Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar...

45
Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President, CRA International University Club of Chicago June 5, 2007

Transcript of Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar...

Page 1: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation:

Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters

Presentation by Steven J. DavisVice President, CRA International

University Club of ChicagoJune 5, 2007

Page 2: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Outline

I. Thrift Industry Insolvencies and Response

II. The Winstar-Related Cases

III. On Damages in Breach of Contract

IV. Assessing Damage Outcomes in the Winstar Matters

V. Some Lessons

Page 3: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

I. Thrift Industry Insolvencies and Response

Page 4: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

The S&L Industry in the 1980s• Historically, Savings and Loan Institutions (S&Ls) pooled

small savings and time deposits and used the proceeds to fund long term, fixed-rate mortgages.

• Most S&Ls became insolvent during the 1980s.• Initial wave of insolvencies caused by historically high interest

rates in the late 1970s and early 1980s. As interest rates rose,– The value of S&L loan portfolios fell dramatically– Spreads between return on assets and cost of funds turned negative.

• Later insolvencies caused by a combination of – Unwise regulatory reforms – Lax oversight by government officials – Fraud, mismanagement and excessive risk taking

• The scale of the insolvencies vastly exceeded the reserves of the Government’s deposit insurance fund (FSLIC).

Page 5: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Supervisory Mergers• The government encouraged “supervisory mergers” to prevent

the collapse of failing S&Ls and reduce demands on FSLIC.• To facilitate takeovers of failing S&Ls by stronger institutions,

the Government relied on cash infusions and several other inducements:– Opportunity for acquirer to circumvent restrictions on

branch banking and interstate banking– Relaxation of certain rules re loan portfolios– Assurance of continued forbearance w.r.t. capital

requirements of acquirer– Use of “supervisory goodwill” to meet regulatory

capital requirements– Other capital credits and allowances– Special tax breaks

Page 6: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Supervisory Goodwill

• Under the “purchase method of accounting”, the excess of liabilities over assets in the acquired institution is designated as “supervisory goodwill” and treated as a form of intangible capital.

• The goodwill created in this manner had an amortization horizon as long as 40 years.

• Supervisory goodwill counted towards the regulatory capital requirements of the merged institution.

• Effectively, the government allowed the negative net worth of the acquired institution to substitute for actual capital for the purpose of meeting regulatory capital requirements.

Page 7: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Example: Creating Supervisory Goodwill

• Failing S&L has $250 million in assets and $300 million in liabilities net worth of -$50 million.

• When acquired, this excess of liabilities over assets in the failing S&L becomes “supervisory goodwill” in the merged institution.– See charts below for details and a comparison of alternative

methods to account for the acquisition.

• With a 5% capital requirement, each dollar of capital can support $20 of loans.

• So, in this example, supervisory goodwill can support an extra $1 billion in loans (20 X $50 million).

• Note: The government deposit insurance system greatly increased the feasibility and attractiveness of this strategy for poorly capitalized S&Ls.

Page 8: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Mortgage Loans 450$ Deposits 400$ Other Tangible Assets 150$ Other Liabilities 170$

Owners' Equity 30$ Total Assets 600$ Total Liabilities and Equity 600$

Mortgage Loans 200$ Deposits 200$ Other Tangible Assets 50$ Other Liabilities 100$

Owners' Equity (50)$ Total Assets 250$ Total Liabilities and Equity 250$

CAPITAL RATIO = (30/600) = 5%

CAPITAL RATIO = (-50/250) = -20%

Balance Sheet of a "Weak" S&L

Assets Liabilities and Equity

Assets Liabilities and Equity

Balance Sheet of a "Strong" S&L (Acquirer)

Page 9: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Capital Ratio = Capital / Assets Leverage Ratio = Assets / Capital Debt / Equity Ratio = Debt / Equity

Tangible Assets of "Strong" 600$ Deposits and Other Liabilities of "Strong" 570$ Tangible Assets of "Weak" 250$ Deposits and Other Liabilities of "Weak" 300$

Owners' Equity in the merged S&L (20)$

Total Assets 850$ Total Liabilities and Equity 850$

Tangible Assets of "Strong" 600$ Deposits and Other Liabilities of "Strong" 570$ Tangible Assets of "Weak" 250$ Deposits and Other Liabilities of "Weak" 300$ Subtotal 850$ Subtotal 870$

