Chapter11 Solutions

5
Solutions to the Review Questions at the End of Chapter 11 1. While the linear probability model (LPM) is simple to estimate and intuitive to interpret, it is fatally flawed as a method to deal with binary dependent variables. There are several problems that we may encounter: There is nothing in the model to ensure that the fitted probabilities will lie between zero and one. Even if we truncated the probabilities so that they take plausible values, this will still result in too many observations for which the estimated probabilities are exactly zero or one. It is simply not plausible to say that the probability of the event occurring is exactly zero or exactly one. Since the dependent variable only takes one of two values, for given (fixed in repeated samples) values of the explanatory variables, the disturbance term will also only take on one of two values. Hence the error term cannot plausibly be assumed to be normally distributed. Since the disturbances change systematically with the explanatory variables, they will also be heteroscedastic. 2. Both the logit and probit model approaches are able to overcome the limitation of the LPM that it can produce estimated probabilities that are negative or greater than one. They do this by using a function that effectively transforms the regression model so that the fitted values are bounded within the (0,1) interval. Visually, the 1/5 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2008

Transcript of Chapter11 Solutions

Page 1: Chapter11 Solutions

Solutions to the Review Questions at the End of Chapter 11

1. While the linear probability model (LPM) is simple to estimate and intuitive to interpret, it is fatally flawed as a method to deal with binary dependent variables. There are several problems that we may encounter:

There is nothing in the model to ensure that the fitted probabilities will lie between zero and one.

Even if we truncated the probabilities so that they take plausible values, this will still result in too many observations for which the estimated probabilities are exactly zero or one.

It is simply not plausible to say that the probability of the event occurring is exactly zero or exactly one.

Since the dependent variable only takes one of two values, for given (fixed in repeated samples) values of the explanatory variables, the disturbance term will also only take on one of two values. Hence the error term cannot plausibly be assumed to be normally distributed.

Since the disturbances change systematically with the explanatory variables, they will also be heteroscedastic.

2. Both the logit and probit model approaches are able to overcome the limitation of the LPM that it can produce estimated probabilities that are negative or greater than one. They do this by using a function that effectively transforms the regression model so that the fitted values are bounded within the (0,1) interval. Visually, the fitted regression model will appear as an S-shape rather than a straight line, as was the case for the LPM. The only difference between the two approaches is that under the logit approach, the cumulative logistic function is used to transform the model, so that the probabilities are bounded between zero and one. But with the probit model, the cumulative normal distribution is used instead. For the majority of the applications, the logit and probit models will give very similar characterisations of the data because the densities are very similar.

3.(a) When maximum likelihood is used as a technique to estimate limited dependent variable models, the general intuition is the same as for any other model: a log-likelihood function is formed and then the parameter values are taken to maximise it. The form

1/4 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2008

Page 2: Chapter11 Solutions

of this LLF will depend upon whether the logit or probit model is used; further technical details on the estimation are given in the appendix to Chapter 11.

(b) It is tempting, but incorrect, to state that a 1-unit increase in x2i, for example, causes a 2% increase in the probability that the outcome corresponding to yi = 1 will be realised. This would have been the correct interpretation for the linear probability model. But for logit and probit models, this interpretation would be incorrect because the form of the function is not Pi = 1 + 2xi + ui, for example, but rather Pi =F(x2i), where F represents the (non-linear) logistic or cumulative normal function. To obtain the required relationship between changes in x2i and Pi, we would need to differentiate F with respect to x2i and it turns out that this derivative is 2F(x2i). So in fact, a 1-unit increase in x2i will cause a 2F(x2i) increase in probability. Usually, these impacts of incremental changes in an explanatory variable are evaluated by setting each of them to their mean values.

