourdillon, 2006). Leisure tends to

    be a substitute for work, and since leisure generates the least utility to families, a shift in

    economic conditions that increases the rate of return of childrens work, will cause theirleisure time to be sacrificed (Dehejia and Gatti, 2002).

    These economic models reflect a reality: children, mainly in poor households, are seen as

    economic agents who have labour as their key asset. By approaching families

    2In economics, inter-temporality means that certain actions and decisions can be made at different moments in time,according to what is most beneficial to the economic actor. In this case, it refers to households decisions whether to

    optimize their economic wellbeing in the short or the long run.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    4/18

    3

    decision-making processes from a utilitarian perspective, these models may neglect many

    key elements, such as childrens own perspectives and opinions on how to maximise theirown utilities, as well as the importance of respecting the rights of children to ensure their

    development needs are met (Feeny and Boyden, 2004).

    Debates on Child Labour: when does work conflict with childrens rights?

    Child labour has been extensively researched in the development literature, with positionson the subject ranging from total opposition to any form of child labour to more recent

    acceptance of child labour as a phenomenon that is necessary in some households for raising

    additional income; in this context, child work is also seen as contributing positively to

    childrens self-assurance and development (Bourdillon, 2006).

    Conceptualising childrens right to education, freedom from economic exploitation and

    leisure in developing countries should incorporate an awareness of the different ways ofunderstanding child work, given the diverse situations in which families live and themechanisms they draw on to ensure family survival and wellbeing. This means that certain

    forms of work that children in the North would not engage in, are quite common, acceptable

    and even appreciated by children and their communities in some developing countries

    such is the significance of childrens contribution to the household or in the family farm

    (CIDA, n.d.).

    There is possibly a consensus around the worst forms of child labour, which are those that

    damage childrens physical, psychological, social or moral development, and it is preciselyagainst these that Article 32 in the UN Convention on the Rights of the Child takes an

    unambiguous stance. Other forms of child work which are not exploitative may be

    considered acceptable or unacceptable according to the perspective and the context (Feenyand Boyden, 2004), but it is acknowledged that in many cases, children are regarded as

    economic agents.

    There are many factors to consider when analysing the consequences of child labour. One

    key factor is the impact with respect to education. There tends to be agreement that work is

    harmful when it interferes with schooling and the childs capacity to develop her or hishuman capital potential. Bhalotra (2003) explains that, to the extent that poverty pushes

    children into work, child work results in the absence of equality of opportunity in human

    capital acquisition, and is a mechanism for the intergenerational transmission of poverty.

    Clearly, this implies that full time work is negative for children. Still, empirical research

    shows that the majority of children are not employed in full time activities. (Guracello et al.,

    2003).

    A rights-based analysis of childrens time use focuses particularly on the extent to which

    time deprivation may prevent the realisation of a childs rights to quality education (Art. 28)

    and to leisure and rest (Art. 31). In most developing countries, childrens involvement inhousehold activities (either domestic or at the family farm / small business) is seen as a

    desirable activity, contributing to childrens development and complementary to formal

    education (Boyden, 2005; CIDA, n.d.). Where schools are accessible, evidence shows that aslong as households economic livelihoods are not compromised, children will attend school

    and the time they spend on work competes marginally with schooling, although it tends to

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    5/18

    4

    compete more significantly with leisure or study time (Dehejia and Gatti, 2002; Brown et

    al., 2002).

    However, as a result of poor families increased vulnerability to economic changes, childrenwho engage in labour activities (either formal or informal, domestic or external) tocomplement family livelihoods are always at risk of needing to alter their time use in

    response to economic hardship. A shock to the household economy generates a change in

    childrens opportunity cost of education: the need for short-term income increases, causing a

    relative decrease in the discounted value of education.

    Harper (2002) argues that child work is a manifestation of poverty, and in particular,tackling childhood poverty and the mechanisms which lead to the transmission of povertybetween generations and across the life course, could be an effective way to address chronic

    poverty. One transmission mechanism is the under-investment in childrens human capital,

    with consequences for future earnings (Guarcello et al., 2003).

    In addition to poverty, there are a multiplicity of factors that influence the decisions of poor

    families regarding child work and schooling, including the quality of school and itsaccessibility, parents education and their valuation of education, among others. Yet, one of

    the key factors contributing to child labour is poor households vulnerability to risks and

    their inability to access mechanisms to mitigate their impact, which have a direct bearing on

    the possibility of fulfilling childrens rights to education and leisure.

    Under these conditions, it becomes clear that policies targeted at reducing household povertythrough economic empowerment, particularly through lessening credit constraints, can be

    effectively used to address potential trade-offs between childrens time for work, school and

    leisure / play, reducing vulnerabilities, and ensure their rights are met in a sustainable way.

