Analysis of the Shrimp Production

download Analysis of the Shrimp Production

of 9

Transcript of Analysis of the Shrimp Production

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    1/9

    Anais da Academia Brasileira de Cincias (2009) 81(2): 287-295(Annals o the Brazilian Academy o Sciences)ISSN 0001-3765www.scielo.br/aabc

    Analysis of the marine shrimp culture production chain in Southern Brazil

    RODRIGO R. FREITAS1, LUIS VINATEA2 and SRGIO A. NETTO3

    1Universidade Federal do Rio Grande, Departamento de Oceanograa, Programa de Ps-Graduao em Aqicultura

    Laboratrio de Maricultura, Estao Marinha de Aquacultura, Cassino, Caixa Postal 474, 96201-900 Rio Grande, RS, Brasil2Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina (UFSC), Centro de Cincias Agrrias, Departamento de Aqicultura

    Rua Beco dos Coroas, Barra da Lagoa, Caixa Postal 10136, 88063-600 Florianpolis, SC, Brasil3Laboratrio de Cincias Marinhas (LCM), Universidade do Sul de Santa Catarina (UNISUL)

    Av. Colombo Sales, 84, Centro, 88790-000 Laguna, SC, Brasil

    Manuscript received on March 5, 2008; accepted for publication on March 4, 2009;

    presented by ELIBIO L. REC H

    ABSTRACT

    This study was elaborated to identiy and describe the main links o the sea shrimp productive chain in the municipal

    district o Laguna, historically known as the main sea shrimp (Litopenaeus vannamei) production area in the State o

    Santa Catarina, Brazil. The study, held rom April to July 2005, previously identied the local productive process

    through observation, interviews and bibliographical research. Aterwards, specic questionnaires were elaborated or

    each o the several segments connected to the local activity. A total o 90 interviews were conducted, intending to map

    out the procedures and unctionality o the productive chain, rom the necessary inputs or production to the moment

    o shrimp acquisition by nal consumers. Results indicated that the entire productive chain requires actions that range

    rom improvement o sanitary and genetic conditions o larvae to product commercialization. Reduction o bureaucracy

    in public organs, better investment credit conditions, improvement in productive practices, training o technical and

    productive labor, and reduction o production costs will not occur until industrialization politics and commercializationo local production are standardized.

    Key words: Litopenaeus vannamei, marine shrimp culture, production risks, supply chain.

    INTRODUCTION

    In Southern Brazil, commercial cultivation o sea shrimp

    initiated during the seventies, in the state o Santa Cata-

    rina (SC) (Fig. 1). However, it was only in the eighties

    that it acquired actual business characteristics (Barbieri

    Jnior and Ostrensky Neto 2002, Costa et al. 1998). Ex-

    ponential growth o the activity was conrmed through

    censusesperormedby the ABCC (Associao Brasileira

    de Criadores de Camaro) in 2003, when it was noted

    that, between 1997 and 2003, pond areas increased in

    more than 400%, and by the ICepa/SC (Centro de Estu-

    dos de Saras e Mercados 2004), which reported a leap

    Correspondence to: Rodrigo Randow de FreitasE-mail: [email protected]

    rom 35 ha o occupied pond areas in 1998 to 1361 ha

    in 2004.

    In the state o Santa Catarina, with the introduc-

    tion o species Litopenaeus vannamei around 1998 and

    the creation o the Programa Estadual de Cultivo de Ca-

    mares Marinhos (May 22, 1999), the activity became

    promising (Costa et al. 1998). At the time o its estab-lishment, there was an expectation that 3000 jobs would

    be created in the state, with a R$50 million/year revenue.

    The project initiated with the creation and preparation

    o areas destined or cultivation. The states produc-

    tion reached approximately 50 tons in 1998, and in 2004

    production reached 4267 tons/year (Costa et al. 1998).