Supervisory Goodwill 50$ Owners' equity in the merged S&L 30$

Total Assets 900$ Total Liabilities and Equity 900$

CAPITAL RATIO = 3.5%

Balance Sheet After Merger of "Strong" and "Weak" S&LsUsing the Purchase Method of Accounting

Assets Liabilities and Equity

CAPITAL RATIO = -2.3%

Balance Sheet After Merger of "Strong" and "Weak" S&LsUsing the Pooling of Interests Method of Accounting

Assets Liabilities and Equity

Page 10: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

FIRREA (1989)• The Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and

Enforcement Act (FIRREA) and its implementing regulations introduced three types of capital requirements: – Tangible capital (could not be met by goodwill)– Core capital, which permitted limited amounts of

“qualifying supervisory goodwill”– Risk-based capital, a percentage of risk-weighted assets

• FIRREA also mandated a rapid phase-out of supervisory goodwill and required thrifts to exit the real estate development business.

• Guarini amendment in 1993 disallowed certain tax deductions promised in some supervisory mergers.

Page 11: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

FIRREA (1989)

• For our purposes, the chief features of FIRREA are the greatly accelerated amortization of supervisory goodwill and the strict requirements for uniform application of regulatory capital standards (i.e., no further discretionary forbearance by the regulatory authorities).

• Roughly $10 billion in “qualifying goodwill” became subject to rapid phase out due to FIRREA and implementing regulations.

• Almost immediately, 500 S&Ls fell out of compliance with regulatory capital standards.

Page 12: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

II. The Winstar-Related Cases

Page 13: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

The “Winstar” Matters• 130+ cases with related fact patterns filed in the

U.S. Court of Federal Claims during the 1990s.• Common elements:

– In the course of supervisory mergers in 1980s, the Government allegedly entered into regulatory contracts re the treatment of supervisory goodwill, other capital credits and forbearance with respect to capital requirements.

– The contracts were allegedly breached by FIRREA and its implementing regulations (or by the 1993 Guarini amendment to FIRREA.)

• Huge potential liability for Government: Estimated damages of $20-30 billion or more as of 1998-99 plus $200 million in litigation costs.

Page 14: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Number of Winstar-Related Cases Initiated by Quarter, 1990-1999

Q4 1995 24 cases

Q3 1995 44 cases

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50N

umbe

r of c

ases

Sources: List of Winstar cases from USCFC; http://www.uscfc.uscourts.gov/winstar.htm; United States Reports, Volume 518, Cases Adjudged in the Supreme Court at October Term, 1995.

October 1995: Supreme Court grants writ of certioari to hear the Winstar case.

Page 15: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

US v. Winstar et al. (1996)

• The Supreme Court ruled that:– The United States entered into contracts during

the 1980s that allowed special accounting methods in the acquisition of certain failing S&Ls.

– The new capital requirements mandated by FIRREA (1989), as applied to the acquiring institutions, breached the terms of the contracts.

– The Government is liable for damages in breach of contract.

• The Supreme Court remanded to the Court of Federal Claims for determination of damages.

Page 16: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Early Outcomes on Damages

• August 1998: initial judgment of $2.8 million against the government in Winstar.

• April 1999: initial judgment of $909 million against the government in Glendale Federal Bank vs. The United States, the second Winstar-related case tried on damages.– As of June 1989, shortly before the enactment of

FIRREA, Glendale had about $550 million of unamortized supervisory goodwill.

– Thus, Glendale seemed to confirm concerns about huge government exposure in Winstar-related cases.

Page 17: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Glendale Federal Bank v. US• Bench trial lasted 14 months

– 150+ days of testimony, 20,000 pages of trial transcripts– $100 million in litigation costs, per rough estimate of trial court judge

• Judgment of $909 million for plaintiffs:– $528 million for restitution of “benefits conferred on government”– $381 million for non-overlapping (post-breach) reliance damages

• The court calculated restitution as the excess of liabilities over assets in the failing institution at acquisition, less the value of (certain) benefits that Glendale received from the contract.

• Reliance damages were awarded mainly for “wounded bank damages” – the argument being that Glendale lost an historic advantage in its cost of funds because the breach forced Glendale out of capital compliance.

• The restitution award did not survive appeal, because the value of the benefits conferred on the government are “both speculative and indeterminate.”

