Chapter VI ANALYSIS OF THE COST AND RETURN ON PADDY...

48
Chapter VI ANALYSIS OF THE COST AND RETURN ON PADDY CULTIVATION Various operations and practices involved in paddy cultivation along with the problems faced by the farmers in the process of cultivation have all been discussed in the previous chapter. It is appropriate to study the cost of cultivation and the return on paddy so as to know the income earning capacity of the paddy farmers. The cost of cultivation varies according to the type of the farmers and even between the first and second crop. There may be variations in the cost of cultivation even between two different sample areas. This will have an impact on returns also. Hence an attempt is made to study the variation in the cost and to identify the causes for such variation. Cost of cultivation of any crop covers crop cost, labour cost, land cost, machinery cost and livestock cost. Crop cost refers to those costs incurred in the purchase of seeds and plants, manures and fertilizers, pesticides and insecticides and irrigation charges. Machinery cost includes the hire charges of machinery, fuel for machinery, electricity, minor repairs and interest charges on machineries.

Transcript of Chapter VI ANALYSIS OF THE COST AND RETURN ON PADDY...

  • Chapter VI

    ANALYSIS OF THE COST AND RETURN ON PADDY CULTIVATION

    Various operations and practices involved in paddy cultivation

    along with the problems faced by the farmers in the process of cultivation

    have all been discussed in the previous chapter. It is appropriate to study

    the cost of cultivation and the return on paddy so as to know the income

    earning capacity of the paddy farmers.

    The cost of cultivation varies according to the type of the farmers

    and even between the first and second crop. There may be variations in

    the cost of cultivation even between two different sample areas. This will

    have an impact on returns also. Hence an attempt is made to study the

    variation in the cost and to identify the causes for such variation.

    Cost of cultivation of any crop covers crop cost, labour cost, land

    cost, machinery cost and livestock cost. Crop cost refers to those costs

    incurred in the purchase of seeds and plants, manures and fertilizers,

    pesticides and insecticides and irrigation charges.

    Machinery cost includes the hire charges of machinery, fuel for

    machinery, electricity, minor repairs and interest charges on machineries.

  • 170 Labour cost covers the actual wages paid and the imputed value of family

    labour.

    Land cost includes rent paid to the land lord in the case of lease and

    national rent for owned lands. The livestock cost includes the cost of

    maintaining the livestock such as feed cost, fodder cost, cost of veterinary

    medicine and the interest on the value of livestock and depreciation.

    All these cost concepts discussed above cover both fixed as well as

    variable costs. Fixed costs are of non-recurring nature, while variable

    costs are of recurring types and have to be incurred in every production

    period variable costs are also known as operational cost or working cost.

    Fixed costs are those costs which are not a function output, hence

    they do not vary with the level of production land revenue, interest on

    capital for the use of fixed resources, contractual payments, such as rent

    and the value of services form fixed resources, contractual payments.

    Variable costs constitute the outlay of funds that are a function of

    output in a given production period i.e. they vary with level of output.

    Fixed costs are those costs which are independent of output, that is

    they do not change with changes in output. Fixed costs are also known as

    overhead cost and include charges such as contractual rent, insurance,

    property tax, interest on capital, etc. Thus fixed costs are those which are

    incurred in hiring the fixed factors of production and cannot be altered in

    the short run.

  • 171 Variable costs are those costs which are incurred on the

    employment of variable factors of production and can be altered in the

    short run. Thus the total variable costs change with changes in the output

    in the short run i.e. they increase or decrease when the output rises of falls.

    Thus, there are two views about the fixed cost.

    1. Fixed costs are non-recurring in nature.

    2. Fixed costs are those which do not change with the level of output.

    In the cultivation of short duration crops all costs are recurring in

    nature. Hence the first view is not usable for proper classification of fixed

    cost and variable cost. Therefore the second view is taken for classifying

    the cost into variable cost and fixed cost.

    Cultivation expenses for each activity have been collected from the

    farmers and they are classified as variable expenses and fixed expenses

    based on their impact on output.

    The average cost of cultivation is ascertained by dividing the total

    cost by the total area of land for each analysis.

    6.1. COST OF CULTIVATION OF PADDY

    Cost of cultivation is an important factor and it is the basis on

    which marketing decisions are made. A farmer whether big or small,

    prefers to sell his product in the market only when the market price covers

    the cost of production so as to leave a profit. So, the computation of cost

    of cultivation is paramount before analyzing the marketing behaviour of

  • 172 the farmers. Cost of cultivation of paddy in the study is analysed on the

    guide lines of Government of India,

    Estimation of cost has been done in the following manner

    1. Human labour, bullock labour and machine labour (hired) value at the

    actual rates paid by the farmer.

    2. Family labour-valued at the rate of wages paid for hired labour for

    similar work.

    3. Bullock labour and machine labour (owned) – valued at rates paid to

    hire the same.

    4. Seeds (purchased), insecticides and pesticides, manure (purchased),

    fertilizers, irrigation charges – valued at rates actually paid by the

    farmers.

    5. Seeds (farm produced), manure (owned) – valued at the prevailing

    market prices.

    6. Depreciation on implements – values at 20 per cent and apportioned

    in proportion to the value of output of paddy to the total value of

    output of all the crops of the year.

    7. Land revenue – actually paid by the farmer.

    8. Interest on working capital – valued at 12 per cent of half of the crop

    growth period.