    The municipal district o Laguna has historically

    constituted the main sea shrimp production/growth area

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    2/9

    288 RODRIGO R. FREITAS, LUIS VINATEA and SRGIO A. NETTO

    in the state o Santa Catarina. Farms settled down along

    the entire lagoon compound, with approximately 83

    arms occupying 1536 ha o water in roughly 453 pond

    arms at the present (Costa et al. 1998).

    With the objective o providing a better productor the customer, as well as improving productive e-

    ciency, studies on productive chains aim towards raising

    eciency and production when acing diculties im-

    posed by increasingly globalized and competitive com-

    mercial transactions. This study is intended or iden-

    tiying and describing the current links o the shrimp

    culture productive chain in the municipal district area o

    Laguna, SC, in order to generate inormation that con-

    tributes towards overcoming impediments and permit-

    ting the maximization o existent potentialities that are

    not yet being explored.

    MATERIALS AND METHODS

    SIT E SELECTION

    This study was developed in the estuarine system o

    Laguna, Southern Brazil (2812 to 2830S; 4838 to

    4855W),withatotalareaoapproximately183.94km2.

    Three main lagoons orm the system: Santo Antonio, at

    the Southern portion (33.85 km2), Imaru (86.32 km2),

    at the central area, and Mirim, at the North (63.77 km 2)

    (Fig. 1).

    METHODS

    Basedon a previous identication o theregionalproduc-

    tive process, through observation, interviews and bibli-

    ographical research, specic questionnaires were elabo-

    rated or each sector related to the local shrimp culture.

    In this manner, it was possible to accompany the sectors

    and unctionality o the productive chain, starting rom

    the necessary inputs or production up to the moment o

    shrimp acquisition by the nal consumer.

    Data was collected rom April to July 2005, withinterviews o three laboratories, three eed manuac-

    turer representatives, three aerator actory representa-

    tives, 30 producers, one creator association, two pro-

    ducer cooperatives, our technicians, one technical sup-

    port and extension company, two research and teaching

    institutions, two control and inspection agents, one Insti-

    tution o Fomentation and Incentive to Credit, one pro-

    cessing plant, three middlemen, three sh markets, two

    Fig. 1 Study area. Circles represent researched arms.

    supermarkets, three restaurants, one hotel and 25 nal

    consumers. In this manner, interviews included all links

    o the sea shrimp productive chain at the area (Fig. 2),

    with a total o 90 interviewees.

    RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

    The Input group (Fig. 2) considered that shrimp eed

    presents high cost, and that it is dicult to understand

    the reasons or constant increases in prices. Feed quality

    was evaluated as good, as was delivery time and ater-

    sales service by the producers. The companies were verymotivated in participating in the growth o the activity,

    and do not perceive any diculties in supplying the re-

    gionaldemand or shrimp eed, as previously established

    by Ormond et al. (2004). Aerators also received a pos-

    itive evaluation in terms o durability, technical support,

    replacement pieces and maintenance. Other inputs, such

    as ertilizers, also received good evaluations regarding

    prices and easiness o acquisition.

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    3/9

    ANALYSIS OF THE MARINE SHRIMP CULTURE PRODUCTION CHAIN IN SOUTHERN BRAZIL 289

    Fig. 2 Local shrimp culture productive chain.

    Most interviewees reported motivation in working

    with the local shrimp culture, regardless o problems

    such as the white spot virus (WSSV), which causes break

    in production and halts acilities. Even while under-going several diculties, every party involved in this

    process is optimistic or the uture due to decrease in

    production costs and improvement o arm production

    eciency (Table I).

    Due to the continuous search or productivity and

    protability, producers nd themselves in high bank

    debt, causing production loss. Other reasons or their

    debt are bad loan management and occurrence o

    WSSV at the area. Shrimp culture is a high-risk activ-

    ity; thereore, producers must always be aware o cur-

    rent market transormations, local climate and dis-eases. Large debts and risks have imposed a new at-

    titude among administrators, which is to enlarge pro-

    its and avoid decits in order to stay in business (Raz-

    zolini 2001, Guimares and Brisola 2001, Christopher

    and Towill 2002).