Page 18: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

The Complexity of Damages Determination

“The court recognizes that damages, particularly involving a thrift that entered a 40-year contract 18 years ago, which was breached nearly ten years ago, necessarily is not going to be found with the precision that one could determine damages resulting from the breach of a smaller, more discrete contract.” [Trial court opinion in Glendale Federal v. United States, 43 Fed. Cl., at 399 (1999)]

Page 19: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Courts’ Attitude Toward Expectation Damages in Winstar Matters

• “The complexity, breadth and length of the contract which was breached make it difficult to award expectancy damages, … which the court believes would be most consistent with the very purpose of contract law. The difficulty, as plaintiff’s model demonstrates, is the bank is operating in a dynamic market, making dynamic decisions, and responding to millions of stimuli in order to run a profitable enterprise.” [Trial court opinion in California Federal Bank, 43 Fed. Cl., at 404 (1999)]

• “Expectation damages are difficult or impossible to prove due to the length of time which has elapsed since the breach of contract occurred and the fact that many of these thrifts were closed at the hands of federal regulators as a result of breach.” [Watson (1999), summarizing court’s view in several Winstar matters]

Page 20: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

III. On Damages in Breach of Contract

Page 21: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Goal of Contract Law• From the perspective of economic efficiency, the

goal of contract law is to maximize social welfare.– Focus is usually on parties to the contract.– In which case, efficiency boils down to maximizing the

(expected) joint value of the contractual relationship to the parties.

• Legal rules regarding- Contract formation - Interpretation- Enforcement - Holdup- Breach - Mitigation- Remedies and damagesall affect the efficiency of contractual relationships.

Page 22: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Damage Measures

• Damage measure: A rule or formula that governs what a party in breach should pay to the non-breaching party.

• Damage measures affect the efficiency of contractual relationships in several ways:– Incentives to perform– Incentives to take actions in reliance on the contract– Incentives to mitigate losses in the event of breach– Cost of writing contracts– Incentives to renegotiate– Opportunities to allocate risks – Incentives to seek and form contractual relationships

Page 23: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Expectation Damages

• Expectation damages compensate the injured party for the harm caused by the breach. They equal the value of performance to the non-breaching party.

• Usually the preferred remedy from an economic perspective, because expectation damages provide the proper incentive for efficient performance (and efficient breach).

• In practice, expectation damages can be hard or easy to calculate, depending on circumstances.

Page 24: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Example: Efficient Performance• A buyer wants to acquire a

machine that he values at 50.• A seller’s cost of producing the

machine is uncertain at the contract date – see table.

• A mutually optimal complete contract calls for delivery only when the cost turns out to be less than 50, which occurs with probability 0.8 in this example.

• That is, an optimal contract allows for non-performance when the cost of performance exceeds the value of performance.

Cost Probability

10 (low) 30%

30 (mid) 50%

100 (high) 20%

The (expected) joint value of a contract that calls for performance in all states is (.3)(50-10) + (.5)(50-30) + (.2)(50-100) = 12 +10 – 10 = 12

The joint value of the optimal contract is 12 + 10 = 22.

Page 25: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Example Continued: Hypothetical Incomplete Contract

• Hypothetical contract: The manufacturer agrees to produce and deliver the machine in return for a payment of 40. The contract contains no provisions for non-performance or damages in the event of breach.

• How should the law deal with breach?– Requiring specific performance in all circumstances

yields a joint value of 12. – High damages, 50 or more, lead to performance in

all states and, hence, a joint value of 12.– Lower damages, less than 50, lead to (efficient)

breach under high costs, yielding a joint value of 22.

Page 26: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Example Continued: Expectation Damages and Efficient Performance

• Expectation damages yield efficient performance:– The value of performance to the non-breaching party is

50 – 40 = 10. This is the harm to the buyer if the seller breaches.

– Setting damages to 10 yields performance under low and mid costs but not under high costs, replicating the efficient outcome.

• Expectation damages continue to provide the proper incentive to perform in richer examples (continuum of possible costs) and in broader circumstances (uncertainty about seller costs and buyer values).– Damages above the expectation level yield too little breach.– Damages below the expectation level yield too much breach.