(c) While it would be possible to calculate the values of the standard goodness of fit measures such as RSS, R2 or adjusted R2

for linear dependent variable models, these cease to have any real meaning. If calculated in the usual fashion, these will be misleading because the fitted values from the model can take on any value but the actual values will only be either 0 and 1. The model has effectively made the correct prediction if the predicted probability for a particular entity i is greater than the unconditional probability that y = 1, whereas R2 or adjusted R2 will not give the model full credit for this. Two goodness of fit measures that are commonly reported for limited dependent variable models are:

The percentage of yi values correctly predicted, defined as 100 times the number of observations predicted correctly divided by the total number of observations. Obviously, the higher this number, the better the fit of the model. Although this measure is intuitive and easy to calculate, Kennedy (2003) suggests that it is not ideal, since it is possible that a naïve predictor could do better than any model if the sample is unbalanced between 0 and 1. For example, suppose that yi

=1 for 80% of the observations. A simple rule that the prediction is always 1 is likely to outperform any more complex model on this measure but is unlikely to be very useful.

A measure known as ‘pseudo-R2’, defined as where LLF is the maximised value of the log-likelihood function for the logit or probit model and LLF0 is the value of the log-likelihood function for a restricted model where all of the slope parameters are set to zero (i.e. the model contains only an intercept). Since the likelihood is essentially a joint

2/4 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2008

Page 3: Chapter11 Solutions

probability, its value must be between zero and one, and therefore taking its logarithm to form the LLF must result in a negative number. Thus, as the model fit improves, LLF will become less negative and therefore pseudo-R2 will rise. This definition of pseudo-R2 is also known as McFadden’s R2.

(d) When there is more than one alternative outcome, but they are unordered, this is sometimes called a discrete choice or multiple choice problem. The models used are derived from the principles of utility maximisation – that is, the agent chooses the alternative that maximises his utility relative to the others. Econometrically, this is captured using a simple generalisation of the binary setup. When there were only 2 choices (0, 1), we required just one equation to capture the probability that one or the other would be chosen. If there are now, say, three alternatives, we would need two equations; for four alternatives, we would need three equations. In general, if there are m possible alternative choices, we need m-1 equations. The omitted equation then becomes a reference point, analogous to an omitted categorical dummy variable in a standard regression model, and the parameter interpretations need to be modified accordingly compared with the binary choice setup.

4. (a) The differences between censored and truncated variables are as follows. Censored data occur when the dependent variable has been ‘censored’ at certain point so that values above (or below) this cannot be observed. Even though the dependent variable is censored, the corresponding values of the independent variables are still observable. As an example, suppose that a privatisation IPO is heavily oversubscribed, and you were trying to model the demand for the shares using household income, age, education, and region of residence as explanatory variables. The number of shares allocated to each investor may have been capped at, say 250, resulting in a truncated distribution.

In this example, even though we are likely to have many share allocations at 250 and none above this figure, all of the observations on the independent variables are present and hence the dependent variable is censored, not truncated.

A truncated dependent variable, on the other hand, occurs when the observations for both the dependent and the independent variables are missing when the dependent variable is above (or below) a certain threshold. Thus the key difference from censored data is that we cannot observe the explanatory variables either, and so some observations are completely cut out or truncated from the sample.

For example, suppose that a bank were interested in determining the factors (such as age, occupation and income) that affected a customer's decision as to whether to undertake a transaction in a

3/4 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2008

Page 4: Chapter11 Solutions

branch or on-line. Suppose also that the bank tried to achieve this by encouraging clients to fill in an on-line questionnaire when they log on. There would be no data at all for those who opted to transact in person since they probably would not have even logged on to the bank's web-based system and so would not have the opportunity to complete the questionnaire. Thus, dealing with truncated data is really a sample selection problem because the sample of data that can be observed is not representative of the population of interest – the sample is biased, very likely resulting in biased and inconsistent parameter estimates. This is a common problem, which will result whenever data for buyers or users only can be observed while data for non-buyers or non-users cannot. Of course, it is possible, although unlikely, that the population of interest is focused only on those who use the internet for banking transactions, in which case there would be no problem.

4/4 “Introductory Econometrics for Finance” © Chris Brooks 2008