    The producers point out super-harvests o native

    shrimp rom the municipal district o Rio Grande, RS,

    as the main actor o economical losses because o price

    all with shrimp commercialization. But in an extremely

    competitive globalized world, it is not advisable that

    producers become unamiliar with the production risks.

    They must be prepared or any possibility, such as dropsin the products commercial value (Bn et al. 2000).

    Knowing their own company and the possible oppor-

    tunities and threats o the market are necessary or the

    establishment o uture goals.

    The lack o appropriate loans needed or produc-

    tion also increases production costs, reducing nal pro-

    itability o the commodity. This is especially true when

    considering that the producer many times tends to har-

    vest the shrimp beore the commercially appropriate

    moment or payment o contracted debts. An appropri-

    ate loan provides autonomy to the small producer, sothat they can better manage the production and com-

    mercialization o their product, resulting in larger prots

    (Ormond et al. 2004).

    On the other hand, i producers do not have money

    to invest on their property, a portion o the producers

    have no choice but to take on more loans, being drawn

    into a vicious circle o loan acquisitions. Bank credit

    destined to nance productionand investment in ecient

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    4/9

    290 RODRIGO R. FREITAS, LUIS VINATEA and SRGIO A. NETTO

    =

    =

    =

    =

    =

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    5/9

    ANALYSIS OF THE MARINE SHRIMP CULTURE PRODUCTION CHAIN IN SOUTHERN BRAZIL 291

    TABLE IIPossible obstacles in the local productive chain.

    Laboratories Ration Aerators

    White Spot Virus WSSV White Spot Virus WSSV White Spot Virus WSSV

    Shut-down Facilities WSSV Noncompliance Noncompliance

    Scarce Credit Lines Scarce Credit Lines Bad Practices o commissions by Scale

    Lack o representatives rom ACCC Long Payments Plans Low technologic innovation Research

    High Production Costs (Ration, Energy and Employers) High Production Costs High Production Costs

    PoorAcclimatization Scarce Raw Material Low Business Proessionalism-Producers

    Low Genet ic Improvement o Shrimp Shrimp Super Oer rom Rio Grande RS Bad Farm Access

    Inappropriate Transport o the Larvae to the Farms Bad Farm Access Bad Farm Access

    Poor Bio-security Practices Low Commercialization Prices Low Commercialization Prices

    Bad Farm Access

    Low Commercialization Prices

    Unproductive Farms WSSV

    Discontinued Work by Support and Research Institutions

    Estate Building UFSC

    Producers Uninormed or with Bad Intentions

    Not Following Environmental Rules

    productive techniques or properties are badly managed.

    Also, they are oten inadequately expended, such as in

    payments o previous debts or even acquisition o per-

    sonal goods. In that manner, at therst sign o production

    ailure, the producers cannot pay their acquired loans.

    Producers are aware o the existence o contract

    breaks, payment diculties, bureaucracy and ew credit

    lines destined to the activity. Producers classiy interest

    rates and nancings rom good to regular, thereore de-

    mystiying the notion that the credit problem is only inrelation to bank institutions, which are orced to ask or

    more warranties in order to provide loans. It is essential

    or the producer not to become excessively dependent o

    such bank loans.

    In terms o accessing road conditions, it was evi-

    dent through the interviewees that a larger attention by

    public institutions is necessary. Unpaved and precari-

    ous access roads are a big obstacle or acquisition o

    ration and larvae as well as commercialization o the

    nal product, and also hold back the economic devel-

    opment o the community that utilizes those accesses.It was also veried that, when arriving at the arm, lar-

    vae are not acclimated as is required by a qualied pro-

    essional. These impediments need to be reviewed and

    solved in the imminent uture (Table II).