Page 27: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Expectation Damages and Mitigation

• An efficient damage measure provides incentives to mitigate harm caused by breach when the resulting savings exceed the cost of mitigation. A proper measure of expectation damages takes this point into account:– Expectation damages (reformulated):

(Expected) losses that would be sustained by the non-breaching party had he optimally mitigated – whether or not he actually did so – plus the costs of optimal mitigation.

– This damage measure deters inefficient breach and encourages cost-saving mitigation.

Page 28: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

• “The general rule of a non-breaching party’s responsibility for mitigation is that ‘damages are not recoverable for loss that the injured party could have avoided without undue risk, burden or humiliation.” [Restatement (Second) of Contracts, Section 350 (1) (1979), as quote in Commercial Fed v. U.S., 22 January 2004] “Further, ‘[a]s a general rule, a party cannot recover damages for loss that he could have avoided by reasonable efforts.’”

Page 29: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Expectation Damages and Reliance• Under certain conditions, expectation damages

mimic the outcomes of a completely specified contract that is mutually preferred by the parties (at contract formation). In this limited but important respect, expectation damages are optimal from an efficiency perspective.

• Expectation damages provide strong, but imperfect, incentives to take actions in reliance on the contract.

– E.g., expectation damages can induce excessive expenditures in reliance on performance, because the non-breaching party receives the value of full performance even when breach is efficient.

• Neither expectation damages nor any other simple, practical damage measure achieves optimality in all circumstances.

Page 30: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Restitution

• “When proof of expectancy damages fails, the law provides a fall-back position for the injured party – he can sue for restitution. The idea behind restitution is to restore – that is, to restore the non-breaching party to the position he would have been in had there never been any contract to breach. …In other words, the objective is to restore the parties to the status quo ante.” [Quoting from the 9th Circuit opinion in Glendale, 16 December 2001, emphasis added.]

Page 31: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Reliance Damages

• The purpose of reliance damages is to place the injured party “in as good a position as he would have been in had the contract not been made.” [Restatement (Second) of Contracts]

• Unlike restitution, reliance damages include “expenditures made in preparation for performance or in performance, less any loss that the party in breach can prove with reasonable certainty the injured party would have suffered had the contract been performed.”

• The comments to the Restatement point out that restitution may be equal to the reliance interest, but ordinarily restitution is smaller because it does not include “expenditures in reliance that result in no benefit to the other party.”

Page 32: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Reliance vs. Expectation Damages

• It is often said that reliance damages are less than expectation damages, “because it would be irrational for a contracting party to plan to spend more on reliance than performance is worth; otherwise, the contract would have negative worth to the party spending on reliance.”

• This logic is correct but easily misapplied when – as in the Winstar matters – the breach occurs years after contract formation.– When breach occurs long after contract formation, the

value of remaining performance can be much smaller than the value of performance already delivered.

– Hence, reliance damages can greatly exceed expectation damages (i.e., the value of remaining performance).

Page 33: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

IV. Assessing Damage Outcomes in the Winstar Matters

Page 34: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

How Did the Breach Affect Plaintiffs?

• FIRREA greatly shortened the time period over which supervisory goodwill could be counted towards regulatory capital requirements. It also eliminated certain other capital credits created in supervisory mergers.

• As a result, many S&Ls fell out of compliance with regulatory capital standards.

• Non-complying S&Ls had three main options:– Shrink liabilities and assets to achieve compliance– Re-capitalize to achieve compliance (or cut dividends)– Exit

Page 35: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Analyses of Lost Profits, Use Value, etc., in the Winstar Matters

An expectancy approach, yes, but in practice, one with several problems:

• Highly speculative, not subject to any ready source of discipline

• Difficult issues of causation• Keenly susceptible to hindsight bias and undue

optimism by plaintiffs re returns on their but-for investment strategies

• Lost profits analyses also tended to ignore or downplay opportunities for plaintiffs to mitigate the cost of breach.

Page 36: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Estimating Expectation Damages Caused by Lost Supervisory Goodwill

• Key economic insight: The cost of re-capitalizing is an upper bound for the harm to shareholders caused by the breach.

• Why? – S&L need not forego good investment opportunities because

of reduced scope for leverage caused by the breach. – Instead, it can raise whatever additional capital it needs to

preserve such valuable opportunities.– Could S&Ls, in fact, access capital markets? Yes. – S&Ls that did not raise new capital (or reduce dividends) to

restore compliance presumably concluded that the costs of raising capital exceeded the net value of the foregone opportunities.