    9. Imputed interest on owned fixed capital – valued at a rate of 10 per

    cent of the value of assets (excluding land) and apportioned in

    proportion to the value of output of paddy to the total value of out put

    of all the crops of the year.

    The components of cost given under ‘comprehensive scheme for

    studying the cost of cultivation of principal crops’ have been re-arranged

    so as to throw light on the variable cost and fixed cost. The classification

  • 173 of cost according to their behaviour into fixed and variable elements is

    very essential for profit planning, effective cost control and taking vital

    decisions as to the time and rate at which paddy is to be sold.

    6.1.1. Storage pattern

    Having seen that paddy is stored for better prices now, it is our turn

    to see the details regarding storage of paddy in the study area. Type of

    store houses, storage cost, etc. deserve attending to learn the economics of

    storage.

    6.1.2. Storage Facilities

    Adequate storage facilities help the farmers spread their sale over a

    period of time after harvesting. Farmers may generally store paddy either

    in their houses or houses of relatives or godowns run by the primary co-

    operative society or rural godowns run by market committees. But a

    surprising phenomenon observed is that all farmers stored their paddy

    only in their houses. Not a single farmer was found to make use of their

    relative’s houses, godowns of co-operative societies and market

    committees.

    6.1.3. Payments in kind and other retentions

    The payments in kind and other retentions at the farm level affect

    the level of marketable surplus. The payments and retentions are wages in

    kind to permanent labourers employed on the farm, kind wages paid to the

    casual labourers in harvesting paddy, customary payments to waterman,

    craftsman, Economically and socially backward people in the village,

    temples, etc. rent paid for leased – in land in which paddy is cultivated,

    interest payment for loan, irrigation charges for paddy land which depends

  • 174 on purchased water supply, paddy payments for relatives like old parents

    who reside separately, sisters, brothers and other close relatives who have

    no land / paddy land, seed for forthcoming sowing, wastages at the time of

    storing and transporting and deductions during the time of marketing.

    They make payments and retentions by varieties and seasons in each

    village. This is necessary to estimate the correct level of marketable

    surplus of paddy in different situations. Before presenting the level of

    such deductions at farm level, let us look at the nature and dimension of

    such payments in the study villages.

    6.1.4. Wage for permanent labourers

    Generally wage paid to permanent labourers is paddy and

    remaining in kind, particularly in paddy. These labourers hail from local

    and nearby villages and work from morning to evening in the farm.

    Owing to the workload and nature of work, they are paid paddy for

    consumption purpose. Usually, some of the marginal and small farmers in

    the delta villages have part-time permanent labourers only for irrigation of

    the paddy fields. They are doing watching and channelising water from

    canals to paddy fields. They are paid by fixed quantity of paddy for this

    service per season, generally, 5 bags per year.

    These labourers also do (simultaneously) the same work in other

    farmer’s field. In this area, a few farmers belonging to medium and large

    groups have regular permanent labourers in their farms. In this area

    labourers are paid generally in cash. One or two farmers pay the part of

    wages in kind, either as coarse cereals or as paddy. Only a small quantity

    of paddy, ranging from 3 to 4 bags, is involved in these transactions.

  • 175 6.1.5. Wage for casual labourers

    Wages for casual labourers in agriculture are generally paid in the

    form of cash for all agricultural activities. Only in the harvesting of paddy

    (complete kind) and groundnut (either cash or kind), wages are paid in

    kind. In a few areas, wage for harvesting of coarse cereals are paid in

    kind. Wage rate for paddy harvesting varies according to farm, season

    and village. The wage per person is fixed and it is four marakkals (one

    marakkal is equal to 4 kg). So bargaining is made only on the number of

    labourers for harvesting one acre or piece of land. Depending upon the

    demand for labourers and other factors, the number of labourers may vary

    between 30 and 35 persons per acre. Actually, the number of persons

    working and the number of persons agreed in the contract may differ. But

    wage paid for the number of persons working in the field may exceed or

    be lower than in the agreement. For analytical convenience, this type of

    wage rate is transformed into wage rate as in the other villages.

    The following are the major determinants of wage rate for

    harvesting paddy.

    i) distance between paddy field and kalam (threshing place).

    ii) demand for labourers at the time of harvest.

    iii) climatic conditions prevailing at the time of harvest.

    iv) expected yield from the piece of paddy land; and

    v) the size of landholding of the farmer.

    Greater the distance between paddy field and threshing place,

    higher is the wage rate, since the work requires more time and labour.

    Generally, paddy, sowing and harvesting in many areas take place within

    a limited time span. So, the demand for labourers is very high at certain

  • 176 periods and less in some other period, thus contributing to variation in

    wage rate. The climatic conditions prevailing at the time of harvest also

    influence the wage rate. If there is heavy rain, the farmers are forced to

    accept higher wage rate demanded by labourers so as to avoid crop

    spoilage. The expected yield of paddy also determines the wage rate. If

    the expected productivity is high in a piece of land, labourers accept to

    reduce the wage rate expressed as a share of output and vice versa.

    Finally, the large farmers have a group of casual labourers. Traditionally,

    this group works on such farms. Because of the regularity of

    employment, such casual labourers accept a somewhat lower level of

    wage rate than the rate prevailing in the area.