    The accelerated growth o the activity at the area

    also created countless conficts on how to use common

    resources. This generated a negative image o the activ-

    ity on the community, public service and environmental

    organs. In this manner, meetings or the promotion o

    understandings and agreements are necessary. This will

    also put an end to the belie that environmental licenses

    serve only as a money source to the local environmen-

    tal organs, requested only as a necessity or initiating

    activities.

    The level o environmental conscience and concern

    o the producers with the environment surrounding their

    properties is directly linked to their own survival in theactivity. Producers request more support and inspection

    o the daily routine at the arms, as well as education and

    control rom the environmental organs. Better organi-

    zation o the actions and rules that orientate the activity

    is necessary in order to avoid generating misunderstand-

    ings that harm the activity and its productive chain.

    In order to improve and encourage the established

    productive practices, environmental organs are strongly

    attempting to mitigate the current environmental impacts

    o arm construction and operation, such as disposal o

    cultivation efuents into the ecosystem and impacts othe conversion o terrestrial intoaquatic ecosystems, with

    actions such as efuent treatment (Vinatea 1999).

    There is no easy way to measure the control o en-

    vironmental impacts and inadequate use o natural re-

    sources; in order to accomplish that, it is necessary to

    establish economic incentives and harden the laws (Cor-

    dero et al. 2005). It is essential that the obligations and

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    6/9

    292 RODRIGO R. FREITAS, LUIS VINATEA and SRGIO A. NETTO

    regulations made to the producers be regarded as nec-

    essary or the sustainability o the activity, and in the

    uture become spontaneous attitudes or seeking the ra-

    tional use o the local common resources. It is important

    to see that the ast commercial and productive world-wide growth o aquaculture is usually accompanied by

    environmental degradation and distancing o social re-

    sponsibilities (Brummett and Williams 2000).

    The ACCC (Associao Catarinense de Criadores

    de Camaro) complicated the regional political-eco-

    nomical scenery, act evidenced by the lack o cooper-

    ation among its own members. Producers act indepen-

    dently without normative and surveillance by the entity.

    Actions or the benet o all, intended to improve e-

    ciency and reduce production costs, are not put into prac-

    tice because individual needs surpass collective needs.This practice goes completely against the competitive

    world pattern o agribusiness, which debates the impor-

    tance o integrating all links o any productive chain.

    By creating common practices, the producers generate

    knowledge and aggregate value to their product (Laz-

    zarini et al. 1995).

    Due to the ragile politics and economy o the lo-

    cal productive chain, it is undamental that the ACCC

    works as an Agency o Local Competitiveness, des-

    tined to generate programs with the objective o devel-

    oping the competitive capacity o the activity. In that

    manner, it could create a channel o dialogue, integrat-

    ing the entity and the productive chain with decision-

    makers, establishing goals and incentive actions or the

    growth o the activity. These actions will help to gen-

    erate jobs, income and technological and regional de-

    velopment (Pio and Maldonado 2005). This would also

    open up the possibility o a harmonic channel o rela-

    tionships capable o gathering the town, state and nation,

    aiding in the solution o the activitys problems by pro-

    viding appropriate inrastructure (road access) and re-search (Brummett and Williams 2000).

    As or quality o labor used in the arms, it re-

    ceived good and bad evaluations rom the interviewees.

    Major obstacles include the need or constant training

    and the lack o recognition, by some producers, that em-

    ployees are essential or the activity, considering that

    they are responsible or caring o the shrimp, which

    in turn generates prots. Also, arm workers receive

    low wages and possess low education, thereore need-

    ing to complement their income with other activities, as

    described in Schaeer and Panitz (A.L.C. Schaeer and

    C. Panitz, unpublished data). This was a negative act

    established by this research.In terms o technicians, it was evidenced that they

    are not motivated. Due to the act that they do not

    have autonomy to make changes, they are considered

    by some producers useless and unnecessary in accom-

    plishing arm handling, being the rst to be cut o the

    payroll at the rst sign o problems. They also receive

    low wages and do not have labor contracts.