    Macro-level policies promoting poverty reduction: their links to children

    Countries poverty reduction strategies are geared towards promoting economic growth.

    They encompass numerous policies that target different aspects of development, including

    agricultural development, financial markets, gender empowerment, education, health, etc.The aim is that if effective, these distributional policies should contribute to poverty

    reduction, thus achievingpro-poor growth.

    In the last few years, one of the mechanisms through which poverty reduction policies have

    aimed to promote poor households economic empowerment, encourage livelihooddiversification and reduce vulnerability to risk is through reducing the credit constraints of

    the poor. This is usually done at two different levels:

    1) Promoting adequate regulatory frameworks that will enable financial markets to develop,

    and particularly reaching poorer communities, who are frequently without financialservices because of the risk implied by lack of collateral or legal mechanisms that can

    ensure repayment (Beegle et al., 2003).

    2) Working with communities at the micro-level, by encouraging microcredit institutions to

    provide poor families with options to increase their productivity (when the amount ofcredit is sufficient) or to smooth consumption in the face of shocks (Khandker, 2003).

    With respect to the impact of microfinance, the United Nations Capital Development Fund

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    6/18

    5

    (UNDP, 2006) explains that it has been shown to (i) help very poor households meet basic

    needs and protect themselves against risks; (ii) improve household economic welfare andenterprise stability or growth; and (iii) contribute to womens empowerment, by supporting

    womens economic participation, thus promoting gender equity and improving household

    wellbeing. UNICEF (2000), for example, recognises the value of these initiatives bysupporting microcredit schemes when lack of access to small loans is identified as a key

    obstacle to improving the situation of women and children. This entails a two-pronged

    approach that combines microcredit with social messages, which often contributes to ahigher demand for basic social services.

    To understand the impact on children of making microcredit accessible to poor households,

    it is essential to move beyond aggregate analysis at the household level and look at the

    intra-household impacts of such credit provision.

    The role of credit in decisions over childrens time allocation

    A number of recent models show that, by preventing households from trading off resources

    inter-temporally in an optimal way, credit constraints give rise to inefficiently high childlabour (Dehejia and Gatti, 2002; Beegle et al., 2003; Guarcello et al., 2003). In one sense,

    by letting children work, parents are borrowing from the future rather than investing in the

    human capital that would make children more productive in the future. This strategy, which

    can be optimal for a family faced with time and resource constraints, is not efficient giventhat the present discounted value of another hour of schooling is greater than the return to

    another hour of work3 (Brown, et al., 2002).

    Basu (1999) explains this phenomenon by the fact that, in developing countries, a common

    reason for children to discontinue education is not chronic poverty, but a temporary crisis inthe family. As outlined before, results of both theoretical and empirical studies show that

    households, particularly the poor, aim to smooth their consumption to avoid the troughscaused by external shocks (such as droughts, floods, the illness of the main breadwinner,

    dowry payments) in the long run, which is difficult in the absence of an adequate credit

    markets (Guarcello et al., 2003; Beegle et al., 2003). Thus, when faced with credit

    constraints, children in the household are frequently the economic agents that contribute tosmoothing consumption by providing additional income. Conversely, evidence suggests that

    if credit is widely available, households can borrow to smooth income variability without

    disrupting childrens education or leisure time (Deheijia and Gatti, 2002).

    Childrens participation in the workforce, however, does not necessarily imply that they willdrop out of school or that work will cause a loss in school attainment. Sedlacek et al.(2005)

    explain that the research establishing the link between child labour and education is limited.

    For example, in Latin America, child labour does have a negative and significant effect onschool enrolment, but the greater adverse effect is on the pace of progression through school

    3 In the framework of human capital investment, the general principle is that it is more efficient to invest in educationduring childhood to maximize the level of human capital in an individual as an adult, contributing significantly to the

    probability of earning a higher income. When discounted at present value, the returns from this more highly paid job are

    higher than the returns from the income received through childrens work activities. Thus, credit constraints can pushhouseholds to inefficiently increase the number of a childs work hours, reducing the time the child can invest in

    developing its human capital, through schooling.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    7/18

    6

    and the quality of attainment through attendance. Schooling is not a full time activity, so the

    trade off between work and schooling time might not be significant these two activitiesmight co-exist at the expense of leisure activities (Dehejia and Gatti, 2002).