    6.1.6. Customer payments

    Customer payments are made to watchman, crafts man, dhobi,

    barber, economically and socially backward people in the village and to

    temples etc.,

    6.1.7. Loan repayment

    Farmers require loan for both agricultural and non-agricultural

    purpose. The loans obtained are generally repaid in cash. Sometimes, a

    few farmers belonging to marginal and small groups repay their loans in

    terms of paddy. There is a growing literature on interlinking in the case of

    food crops, because farmers need relatively small amount of loan and it is

    available from the business community of the same village who also have

    no agricultural land. They need paddy for consumption requirements and

    demand paddy as the mode of repayment of loan from the farmers.

  • 177 6.1.8. Interest payment

    As in the case of repayment of loan, we also see the payment of

    interest in the form of paddy.

    6.1.9. Irrigation charges

    Irrigation charges for water purchased for paddy cultivation from

    other farmers are also paid in the form of paddy. The irrigation charges

    very from farm to farm and taluk-to-taluk. It ranges from 5 to 6 bags per

    acre per season. But irrigation charges for crops other than paddy are paid

    in cash.

    6.1.10. Consumption of paddy

    Quantity taken for consumption from production is a major

    determinant of marketable surplus. Generally, paddy producing farmers

    meet their consumption requirements of rice from their own production of

    paddy. Some of the marginal and small farmers meet their consumption

    need mostly by allotting from production and the remaining by purchasing

    from open market and or government fair price shops. This is also

    practised among a few medium group farmers of non-delta region. But

    for a large proportion of medium farmers in the region, all the medium

    farmers in the delta region and all large farmers in the both regions meet

    their grain consumption needs entirely from own production. One or two

    farmers in the lower groups sold all their inferior variety of paddy and

    bought back superior variety of rice or such variety in paddy from other

    farmers or traders.

  • 178 6.1.11. Paddy for relatives

    Traditionally, farmers give rice with a certain amount of money to

    aged parents as Jeevanasam (like pension). A number of farmers give

    considerable quantity of paddy / rice to their close relatives like married

    sisters, brothers, etc. who have no paddy land / agricultural land and are

    engaged in non-agricultural occupations in near by places.

    6.1.12. Wastage and deductions

    Wastage and weight loss of paddy occur at the time of storage.

    Wastages happen by rats, pests, etc. The weightage loss occurs by the

    loss of moisture content of paddy while storing it. Apart from this,

    wastage occurs during the time of the transport of paddy from one place to

    another place. The weightage loss and other wastages are directly

    associated with quantum and period of storage. Another component

    determining the level of marketable surplus is deduction made by

    marketing authorities by means of taking samples (higher than the

    required quantity) and reduction for moisture content. This is illegal,

    because already the marketing authority offers a price for paddy according

    to moisture content in it. However, according to some of the farmers, if

    they protest, the weighman will over-report the moisture content and

    farmers will receive an even lower price.

    6.1.13. Receipts of paddy

    Like the payments and retentions, farmers receive paddy from

    different sources. The sources are wages received, land, collection of

    loan, collection of interest, irrigation charges, relatives and other sources.

  • 179 6.1.14. Wages

    A few family members of marginal and small groups may be

    working as agricultural labourers, either permanent or casual. They may

    receive paddy as wage. In this village, agricultural labourers belonging to

    marginal and small farm households earn paddy in this way.

    6.1.15. Loan and interest collection

    No one receives paddy as collection of loan or interest in both the

    seasons. This is because the farmers generally do not get loan for

    agricultural operations from private sources in cash. They are borrowing

    mostly from the co-operative society or commercial banks or acquire

    agricultural inputs on credits.

    6.1.16. Irrigation charges

    Farmers receive paddy as irrigation charges by selling water to near

    by field, which has no own well or canal water facilities.

    6.1.17. Marketable surplus of paddy

    The marketable surplus of paddy is defined as the surplus quantity

    available for sale from production after deducting all payments and

    retentions such as consumption, wage for permanent labourers, wage for

    harvesting, customary payments, rent for leased – in land, load repayment,

    interest payment, irrigation charges, paddy given to relatives, seed

    deductions and wastage.

    The primary data collected were analysed through well known

    statistical tools. The tools were selected for analysis on the basis of merit

    and weightage of each and every individual problem of the study

  • 180 concerned. The various tools which were used to analyse the data were,

    mean, medium, standard, deviation, Anova table, Duncan table and

    regression. The analysis of each table is given in terms of percentage.

    The descriptive findings and reasons are the same.

    6.1.18. Variety of paddy

    Varieties have been classified under two categories called common

    and fine. In Kuruvai and Thaladi season only these varieties are

    cultivated. Common varieties are IR-20, ADT-36, TKM-9, CO-43, CR-

    1009 and fine varieties are white Ponni and Katta Ponni.

  • 181

    TABLE 6.1 Variety of paddy cultivators – farm size

    Farm size

    ADT-36 IT-20

    TKM-9

    CO-43

    CR-1003

    White & Katta Ponni

    Maginal 27 67 --- --- --- ---

    Small 35 48 --- --- --- ---

    Medium 24 29 --- --- --- 06

    Large 20 13 07 07 14 03

    Total 20 (35.3)

    13 (52.3)

    07 (2.3)

    07 (2.3)

    14 (4.7)

    09 (3.0)

    Source: Primary data. Note: Figures in parentheses refer to percentage.

    From the above table we can understand the majority of the farmers

    in the study area. Cultivators of IR-20 numbered 157 out of the 300

    farmers followed by 106 farmers cultivating ADT-36. The lowest

    cultivating crop variety is TKM-9 and CO-43. This clearly slows that the

    IR-20 will give more profit than the other varieties, so the farmers give

    more importance to cultivating IR-20 and ADT-36 than other varieties.