Page 37: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Could Thrifts Raise Capital in the Wake of FIRREA?

• “Between the end of 1989 and the end of 1993, there were nearly 500 equity and debt offerings by thrifts and thrift holding companies with total amounts of between $250 million and $1.3 billion per quarter.” [Expert Report of Jonathan Arnold and Steven Davis in Southern National Corp. vs. United States]– In total, the industry raised more than $15 billion in capital

during the period. (In comparison, recall that FIRREA affected about $10 billion in qualifying goodwill.)

– Thrifts in every region of the country raised capital during this period.

– Some capital-raising thrifts had supervisory goodwill on the books at the time of FIRREA’s enactment, some did not.

Page 38: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Costs of Re-Capitalizing• Flotation costs (direct cost of issuing new equity):

– Registration fees– Management and underwriting fees– Cost of legal and accounting services– Other direct expenses

• Adverse information effects on equity price– A potentially relevant factor when “insiders” with private

information determine timing and amount of equity issue.– Not very relevant when the fact and timing of equity issue

are compelled by external forces.– Of doubtful relevance anyway in a heavily regulated

industry subject to routine examinations and compulsory disclosure of detailed financial information.

• Wealth transfers from S&L stockholders to debt holders and other creditors – including the government deposit insurance fund.

Page 39: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Cost of Recapitalizing: Advantages as a Measure of Damages

• Promotes efficient contractual relationships– Proper incentive to perform– Proper incentive to mitigate– Strong incentive to rely

• Obviates need for speculative lost profits analysis • Easy to quantify, especially relative to lost profits or

restitution of conferred benefits• Cuts through complexity and inaccuracy of the

accounting numbers• Does not deter efficient regulatory reform

Page 40: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Glendale Court’s Reaction

• “The court finds the testimony of Nobel Laureate Merton Miller, a brilliant scholar, regarding the value of leverage of little utility in this case. Professor Miller testified that any contention that Glendale lost something of value was meritless because leverage, standing alone, has no value. Plaintiffs convincingly point out that, notwithstanding the general principle of finance for which Dr. Miller won the Nobel prize in Economics in 1990, the situation of thrifts and other lending institutions is different, because they have access to low-cost government insured borrowings (retail deposits) which are unavailable to other institutions.”

Page 41: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

# of Cases

All Winstar cases (net of consolidation) 131

Voluntary dismissal 42Victory for government on liability grounds 16

Statute of limitations 6Cases adjudicated to a judgment on damages 36Cases settled for positive damages 9Ongoing cases 28

Cases appealed on damages:Final damages = Initial damages 14

Both decisions for defendant (damages = 0) 9Both decisions for plaintiff (damages < 0) 5

Final damages > Initial damages 4

Final damages < Initial damages 11

Number of cases with positive damages 26

Total damages awarded to date: $1.24 Billion

Summary of Outcomes in Winstar-Related Cases

Notes: Three cases with positive damages involved Guarini-related litigation.

Page 42: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

V. Some Lessons

Page 43: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Lessons

1. A proper economic analysis can deliver a sound, practical approach to expectation damages in complicated cases. In the Winstar cases, the cost of recapitalizing provides an upper bound to damages caused by the loss of supervisory goodwill• The cost of recapitalizing is quantifiable using hard data.• This damage measure has desirable efficiency properties.• It obviates the need for a speculative analysis of lost profits.• It cuts through the inaccuracy and complexity of the

accounting numbers.

Page 44: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Lessons

2. Firmly establish factual predicates for damage measures and the underlying economic theory, even when they are well known or “obvious” to informed experts.

3. Use simple formulations of economic insights that are easy for the non-expert to grasp. More general formulations are more powerful but can also be harder to understand.

Page 45: Breach of Contract in Complex Commercial Litigation: Damage Theories and Outcomes in the Winstar Matters Presentation by Steven J. Davis Vice President,

Lessons

4. Some courts give undue weight to problematic accounting measures.

5. The law should promote efficient contractual relationships. Applying this principle can help to identify undesirable features of certain damages measures.

6. In matters that involve breach of contract by the government, damage measures should be designed to maximize the joint value of the contractual relationship (as in ordinary contract law) and to promote efficient legislative responses to regulatory problems.