    Rosati and Rossi (2003) analyse the decision-making process in a more nuanced way. They

    look at the time that children devote to work, both when it is their only activity and when

    they combine it with schooling. They emphasise the importance of accounting for thenumber of hours spent working, which is used as a measure of child welfare (a measure of

    foregone schooling and leisure), but it is also essential to evaluate the cost of work in terms

    of human capital accumulation.

    Given that multiple strategies have been attempted to reduce child labour and its impact onschool attainment with few having been successful, promoting access to credit as a means to

    reduce household vulnerability, promote livelihoods and reduce child labour is a highly

    policy relevant topic. In fact, as Dehejia and Gatti (2002) and Guarcello et al. (2003)

    suggest, policies aimed at developing financial and capital markets, and at improving riskcoping and risk reduction mechanisms, could be effective instruments to reduce the extent of

    child labour and increase human capital accumulation.

    Another issue to consider in relation to access to credit is households asset composition. In

    general, assets are found to be negatively correlated with child labour (Brown et al., 2002)

    given that assets help to ease the credit constraints for some households since they can be

    used as collateral. Cockburn (2001), however, demonstrates how different physical assetshave different effects on child labour supply according to their degree of substitution.

    Increased access to physical assets that require relatively more child labour, such as small

    animals, will tend to increase child labour participation and reduce child schooling andleisure. Consequently, the choice of assets to be promoted in a poverty alleviation

    programme must consider the effects on child labour and schooling. Thus, if access to assets

    is being promoted with the policy objective of reducing child labour and increase childschooling, care should be taken to encourage the accumulation of those physical assets that

    increase household income, ease credit constraints and encourage substitution away from

    child labour. This is not a trivial policy issue as we will see from the example from theYoung Lives research where there was evidence of increased child work after the

    implementation of a poverty reduction policy promoting access to credit to acquire assets,

    which turned out to be intensive in child labour.

    In addition to policies aimed at generating access to credit markets, policies providing safetynets are also powerful instruments to promote school attendance and reduce child work

    (Guarcello et al., 2003). Cash transfer programmes, often conditional on school attendance(like Bolsa Escola in Brazil, Oportunidades in Mexico and Juntos in Peru), have been laudedas one of the best ways to tackle this problem (Sedlacek, 2005; Perry et al., 2006). They

    work with a similar principle to microcredit: the transfer relieves the households credit

    constraint, helps it smooth consumption and thus encourages children to stay in school.Nevertheless, one shortcoming is sustainability: these programmes are expensive,

    particularly if provision is comprehensive; they are often unaffordable in developing

    countries in the long run. Microcredit, however, has been shown to be sustainable, whether

    they are implemented for profit or non-profit; these mechanisms can therefore be more

    easily implemented among the countrys poor. This does not mean that social protectionmechanisms such as cash transfer programmes should be ruled out, because not all families

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    8/18

    7

    in poor communities have the characteristics required to access credit (particularly in the

    short-term); however, credit schemes can complement these efforts, perhaps in a moresustainable way.

    Empirical studies and findings

    Although access to credit has been recognised as central to child labour, there has been little

    empirical work done on the subject, partly because data sets do not provide all theinformation needed to carry out a comprehensive analysis. One of the main problems is that

    credit access is difficult to measure from Living Standard Measurement Surveys, which

    usually only ask whether a household had a loan or bank account this is not a good

    measure of access to credit, since some households that have access to credit might not havehad to borrow.

    In addition, without access to information on the time use of children outside the market,estimation of these models is limited to datasets that do not distinguish clearly between the

    time children spend on school, work and leisure, so that the resulting analysis on childrens

    time allocation is only partial (Apps, 2002).

    Jacoby and Skoufias (1997) carried out the first serious empirical work that addressed theissue of poor households which lack access to credit markets and which might draw on child

    labour when faced with income shocks. With data from six Indian villages, the authors

    concluded that childrens economic activity is used by poor households as a means to insure

    themselves against risks. Dehejia and Gatti (2002), on the other hand, carried out their workat an aggregate level, measuring child labour as a country aggregate and approximating

    credit constraints by the countrys level of financial development. Beegle et al. (2003) were

    the first to use panel data for their analysis, focusing on Tanzania. The study finds thathouseholds respond to transitory income shocks by increasing child labour, but the extent to

    which child labour is used as a buffer is less when households have access to credit.

    Guarcello et al. (2002) analysed the response of child labour to income shocks (loss ofemployment, death in the family, droughts in the region, etc.) in Guatemala. They identified

    a sub-sample of credit-constrained households and found that credit rationing is associated

    with higher child labour and that shocks significantly increase the proportion of working

    children. Ersado (2002) found that in Nepal, Peru and Zimbabwe, improving access to credithas potential for alleviating child labour and enhancing school enrolment in rural areas,

    although less so in urban areas. Given that Living Standard Measurement Surveys, often

    used to analyse households economic situation, have little information on credit accessErsado used data from commercial banks at the community level as proxy measures of

    access to the formal credit market. Acknowledging it as a partial source of information on

    credit access, he warned that results should be interpreted with caution. However, despite thelimits of his information, the results are still consistent with other findings in the literature.