  • 182 TABLE 6.2 Variety of paddy cultivation in the study area

    (no. of farmers)

    Study area ADT-36 IT-20TKM-

    9 CO-43

    CR-1003

    White and Katta Ponni

    Kumbakonam 33 66 --- --- --- 01

    Orathanadu 46 52 --- --- --- 02

    Papanasam 27 39 07 07 14 06

    Total 106 (35.3)

    157 (52.3)

    7 (2.3)

    7 (2.3)

    14 (4.7)

    09 (3.0)

    Source: Primary data. Note: Figures in parentheses refer to percentage.

    From the above table, one may find that Kumbakonam taluk,

    stands first having 66 farmers cultivating to IR-20 followed by 52 and 36

    farmers producing IR-20 variety. Further even in the ADT variety of

    paddy Orathanadu stands first having 46 farmers producing ADT-36

    followed by Kumbakonam and Orathanadu taluks with 33 and 27 farmers

    respectively.

  • 183 TABLE 6.3 Kuruvai production per acre – area wise

    (no. of farmers)

    Per acre Production Kumbakonam Orathanadu Papanasam Total

    20.00 --- --- 6 (100.00 ) 6

    (100.00 )

    21.00 6 (100.00 ) --- --- 6

    (100.00 )

    22.00 --- --- 6 (100.00 ) 6

    (100.00 )

    23.00 --- --- 7 (100.00 ) 7

    (100.00 )

    24.00 18 (34.6 ) 27

    (51.9 ) 7

    (13.5 ) 52

    (100.00 )

    25.00 38 (36.5 ) 34

    (32.7 ) 32

    (30.8 ) 104

    (100.00 )

    26.00 32 (37.2 ) 26

    (30.2 ) 28

    (32.6 ) 86

    (100.00 )

    27.00 6 (18.2 ) 13

    (39.4 ) 14

    (42.4 ) 33

    (100.00 )

    Total 100 (33.33) 100

    (33.33) 100

    (33.33) 300

    (100.00) Source: Primary data. Note: Figures in parentheses indicate percentage. It is perceived from the presented data that the highest is

    production at 59.7 per cent in Papanasam taluk with 32 bags of paddy and

    the lowest in Orathanadu at 18.9 per cent. This may be due to the high

    yielding cultivated land in Papanasam followed by Kumbakonam, further

    46.2 per cent and 53.8 per cent having the highest production of 37 bags

    per acre while Papanasam accounted for 100 per cent having production

    of 38 bags per acre and no other area exceeded production in Papanasam.

  • 184 TABLE 6.4 Thaladi production per acre – area wise

    (no. of farmers)

    Per acre Production Kumbakonam Orathanadu Papanasam Total

    32.00 18 (23.4) 13

    (16.9) 46

    (59.7) 77

    (100.00)

    33.00 7 (100.00) --- --- 7

    (100.00)

    34.00 19 (50.00) 19

    (50.00) --- 38

    (100.00)

    35.00 31 (36.50) 27

    (31.80) 27

    (31.80) 85

    (100.00)

    36.00 19 (26.00) 34

    (46.60) 29

    (24.40) 73

    (100.00)

    37.00 6 (46.20) 7

    (53.8) --- 13

    (100.00)

    38.00 --- --- 7 (100.00) 7

    (100.00)

    Total 100 (33.33) 100

    (33.33) 100

    (33.33) 300

    (100.00) Source: Primary data. Note: Figures in parentheses indicate percentage.

  • 185

    The Thaladi production shows the high production level found in

    almost all production areas from 20 bags to 27 bags in Papanasam and

    low productivity level in Kumbakonam taluk. Orathanadue stands second

    next to Papanasam in terms of productivity with 26 and 27 bags category,

    both Papanasam and Kumbakonam stand equal.

    Both the Kuruvai and Thaladi production were compared in the

    study areas. Kuruvai production is much higher than the Thaladi

    production. This is an example of marginal diminishing utility. When

    land is being used repeatedly, the production capacity of the land goes on

    decreasing.

  • 186 TABLE 6.5 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan Tables for average land

    holdings in the study area

    One ANOVA test is prepared to test whether the average land

    holding differs significantly among the three areas of study mainly

    Kumbakonam, Orathanadu and Papanasam taluks.

    Descriptive table 6.5(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviation Standard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 5.0300 2.9023 0.2902 4.4541 5.6059

    Orathanadu 100 6.6150 5.1394 0.5739 5.5952 7.6348

    Papanasam 100 5.0550 2.9905 0.2991 4.4616 5.6484

    Total 300 5.5667 3.379 0.2290 5.1259 6.0074

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    The above table gives the mean, standard deviation; standard error

    and 95 per cent confidence interval for mean are given for the three areas.

  • 187

    ANOVA table 6.5(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 184.662 2 62.441 5.649 0.004

    Within groups 4334.265 297 14.594

    Total 4499.167 299

    In the above ANOVA table as the significance value is 0.004

    which is less than 0.05, the average land holding differs significantly in

    the three sampled areas.

    Duncan table 6.5(c)

    Study area N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2

    Kumbakonam 100 5.0300

    Orathanadu 100 6.6150

    Papansam 100 5.0550

    Sig. .963 1.000

    From the Duncan table, we learn that Kumbakonam and

    Papanasam respondents on the average have 5 acres of land which

    indicates wet land and garden land while the Orathanadu respondents have

  • 188 on an average 6.6 acres which is significantly higher than the other two

    areas.