    The producers are also acing many restrictions at

    the time o commercialization, depending entirely on the

    intermediate persons. By selling their products to ew

    buyers, the producers must accept prices determined bythe mediators. Thereore, the generated prot does not

    provide satisactory return to the producers, who ace

    alone the production risks.

    The Shrimp Producers o Laguna Cooperative (Co-

    percamaro) needs to ll the gap among producers and

    consumers. Since the Cooperative is in its initial stages,

    their actions are still restricted to stockpiling and reez-

    ing, but nevertheless it is a promising idea. The Coop-

    erative has the double-unction o gathering people and

    improving business, and users o the Cooperative also

    need to incorporate the double-unction o being own-

    ers and users o the enterprise (Antonialli 1998). Due

    to that act, group trust and motivation are a major part

    o the success o the enterprise. A good example is the

    relationship o the Cooperative o Aquacultures rom the

    Esprito Santo State, which sells their products directly

    to supermarkets (Piedade et al. 2002).

    Storage techniques ater harvest also need to be

    improved. Sanitary problems are common. Dirty boxes

    and inadequate trucks occasionally bring problems at

    the moment commercialization due to reduced productquality and consequent price reduction. Adequate stor-

    age and handling practices are crucial actors or prod-

    uct quality, preserving maximum sensorial and nutri-

    tional qualities or consumption (Neiva 2002).

    Traditional markets treat all their customers

    equally; thereore, they must know how to interact with

    potential consumers in an individualized way in order

    to discover their desires and needs. Every process be-

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    7/9

    ANALYSIS OF THE MARINE SHRIMP CULTURE PRODUCTION CHAIN IN SOUTHERN BRAZIL 293

    gins and ends with the consumer, so it is necessary to

    identiy market opportunities through the needs o the

    nal customer (Razzolini 2001, Naim et al. 2002). Un-

    derstanding the local productive chain is important due

    to the act that it is a sensitive system. The product(shrimp) reaches the consumer and the inormation on

    consumption returns to producers, which in turn can

    adopt ast measures to solve possible distortions in the

    system (Quinn 1997, Christopher and Towill 2002).

    Consumers should be more conscious about what they

    are consuming. Such concern o consumers with prod-

    uct does not exist, act conrmed by the answers o the

    interviews on the productive chain.

    Value aggregation, creation o trademarks and ad-

    vertising o the product do not exist at the area and

    should become priorities or the local shrimp culture.Trademarks, or instance, identiy products, simpliy

    choices and reduce risks or the consumers. All pro-

    ducer interviewees said that their produced shrimp are

    only sold resh, without any aggregated value. This

    limits their nal price and does not support the grow-

    ing demand or dierent products and the implemen-

    tation o various health procedures required by several

    importer countries. For instance, shrimp classied as

    headless, wrapped and rozen would be sellable in only

    about 40% o the North American market (Ormond et

    al. 2004). Such setback pointing in the local produc-

    tive chain is also beginning to be solved by the Coper-

    camaro initiative.

    Cultural, economical, social, amiliar and psycho-

    logical aspects interere in the consumers behavior, a-

    ecting the buying decision. It can be said that the pur-

    chase process o a certain product is divided into ve

    stages: recognition o necessity, research or relevant

    inormation, evaluation o alternatives, purchase deci-

    sion and ater-sale evaluation (Guimares and Brisola

    2001). Thereore, through this research, we have dis-covered that the major decision actors or purchasing

    this product at the area are price, ollowed by quality

    (Fig. 3). Price is still considered the largest diculty

    in the diusion o a shrimp alimentary habit among the

    Brazilian people (Ormond et al. 2004).