    The empirical work to date has therefore clearly endorsed the thesis that improving credit

    access has great potential to reduce child labour. Given the policy relevance of such a

    conclusion, it is critical to have a broader and more precise evidence base that can be useful

    for influencing policy.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    9/18

    8

    Young Lives research and findings

    The existing evidence strongly suggests that easing poor families credit constraints has a

    positive impact on the reduction of child labour and on the promotion of schooling andleisure activities for children. However, there is an acknowledgement in the literature of

    insufficient information and data linking credit constraints and households decisions

    resulting in studies having to approximate their analysis through aggregate variables orproxies for information on credit and time allocation. Beegle et al. (2003) were closer to

    having a good dataset in their panel survey for Tanzania; but as the survey was not designed

    to research the connection between access to credit and child labour, the findings are not asprecise.

    Young Lives is in a strong position to do research on identifying the conditions which push

    household members, including children themselves, to make decisions during their lifetime

    regarding childrens time allocation, particularly with respect to consumption, shocks, credit

    markets, availability of schools and childrens agency.

    Young Lives carries out both quantitative and qualitative research which it frequentlyanalysed in tandem to develop a more comprehensive perspective on the policy issues it is

    examining. This research generates informative conclusions and messages to inform

    policy-makers.

    Focusing on childrens time allocation and the impact of credit constraints, we have some

    interesting findings from the data available to date, which we will look at below. However,given its longitudinal nature and the fact that the second round of data collection has been

    revised to include precise and specific questions that will enable an understanding of the

    connections between credit constraints and child labour, from the first half of 2007, Young

    Lives will be a unique source of information on the factors that make credit markets workfor children.

    Let us look at three examples based on Young Lives current research which suggest some

    initial conclusions; we will then briefly outline the possibilities of the projects futureresearch based on the its second round of data collection and further qualitative research

    during its second phase.

    Quantitative analysis: Improvement of credit constraints and child labour in Peru

    In line with the review of the literature, when credit constraints are prevalent, as is the case

    for most poor households in urban and rural Peru, short-term economic shocks may haveimportant long-term consequences, particularly on educational outcomes.

    Based on panel data from Peruvian households, Escobal et al. (2005) looked at how shocks

    affect the progress of 6 to 14 year-olds children in the Peruvian school system. The authors

    found no evidence of negative shocks resulting in further overage4. However, although

    Peruvian parents seem to be reluctant about taking their children out of school when facing

    an economic shock, there is evidence that negative shocks reduce the effective accumulation

    of human capital through cuts in educational expenditure both in urban and rural areas.Escobal, et al identified two ways in which households modify expenditure on education

    4Overage occurs if the child repeats a school year or drops out temporarily or permanently from the school system.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    10/18

    9

    when faced with adverse economic shocks: moving their children from private to public

    schools5 and reducing educational spending on children

    6. This result is consistent with

    Patrinos and Psacharopoulos (1997) who found that child labour and schooling in Peru may

    be complementary, which means that rather than substituting school time for work, both

    activities are carried out by the child during the course of a day.

    To explore this issue further, we analyse data from the 8-year-old cohort in the PeruvianYoung Lives sample. We explore the relationship between credit constraints and changes in

    the time devoted to school and work. It is important to highlight from the outset that, as seen

    in table 1, in this sample consisting of nearly 1000 children, most of them, with theexception of 6 (1.5% of the sample) go to school. Nevertheless, approximately 20% of the

    sampled children acknowledged they work to earn additional income for their families.

    Further, more than half of the sampled households admitted to having a credit burden. It is

    interesting to note that households that have important debt are slightly more likely to have

    children that combine school and work. The analysis presented in table one provides ageneral overview of the link between households debt status and childrens participation in

    school and work. However, at this stage the analysis explicitly excludes other variables that

    might also have an impact on the school/work decision, which need to be controlled for in

    further analysis to asses whether serious debt has a strong impact on schooling outcomes.

    Table 1Relationship Between Debt Status and Children School/Labour Outcomes

    Only Studies Studies and

    Works

    Only

    Works

    Does not

    Work orStudy

    Total

    Has an important debt 41.6% 11.1% - - 52.7%Has no important debts 36.7% 9.1% - - 45.8%

    No response 0.4% 0.3% 0.3% 0.6% 1.5%

    Total 78.7% 20.4% 0.3% 0.6% 100.0%

    Source: Peruvian Young Lives 8 year cohort sample.