    TABLE 6.6 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan Tables for the average cost

    of Kuruvai season – area wise

    Descriptive table 6.6(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviation Standard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 4075.2954 1955.6289 195.5629 3687.2561 4463.334

    Orathanadu 100 3298.6286 380.0055 38.0005 3223.2273 33.74030

    Papanasam 100 3704.6020 1129.8976 112.9896 3480.4058 3928.798

    Total 300 3692.8420 1355.6416 78.2680 3538.8961 3846.867

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.6(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 3.0E + 07 2 1.5E+07 6.631 .000

    Within groups 5.2E + 08 297 1748519

    Total 5.6E + 08 299

  • 189

    Duncan table 6.6(c)

    Study area N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2 3

    Kumbakonam 100 3296.6288

    Orathanadu 100 3704.6020

    Papansam 100 4075.2954

    Sig. 1.000 1.000 1.000

    From the above table, we find that the average Kuruvai cost per

    acre in the study area in Papanasam taluk shows that the major mean cost

    is Rs.4075.29. This analysis has revealed the lower quality of land and

    the higher cost of manure. Kumbakonam taluk is the lowest among three

    study area with high quality of land and higher utilization of new

    technologies and manure. The cost wise analysis of Kuruvai is satisfactory

    in Kumbakonam when compared to the other two areas.

  • 190 TABLE 6.7 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan Tables for the average cost

    of Thaladi season – area wise

    Descriptive table 6.7(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviation Standard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 4279.0601 2053.4109 205.3410 3871.6190 4686.501

    Orathanadu 100 3463.5801 0399.0057 039.9006 3384.3987 3542.731

    Papanasam 100 4193.0931 1280.9053 128.0905 3938.9337 4447.252

    Total 300 3978.5711 1458.2029 084.1894 3812.8923 4144.248

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.7(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 4.0E + 07 2 2.02 + 07 10.11 .000

    Within groups 6.0E + 08 297 2005473

    Total 6.4E + 08 299

  • 191

    Duncan table 6.7(c)

    Study area N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2

    Kumbakonam 100 3463.5601

    Orathanadu 100 4190.0931

    Papansam 100 4279.0601

    Sig. 1.000 0.668

    From the above table, it can be noted that the expenses per acre

    show the differences in expenses incurred in different areas. The

    difference between the average expense in Papanasam and Orathanadu is

    almost equal but in Kumbakonam the cost per acre is the lowest.

    From the above analysis it is noteworthy to note that Thaladi leads

    with the lowest in terms of expenditure in cost per acre in Kuruvai

    compared to other areas.

  • 192 TABLE 6.8 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for the average

    Kuruvai cost – farm wise

    Descriptive table 6.8(a)

    Farm size N Mean

    Standard deviation

    Standard error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Marginal farmers 103 2939.7403 263.6452 25.9777 2888.2136 2991.2670

    Small farmers 94 3573.7066 516.1078 53.2325 3467.9975 3679.4145

    Medium farmers 66 4026.0168 605.4701 74.5282 3877.1736 4174.8599

    Large farmers 37 5497.6710 2916.4213 479.4667 4625.2878 6470.0543

    Total 300 3692.8420 1355.6416 78.2680 3538.8161 3846.867

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.8(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 1.9E + 08 3 6.3E + 07 51.149 .000

    Within groups 3.6E + 08 296 1222598

    Total 5.5E + 08 299

  • 193

    Duncan table 6.8(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2 3 4

    Marginal farmers 108 2989.7406

    Small farmers 94 8573.7086

    Medium farmers 66 4026.0168

    Large farmers 37 5497.6710

    Sig. 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

    The above table shows that most of the farmers in the study area

    are marginal farmers and their average expenditure is Rs.2989.74 per acre.

    And out of 300 farmers, in the study group, only 37 large farmers have got

    the mean of Rs.5498.67 per acre.

  • 194 TABLE 6.9 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for average Thaladi

    cost – farm wise

    Descriptive table 6.9(a)

    Farm size N Mean

    Standard deviation

    Standard error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Marginal farmers 103 3381.1555 884.9532 87.1970 3208.2006 3554.1104

    Small farmers 94 3752.3919 541.9132 55.8941 3641.3973 3863.3864

    Medium farmers 66 4227.3178 889.7436 78.2546 4071.0323 4383.6029

    Large farmers 37 5772.5546 3062.2424 503.4295 4751.5521 6793.5570

    Total 300 3978.5711 1458.2029 84.1894 3812.8923 4144.2499

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.9(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 1.6E + 08 3 5.5E + 07 34.506 .000

    Within groups 4.7E + 08 296 1591374

    Total 6.4E + 08 299

  • 195

    Duncan table 6.9(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2 3

    Marginal farmers 103 3381.1555

    Small farmers 94 3752.3919

    Medium farmers 66 4227.3176

    Large farmers 37 5772.5546

    Sig. 0.096 1.000 1.000

    From the above table, it has been observed that out of 300 farmers

    in the study area, 103 farmers form part of the marginal group having the

    average cost per acre with Rs.3381.15 and 37 large farmers have

    Rs.5572.55 as the average cost per acre.

    From the combined analysis of both the Kuruvai and Thaladi it can

    be understood that cost per acre for Thaladi is higher than Kuruvai cost

    due to increase in the variable cost per acre.