    On the other hand table 2 shows that those children combining work and school in general

    have lower mathematics, reading and writing skills as assessed by the YL survey than thoseonly attending school. Items evaluating these competencies were included in the Young

    Lives questionnaire and administered to the 8 year cohort7. Cueto et al (2005) indicate that

    since each achievement area was only evaluated through a single item and correlationsbetween were positive, a factor analysis was carried out to generate a composite

    achievement for the three areas tested. The last column in Table 2 presents this overall skill

    score.

    Table 2

    5 Perus public education has fared poorly in international evaluations (see results from PISA, www.pisa.oecd.org)6This refers to expenditure on books, uniforms, school utensils and in some cases, extra tuition, even when there are noschool fees.7The reading evaluation required children to read three letters (N, A, P); one word (pan, Spanish for bread), and one

    sentence (El pan es rico, Spanish for the bread is tasty). The item to measure writing skills required children to write thesentence me gustan los perros (Spanish for I like dogs). Finally to asses numeracy skills, children were required to solve

    a basic multiplication (2 x 4).

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    11/18

    10

    Work and Skills

    (Percentage of Children Doing Excercises Right)

    Math Skills Reading Skills Writing

    Skills

    Skills Score

    Only Goes to School 59.8% 84.5% 59.9% 1.219

    Goes to School and Works 53.3% 72.9% 40.9% 1.018

    Difference is Statistically Significant

    (95%) NO YES YES YES

    Source: Peruvian Young Lives Sample (8 Year Old)

    Appendix 1 shows the results from a regression analysis looking at the effect that credit

    constraints may have on school and work decisions, as well as the effect that these decisions

    can have on childrens accumulation of skills though schooling. The table shows the

    following: column 1 has the determinants of the score for children that combined school and

    work; column 2 shows the same determinants for those who only attended school; column 3shows the probability of working in addition to going to school. The three equations have

    been estimated simultaneously. To identify the selection equation adequately, twoexogenous variables were used: (a) household has a serious debt; and (b) there is no father in

    the household. We hypothesized that these variables affect the decision of the child

    attending school or/and work, but only contribute to childrens performance when the childworks. Interestingly both variables were jointly significant in the selection equation and

    neither appears significant if included in the skill equation8.

    Our results show that having an important debt can affect, though marginally, the probability

    of children working in addition to attending school. Other key determinants of work are alow socio economic status (proxied by access to electricity and mothers educational level),

    the distance to school and having no father in the household. It is interesting to note thatcontrolling for the decision to combine work and schooling, mother education plays a largerrole in increasing skills for those children that just attending school. This implies that even if

    combining both activities, children learn more at school when supported at home by a better

    educated mother. However, for these children with more highly educated mothers who havethe skills to find a better paid job outside the house, younger siblings may generate a

    competing demand for mothers time, so children might be required to look after their

    younger siblings. In this case, the data shows that a larger number of children under 3 in the

    household may result in less time for studying and lower school achievement. Policies thatpromote access to free or cheap child care facilities may help to shift childrens time away

    from caring for their sibling and increase their time for learning or leisure.

    To ensure these results are robust to alternative skills indicators, we carried out a second

    regression replacing the skills index with the composite score constructed from the Ravens

    test administrated to the eight year cohort9. Although the appropriateness of this test for

    Peruvian eight year olds has not been validated, it interesting to note that the results seem

    reliable10

    . Given these results we can safely claim that the overall item indicator does

    represent a good measure of general ability.

    8The SmithBlundell test for exogeneity was conducted to confirm these results.9Raven's Progressive Matrices, a test of general ability, is often suggested as a means of identifying non verbal IQ.10 As measured by Cronbach's alpha reliability coefficient, which is reasonably high for each of the three sections of the

    test (0.769, 0.843 0.858) and is even higher when calculated for all items together (0.929).

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    12/18

    11

    Thus, Young Lives results in Peru show that although work does not generally cause

    children to drop out of school, combining both activities has a significant impact onchildrens learning and thus their accumulation of human capital. This is exacerbated when

    the family faces an important debt burden. By promoting mechanisms to release households

    credit constraints, debt burdens could be better managed and thus result in children beingable to allocate more time to school and learning.

    Findings from Young Lives Qualitative Research in Andhra Pradesh, India

    Box 1 outlines the second example from Young Lives research, illustrating the connection

    between poor households access to credit and childrens increased time allocation to

    schooling. It draws on a sub-sample of four sites in Andhra Pradesh, India, where in-depthqualitative research was undertaken with beneficiaries of womens Self Help Groups

    (SHGs) and their leaders to find out how the SHG and the loans received by members, arebeing used to improve household wellbeing, particularly that of children. The general

    conclusion was that, despite the small size of the loans, they are contributing positively tosmoothing families consumption and thus allowing children to stay in school.

    Box 1: Self Help Groups in Andhra Pradesh (AP), India

    (see Jones and Mukherjee, 2006)

    In the context of poverty reduction and economic development in AP, the promotion of

    microfinance has been identified as a primary engine for community development.

    In particular, womens SHGs, whose main objective is the provision of small loans to womenmembers, have been promoted extensively by the Indian government as a model for community

    development at the grassroots level.

    Microcredit institutions have thrived and there are public, NGO, private and donor funded

    initiatives.

    Young Lives research has found several limitations in these mechanisms, such as the fact that

    the small loans provided are insufficient for channelling women into productive investments to

    become self-employed, which is their original intention.

    However, interviews with members of self help groups revealed that these small loan are used

    for consumption spending, mainly allocating resources to childrens wellbeing, primarily

    spending on schooling and nutrition, and reducing the likelihood of children dropping out ofschool. This illustrates clearly that a relaxation of credit constraints tends to have a positive

    impact on investment in human capital, as more time is allocated away from work to school.

    An additional positive externality of SHGs in AP is that womens greater control over resources

    has strengthened their role in decision-making in the household, translating into more resources

    being spent on child development.

    From this preliminary evidence, in the case of AP, microcredit for women can be used as a

    policy measure to ensure that childrens rights are pursued.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    13/18

    12

    Findings from Young Lives Quantitative and Qualitative Research in Ethiopia

    The next example, in box 2, draws on research carried out in Ethiopia by the Young Lives

    team, targeted mainly at identifying how the first phase Ethiopias Poverty ReductionStrategy Paper had performed in terms of improving child wellbeing by making policy

    recommendations to improve the attention given to children in the second PRSP. The

    research draws on a sample of 1,999 households with at least one child aged 6 to 17 in 2002,and on additional household data collected from 3,115 children aged 7 to 17 years from 20

    sentinel sites. From this, the Young Lives project sought to understand the impact on child

    labour and schooling of public policy interventions formulated within the PRSP(Woldehanna et al., 2005). These quantitative findings were complemented by in-depth

    interviews. In this case, the findings endorse Cockburns (2001) research, which suggests

    that if credit is used to buy assets, it will only have a positive impact on childrens schooling

    if such assets are not intensive in child labour.

    Box 2: Ethiopia and Agricultural Development Led Industrialisation

    (See Woldehannaet al., 2005)

    Ethiopias Agriculture Development Led Industrialisation (ADLI) is one pillar of Ethiopias

    PRSP. Its aim is promoting economic growth by stimulating Ethiopias agricultural sector which

    has comparative advantage.

    The policy promotes labour-intensive agricultural activities through diverse mechanisms, one of

    which is credit provision to families for buying agricultural equipment and assets, like livestock.

    Although the programme has had some initial achievement in promoting sectoral development

    and the livelihoods of families involved in it, Young Lives research shows that it has had some

    unexpected impacts on childrens time allocation: ownership of livestock in Ethiopia is

    negatively associated with child enrolment since children's labour is usually used for herding

    cattle.

    Children with increased responsibilities for rearing livestock were shown to spend less time in

    school and on school-related activities.

    This means that in this context, even if the policy is raising the sectors productivity with a

    positive effect on aggregate rural household income and a relaxation of credit constraints, it has

    had some unexpected impacts on child wellbeing mediated through intra-household dynamics.

    Accordingly, to ensure that the policy incorporates childrens wellbeing as one of its objectives, it

    is essential to identify specific actions. One way is ensuring that the loan provided to thehousehold is sufficient not only to buy livestock, but to ensure that they can employ additional

    external help to free childrens time from herding and shifting it to school or leisure, and

    encouraging their human capital development.

    From these three examples, we can see the current potential of Young Lives to do analyses

    relating child labour and the reduction of constraints for access to credit. But the projects

    real potential to generate unique new knowledge on this issue will be realised after thesecond round of quantitative data collection because:

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    14/18

    13

    1. The new questionnaire asks specific questions on childrens time allocation, not only to

    childrens carers, but to children themselves. This will be critical in analysingcontinuous and precise changes in time allocated to work, school and leisure; this

    information is seldom available from household questionnaires, and will enable us to

    track the marginal changes that cause shifts from one activity to another.

    2. The questions on loans are very detailed, including a question on whether the individualwould get a loan in response to a shock.