  • 196 TABLE 6.10 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for Kuruvai cost per

    bag – farm wise

    Descriptive table 6.10(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviation Standard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 118.6359 56.2865 5.6266 107.4714 129.800

    Orathanadu 100 123.0692 60.8859 6.0886 110.9889 135.159

    Papanasam 100 109.3651 33.9912 3.3991 102.6205 116.109

    Total 300 117.0234 51.8746 2.9950 111.1295 122.917

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.10(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 9780.120 2 4390.080 1.827 0.163

    Within groups 794812.2 297 2876.135

    Total 804592.3 299

  • 197

    Duncan table 6.10(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2 3 4

    Marginal farmers 103 83.5565

    Small farmers 94 104.9818

    Medium farmers 66 121.3870

    Large farmers 37 232.9971

    Sig. 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

    From the analysis of cost per bag of paddy production, it can be

    inferred that Papanasam stands the lowest among the other taluks with an

    average cost Rs.109 per bag followed by Kumbakonam with Rs.118 per

    bag, the highest being Orathanadu where the cost per bag comes to

    Rs.123/=. Further while analyzing the cost factor Papanasam is placed

    better than the other two study areas in terms of cost. The reason is due to

    qualitative cultivable land available in Papanasam compared to

    Orathanadu where only meagre area of quality land is available.

  • 198 TABLE 6.11 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for Thaladi cost per

    bag – area wise

    Descriptive table 6.11(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviationStandard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 172.2550 87.0685 8.7068 154.9787 189.532

    Orathanadu 100 177.9221 87.1093 8.7109 160.6372 196.206

    Papanasam 100 171.5709 60.0993 6.0099 159.8459 183.496

    Total 300 173.9160 78.9085 4.5558 164.9505 182.883

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.11(b)

    Land Sum of squares df Mean square F Significant

    Between groups 2430.755 2 1215.378 .194 .824

    Within groups 1859307 297 6260.291

    Total 1881737 299

  • 199

    Duncan table 6.11(c)

    Study area N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1

    Kumbakonam 100 171.5709

    Orathanadu 100 172.2550

    Papansam 100 177.9221

    Sig. .597

    The descriptive table shows that the Thaladi cost per bag is the lowest in

    Kumbakonam followed by Orathanadu and Papanasam and the cost being

    Rs.171, Rs.172 and Rs.177/= respectively in the three study areas.

    Further the comparative study of the cost analysis reveals that out of both

    Kuruvai and Thaladi seasons, the cost of cultivation is much lower for Kuruvai

    when compared to Thaladi crop cultivation. This is again due to diminishing

    marginal utility, where the repeated use of land increases the variable cost by

    putting more manures etc. However the fixed cost will remain the same.

  • 200 TABLE 6.12 Multiple linear regression for marginal farmers in Kuruvai

    season production per acre

    Taking Kuruvai profit per acre as the dependent variable and

    cultivation as variable cost, cultivation fixed cost, total no. of members in

    the family and Kuruvai production per acre as independent variables a

    multiple linear regression analysis is carried out. The results are given

    below

    Model summary table 6.12(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .9958 .990 .990 54.8173

    From the table R square equation is 0.990 which means that 99 per

    cent of the variability is explained in the dependent variable by the above

    said independent variable.

    Co-efficient table 6.12(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized

    co-efficients beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 14466.783 111.615 102.932 .000

    CUL-VCOS -4.78E-02 .22 -0.23 -2.172 .032

    CUL-FCOS .143 .049 .033 2.949 .004

    TNF -7.292 4.558 -0.019 -1.600 .133

    KUGR-PRO .436 .005 1.792 90.840 .000

  • 201 From the co-efficient table all the variables except TNF (Total

    number of family members) are having significant effect on the

    regression. Thus, the regression equation is obtained as

    Y = 11466.783 – 478E.02x1 + 0.143x2 + 0.436x3

    where, x1 is variable cost, x2 is cultivation fixed cost, and x3 Kuruvai

    cropped production.

    CUL-VCOS - Kuruvai cultivation variable cost.

    CUL-FCOS - Kuruvai cultivation fixed cost.

    KUGR-PRO - Kuruvai crop production per acre.

    TNF - Total number of members in the family.

  • 202 TABLE 6.13 Multiple linear regression for small farmers in Kuruvai

    production per acre

    Model summary table 6.13(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .9958 .993 .992 62.7092

    The table indicates R square is 0.992 which means that 99 per cent

    of the variability is explained in the dependent variable by the above said

    independent variable.

    Co-efficient table 6.13(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 11027.860 176.984 62.682 .000

    CUL-VCOS -4.14E-02 .57 -0.012 -0.732 .486

    CUL-FCOS 2.603E-02 .012 .035 2.213 .029

    TNF 4.375 7.363 .006 0.594 0.554

    KUGR-PRO 0.214 0.002 2.863 88.549 0.000

    In the co-efficient table, it can be noted that all the variables except

    TNF (Total number of members in the family) have significant effect on

    regression. Thus the regression equation is obtained as

    Y = 11027.860 – 4.14E-02x1 + 2.603E-02x2 + 0.214x3

    where, x1 is variable cost of cultivation, x2 is fixed cost of cultivation and

    x3 is production of an acre of Kuruvai crop.

  • 203 TABLE 6.14 Multiple linear regression for medium farmers in Kuruvai

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.14(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .9958 .991 .990 61.0557

    From the table it can be observed that R square equation is 0.990

    which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained in the

    dependent variable by the above said independent variable.

    Co-efficient table 6.14(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 9077.875 425.744 21.322 .000

    CUL-VCOS .440 .142 .046 3.092 .003

    CUL-FCOS -5.43E-02 .012 .069 -4.631 .000

    TNF -10.109 10.813 -0.013 0.935 0.054

    KUGR-PRO 0.149 0.008 3.108 49.457 0.000 It is perceived from the co-efficient table that all the variables

    except TNF (Total number of members in the family) are having

    significant effect on the regression.

    Thus the regression equation is obtained as

    Y = 9077.875 + 0.440x1 – 5.43E.02x2 + 0.149x3

    where x1 shares the variable cost of cultivation,

    x2 shares the fixed cost of cultivation.

    x3 shares the Kuruvai crop production per acre.

  • 204 TABLE 6.15 Multiple linear regression for large farmers in Kuruvai

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.15(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .992R .984 .992 42.7490

    It can be seen from the above table that R square equation is 0.992

    which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained in the

    dependent variable by the above said independent variable.

    Co-efficient table 6.15(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant -10348.1 1513.870 -6.836 .000

    CUL-VCOS 8.272 .536 1.881 15.432 .000

    CUL-FCOS 1.793 .095 1.400 18.933 .000

    TNF -981.748 39.265 -2.904 -25.003 .000

    KUGR-PRO -6.69E-02 .003 -3.136 -19.412 .000

  • 205 TABLE 6.16 Multiple linear regression for marginal farmers in Thaladi

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.16(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .6958 .483 .456 325.1857

    Co-efficient table 6.16(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 8592.361 630.603 13.626 .000

    TNF 112.932 26.206 .385 4.691 .000

    KUGR-PRO -4.25E-02 .019 -0.213 -2.251 .027

    THA-VCOS .199 .120 .123 1.553 .124

    THA-FCOS -2.488 .292 -0.706 -8.532 .000

    It can be seen from the table presented that R square equation is

    0.456 which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained in the

    dependent variable by the model summary of the independent variables.

    And co-efficient table of all the variables except TNF (Total number of

    members in the family) are having significant effect on the regression.

    Thus, the regression equation is obtained as

    Y = 8592.361 + 0.199x1 – 2.488x2 – 4.25E.02x3

    where x1 is cultivation variable cost, x2 cultivation fixed cost and x3

    Thaladi crop production per acre.

  • 206 TABLE 6.17 Multiple linear regression for small farmers in Thaladi

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.17(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .5238 .273 .232 267.8606

    Co-efficient table 6.17(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 5910.034 751.496 7.731 .000

    TNF -66.361 31.499 -0.200 -2.110 .038

    KUGR-PRO 1.223E-03 .10 .038 .119 .906

    THA-VCOS .666 .230 .476 2.894 .005

    THA-FCOS -0.219 .050 -0.698 -4.364 .000

    From the table, it is important to note that R square equation is

    0.232 which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained in the

    dependent variable by the above said independent variable. And from co-

    efficient table we note all the variables except TNF (Total number of

    members in the family) are having significant effect on regression which

    is obtained as

    Y = 5910.034 + 0.666x1 – 0.219x2 + 1.223E-03x3

  • 207 TABLE 6.18 Multiple linear regression for medium farmers in Thaladi

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.18(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .9188 .643 .830 235.9172

    Co-efficient table 6.18(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant 23489.937 1645.062 14.279 .000

    TNF -95.066 41.780 -0.131 -2.275 .026

    KUGR-PRO .152 .012 3.407 13.026 .000

    THA-VCOS -4.837 .524 -0.545 -8.858 .000

    THA-FCOS .163 .045 .223 3.589 .001

    From the above table, it may be observed that R square equation is

    0.830 which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained. And

    from the co-efficient table, it can be noted that all the variables except

    TNF (Total number of members in the family) are having significant

    effect on equation which is obtained as

    Y = 23489.937 - 4.837x1 + 0.163x2 + 0.152x3

  • 208 TABLE 6.19 Multiple linear regression for large farmers in Thaladi

    season production per acre

    Model summary table 6.19(a)

    Model R R square Adjusted R

    square Standard error of the

    estimate

    1 .9748 .948 .942 115.5334

    Co-efficient table 6.19(b)

    Model

    Unstandardized co-efficients Standardized co-efficients

    beta t Sig.

    Std. error

    Constant -63421.5 3458.384 -18.349 .000

    TNF -1147.498 73.323 -2.272 -15.650 .000

    THA-VCOS 22.867 1.141 3.622 19.870 .000

    THA-FCOS 3.297 .201 1.723 16.363 .000

    It can be deducted from the table presented that R square equation

    is 0.942 which means that 99 per cent of the variability is explained. And

    from the co-efficient table, if any may be noted that are the variables

    except TNF are having significant effect on equation which obtained as

    Y = 63421.5 = 22.867x1 + 3.297x2 + 110.583x3

  • 209 TABLE 6.20 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan Tables for marketable

    surplus in Kuruvai season – area wise

    Descriptive table 6.20(a)

    Study area N Mean Standard deviationStandard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 29.0572 6.2590 .6258 27.8154 30.293

    Orathanadu 100 29.0703 7.9448 .7945 27.4939 30.649

    Papanasam 100 28.7816 5.2759 .5276 27.7347 29.829

    Total 300 -

    28.9697 5.6652 .9790 28.2236 29.771

    Source: Calculated on the basis of the data collected during the field work.