    3. There are comprehensive questions on shocks and household responses to them.

    4. The same households and children will be asked the same questions again three years

    later, enabling us to understand their household decisions, and the implications for

    children.

    5. Having a panel, after the second round of data collection, will allow to better control for

    un-observable factors that can skew the estimated relationship between creditconstraints and child time allocation.

    Conclusions

    Childrens involvement in work is not always problematic, but it can be a violation of

    childrens rights when it is exploitative or interferes with their possibilities to fulfil other

    rights, such as the right to quality education and leisure, and undermines their potential todevelop their human capital and thus potentially causes an intergenerational poverty trap.

    Understanding household and childrens decisions over time use is essential in trying to

    identify the factors that will help keep children in school and minimise their work time,particularly in circumstances of economic adversity like external shocks.

    Understanding the linkages between macro-level policies, such as microfinancemechanisms, is essential in terms of identifying the different compensatory policies

    governments can put into place to offset the potentially negative consequences of childlabour, and maximising the potential to ensure that childrens wellbeing is promoted in

    context-appropriate ways. This implies that families are able to preserve their level of

    consumption and thus mitigate vulnerabilities through the use of credit, and not childrens

    work.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    15/18

    14

    Appendix 1

    Skill Test Performance Conditional on School and Working Decisions

    (Endogenous switching regression model)

    Skills Score Selection Equation(1) (2) (3)

    ChildrenStudies and Work

    ChildrenOnly Studies

    (Probability of Workingand Studying)

    Gender of the Child 0.045 -0.002 0.202 *

    (0.067) (0.026) (0.121)

    Child Age (in months) 0.362 *** 0.136 *** -0.019

    (0.102) (0.042) (0.194)

    Age at which Child Started School -0.083 -0.084 *** -0.051

    (0.062) (0.026) (0.120)

    Number of Rooms in Dwelling 0.001 0.009 -0.016

    (0.021) (0.008) (0.039)Has Electricity -0.158 ** 0.056 -0.389 ***

    (0.085) (0.037) (0.149)

    Parents own their Dwelling -0.088 0.026 0.161

    (0.070) (0.029) (0.132)

    Mother's Education -0.008 0.021 *** -0.034 ***

    (0.010) (0.004) (0.016)

    Speaks a Native Language 0.047 -0.103 *** 0.202

    (0.100) (0.051) (0.199)

    Body Mass Index - Mother 0.012 0.004 -0.033 ***

    (0.009) (0.004) (0.017)

    Body Mass Index - Child -0.008 0.013 ** 0.001(0.018) (0.007) (0.034)

    School is Private -0.176 -0.069 0.223

    (0.147) (0.043) (0.249)

    # family member above 3 years -0.005 -0.027 *** 0.027

    (0.018) (0.007) (0.034)

    # of young siblings under 3 -0.094 -0.025 -0.045

    (0.069) (0.028) (0.129)

    Distance to School -0.006 ** 0.000 -0.012 ***

    (0.003) (0.001) (0.006)

    Area is Urban 0.127 0.058 -0.299 ***

    (0.082) (0.036) (0.153)Father is missing 0.279 ***

    (0.128)

    Household has a Important Debt 0.130 *

    (0.684)

    Constant -2.046 -0.436 1.188

    (1.012) (0.427) (1.937)

    Number of obs 638

    Wald chi2(15) 35.23 Prob > chi2 0.0023

    LR test: indep. eqns. chi2(1) 3.85 Prob > chi2 0.0499

    Source: Own Estimation based on Peruvian Young Lives 8 year cohort sample.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    16/18

    15

    References

    Apps, P. (2002) Gender, Time Use, And Models Of The Household,Institute for the Studyof Labour (IZA),Discussion PaperNo. 796.

    Basu, K. (1999) Child Labour: Cause, Consequence, and Cure, with Remarks onInternational Labour Standards,Journal of Economic LiteratureVol. XXXVII, (September

    1999), pp. 10831119.

    Becker, G. (1965) A Theory of the Allocation of Time, The Economic Journal, Vol. 75,

    No. 299, September 1965.

    Becker, G. (1993) Human Capital, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, Third

    Edition.

    Beegle, K., Dehejia, R. and Gatti, R. (2003) Child labour, Income Shocks, and Access to

    Credit, World Bank Policy Working PaperNo. 3075.

    Bhalotra, S. (2003) Is Child Work Necessary? Working Paper 00/493, May 2003,

    Department of Economics, University of Bristol.

    Bourdillon, M. (2006) Violence Against Working Children: A Report on Recent Research

    Relating to Work that is Harmful to Children, Stockholm Save the Children Sweden.

    Bourguignon, F. and Chiappori, P. (1994) The Collective Approach to HouseholdBehavior, in The Measurement of Household Welfare, R. Blundell, I. Preston and I. Walker

    (eds.), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Boyden, J. (2005) Does child labour always undermine education? ID21 InsightsNo. 56

    http://www.id21.org/insights/insights56/insights-iss56-art08.html

    Brown, B., Deardorff, A. and Stern, R. (2002) The Determinants of Child Labour: Theory

    and Evidence, University of Michigan Discussion PaperNo. 486.

    Canadian International Development Agency (CIDA), n.d., Childrens Contribution to

    Working and Caring for the Land: The Links between Agriculture and Childrens Rights,Discussion Paper & Programming Tool, Childrens Rights Unit, Human Rights andParticipation Division.

    Cockburn, J. (2001) Child Labour Versus Education: Poverty Constraints or Income

    Opportunities?, CREFA (Universit Laval) Working Paper, Qubec.

    Dehejia, R. and Gatti, R. (2002) Child Labour: The Role of Income Variability and Access

    to Credit in a Cross-Section of Countries, World Bank Policy Working PaperNo. 2767.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    17/18

    16

    Escobal, J., Saavedra, J. and Surez P. (2005) Economic Shocks and Changes in School

    Attendance Levels and Education Expenditure in Peru, Young Lives Working PaperNo. 13,Young Lives: London.

    Ersado, L. (2002) Child Labour and School Decisions in Urban and Rural Areas: CrossCountry Evidence, FCND Discussion PaperNo. 145, International Food Policy Research

    Institute.

    Feeny, F. and Boyden, J. (2004) Acting in Adversity Rethinking the Causes, Experiences

    and Effects of Child Poverty In Contemporary Literature, QEH Working Paper Number

    116.

    Guarcello, L., Mealli, F. and Rosati, F. (2003) Household Vulnerability and Child Labour:

    The Effect of Shocks, Credit Rationing and Insurance, Report for the Understanding

    Childrens Work Interagency Working Group: UNICEF, ILO, World Bank Group, July2003.

    Khandker, S. (2003) Micro-finance and Poverty: Evidence Using Panel Data from

    Bangladesh, World Bank Policy Research Working PaperNo. 2945.

    Harper, C. (2002) Policy Arena: Recent Approaches to Understanding Policy And Action

    For Eradicating Childhood Poverty,Journal of International Development14, 10751079.

    Jacoby, H. and Skoufias, E. (1997) Risk, Financial Markets, and Human Capital in a

    Developing Country,Review of Economic Studies, LXIV (1997), 311-335.

    Jones, N. and Mukherjee, M. (2006), Synergies and Tensions Between Womens

    Empowerment and Childrens Rights: A Critical Assessment of Womens Self- Help Groups

    in Andhra Pradesh, India, Paper presented at the XVI ISA World Congress of Sociology,

    Durban, South Africa, 23 29 July 2006.

    Patrinos, H. and Psacharopoulos, G. (1997) Family size, schooling and child labor in Peru:

    an empirical analysis,Journal of Population Economics, 10(4), 387405.

    Psacharopoulos, G. (1997) Child Labour Versus Educational Attainment: Some Evidence

    from Latin America,Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 10, 337 386.

    Rosati, F. and Rossi, M. (2003) Childrens Working Hours and School Enrolment:

    Evidence from Pakistan and Nicaragua, Working Paper No.25, Centre for International

    Studies on Economic Growth.

    Perry, G., Arias, O., Lpez, H., Maloney, W. and Servn, L.(2006) Poverty Reduction And

    Growth: Virtuous and Vicious Circles, Chapter 1, pp. 2 19, World Bank.

    Sedlacek, G., Duryea, S., Ilahi, N. and Sasaki, M. (2005) Child Labour, Schooling and

    Poverty in Latin America,Social Protection Discussion PaperNo. 0511, World Bank.

  • 8/10/2019 Children Time and Poverty

    18/18

    17

    UNDP (2006)Basic Facts About Microfinance, United Nations Capital Development Fund,http://www.uncdf.org/english/microfinance/facts.php

    UNICEF (2000) Poverty Reduction Begins with Children, March, New York: UNICEF.

    Woldehanna, T., Tefera, B., Jones, N. and Bayrau, A. (2005) Child labour, Gender

    Inequality and Rural/Urban disparities: How Can Ethiopias National DevelopmentStrategies Be Revised to Address Negative Spill-Over Impacts on Child Education and

    Wellbeing?, Young Lives Working PaperNo. 20, Young Lives: London.