    ANOVA table 6.20(b)

    Land Sum of squares df Mean square F Significant

    Between groups 5.317 2 2.858 .061 .941

    Within groups 12882.078 297 43.374

    Total 12887.394 299

    Source: Computed from primary data

  • 210

    Duncan table 6.20(c)

    Study area N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1

    Kumbakonam 100 28.7816

    Orathanadu 100 29.0572

    Papansam 100 29.0703

    Sig. .773

    Source: Computed from primary data.

    It can be seen from the table that the marketable surplus can be

    defined as the excess of the samples over total retention. The descriptive

    analysis of the table shows that all the three study areas show almost equal

    amount of samples with little difference between Kumbakonam and other

    study area. An average of 29 bags per acre is marketable surplus in all the

    three areas.

  • 211 TABLE 6.21 Descriptive, Anova tables for Thaladi season profit per

    acre– farm wise

    Descriptive table 6.21(a)

    Farm size N Mean

    Standard deviation

    Standard error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Marginal

    farmers 103 7225.1845 440.9600 43.4491 7139.0034 7311.3655

    Small

    farmers 94 7206.2128 305.6528 31.5257 7143.6090 7266.6155

    Medium

    farmers 66 6609.0909 571.5922 70.3581 8468.5760 8749.8058

    Large

    farmers 37 6858.1351 479.3889 78.8110 6698.2989 7-17.9713

    Total 300 7038.4800 509.5706 29.4201 6980.5384 7096.3266

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

    ANOVA table 6.21(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 2.0E + 07 3 6535734 33.337 .000

    Within groups 5.6E + 07 296 196053.4

    Total 7.8E + 07 299

  • 212

    Duncan table 6.21(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2 3

    Marginal farmers 66 6609.0909

    Small farmers 37 6858.1351

    Medium farmers 94 7206.2128

    Large farmers 103 7225.1845

    Sig. 1.000 1.000 .809

    Source: Computed from primary data.

    From the table on profitability it may be observed that out of the

    300 farmers in the study area, the average profit of marginal farmer is

    only Rs.7225.18 per acre and whose number is 103 compared to the

    average profit of Rs.7038.48 per acre for the 300 farmers. However from

    the combined analysis of 60th Kuruvai and Thaladi one may find that the

    average profit is much higher in Kuruvai cultivation than in Thaladi. This

    is due to the low yielding quality of the land. Further the marginal

    farmers are earning less amount of profit both in Kuruvai and Thaladi

    cultivation.

  • 213 TABLE 6.22 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for average net profit

    per acre – farm wise (per year)

    Descriptive table 6.22(a)

    Farm size N Mean

    Standard deviation

    Standard error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Marginal farmers 103 18515.83 788.9378 77.7364 18361.65 18670.02

    Small farmers 94 18361.30 726.2723 74.9093 18212.54 18510.05

    Medium farmers 66 17350.84 1012.8582 124.8740 17101.85 17509.63

    Large farmers 37 18241.92 522.2607 85.8591 18067.79 18416.05

    Total 300 18177.29 918.0916 52.7174 18079.54 1828.08

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

    ANOVA table 6.22(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 6.0E + 07 3 2.0E + 07 31.413 .000

    Within groups 1.9E + 08 296 638659.6

    Total 2.5E + 08 299

  • 214

    Duncan table 6.22(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2

    Marginal farmers 66 17350.64

    Small farmers 94 16241.92

    Medium farmers 94 18361.30

    Large farmers 103 18515.83

    Sig. 1.000 .066

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

    The table indicates that the combined analysis of net profit per year

    both in Kuruvai and Thaladi is about Rs.18,177/= per acre among 300

    farmers in the sample study area, the highest being Rs.18,515/= and the

    lowest being of Rs.17,350/= per acre for the medium level farmers. The

    higher profit for marginal farmers is due to lesser amount of the labour

    cost.

  • 215 TABLE 6.23 Descriptive, Anova and Duncan tables for average net profit

    per acre – area wise (per year)

    Descriptive table 6.23(a)

    Area code N Mean Standard deviation Standard

    error

    95% confidence interval for mean

    Lower bound

    Upper bound

    Kumbakonam 100 18243.36 969.0725 98.9072 18051.09 18435.87

    Orathanadu 100 18327.09 579.7715 51.9772 1822.96 18430.22

    Papanasam 100 17961.39 1111.1372 111.1137 17740.92 18181.86

    Total 300 18177.29 918.0916 52.7174 18073.54 18281.03

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

    ANOVA table 6.23(b)

    Land Sum of

    squares df

    Mean

    square F Significant

    Between groups 7342074 2 3871037 4.506 .012

    Within groups 2.4E + 08 297 614629.9

    Total 2.5E + 08 299

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

  • 216

    Duncan table 6.23(c)

    Farm size N Subset for alpha = 0.5

    1 2

    Kumbakonam 100 17961.39

    Orathanadu 100 19240.38

    Papanasam 100 18327.09

    Sig. 1.000 .512

    Source: Calculated from primary data.

    From analysis of net profit per acre, table it can be understood that

    Kumbakonam stands the lowest among the other taluks with net profit

    Rs.17,961/= per year followed by Orathanadu Rs.19,240/= the highest

    being Papanasam where the net profit comes to Rs.18,327/=. Further

    while analyzing the net profit Papanasam is placed better than the other

    two study area.