    The main concern or the consumer is to receive

    a product with the best possible quality, speed and with

    a low and competitive price. In order or that to be pos-

    Fig. 3 Questions destined or nal consumers.

    sible, urther studies or discovering the local demandor captive shrimp are necessary. Considering that the

    demands are dicult to predict, increases in the local

    population income are an important aspect that will a-

    ect the demand or these products (Brummett and Wil-

    liams 2000, Christopher and Towill 2002). Consumers

    will be beneted not only by low prices, but also by a

    constant oer o the product in commercial establish-

    ments (Ridler and Kabir 1989).

    The interviewed consumers do not consider the

    consumption o captive shrimp unnecessary, dierent

    rom what is observed in the USA, where shrimp prod-ucts are considered a luxury, reserved or special oc-

    casions and expensive restaurants (Barbieri Jnior and

    Ostrensky Neto 2002). It was veried that more re-

    searches on the local population alimentary habit would

    be necessary in order to reveal expectations and elabo-

    rate ways o increasing consumption, due to the act that

    the Brazilian national market or shrimp is concentrated

    in Rio de Janeiro and So Paulo states.

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    8/9

    294 RODRIGO R. FREITAS, LUIS VINATEA and SRGIO A. NETTO

    The commercial and consuming establishments

    also reported that the native species o the area (Far-

    fantepenaeus paulensis) is better accepted by the con-

    sumers than the captive shrimp. This problem was also

    evidenced by Bn and collaborators (2000) in theirstudy o Penaeus subtilis shrimp market dynamics at

    the French Guiana area. The act that the local commu-

    nity dislikes the cultivated shrimp because o its favor

    ater cooked has to be reviewed. Also, the productive

    chain needs to distribute their product to local markets.

    Today, quality is the big distinction between products

    (Neiva 2002).

    The local community preers native shrimp; con-

    sumption o captive shrimp in the summertime can be

    explained by the larger concentration o tourists at the

    area. There is need to perorm specic marketing re-search in order to reach those potential consumers in

    that determined season.

    Shrimp waste rom processing should also be bet-

    ter employed and could benet countless groups o the

    local productive chain. For example, ecdise could be

    used by local amilies or extraction o chitin, which

    could in turn be used in glue production or orthodon-

    tic material and the aeronautical industry. Heads could

    also be used or the production o meals or the eed

    industry.

    Making these changes will have major eects o

    extreme social importance on the community, generat-

    ing income and sustenance or many amilies excluded

    rom economical lie by utilizing products that would

    otherwise be discharged in the local ecosystem, generat-

    ing pollution.

    CONCLUSIONS

    As a result o this study, it was observed that the local

    productive chain groups are waiting or a management

    capable o consolidating, establishing and enlarging theniches that have not yet been explored. Projects that will

    make production dynamic and the chain more eective

    should be treated as priority, i there is real desire to

    strengthen this activity in the uture.

    RESUMO

    O presente estudo oi elaborado para identicar e descrever os

    principais elos da cadeia produtiva no municpio de Laguna,

    regio que historicamente constitui-se em principal rea de

    produo de camaro marinho ( Litopenaeus vannamei) em

    Santa Catarina, Brasil. O estudo oi desenvolvido de abril a

    julho de 2005, a partir de uma prvia identicao do proces-

    so produtivo local, atravs de observao, entrevistas e buscabibliogrca. Foram elaborados questionrios especcos para

    os vrios segmentos atrelados atividade local. Foi realizado

    um total de 90 entrevistas, pretendendo-se azer um acompa-

    nhamento do desempenho e uncionalidade da cadeia produ-

    tiva desde os insumos necessrios produo at o momento

    da aquisio do camaro pelo consumidor nal. Os resultados

    indicam quetodosos elos descritosnecessitam aes quevisem

    desde o melhoramento sanitrio e gentico das ps-larvas at

    a comercializao do produto. Desburocratizao dos rgos

    pblicos, maior acesso ao crdito para investimentos, melho-

    rias nas prticas produtivas, capacitao da mo-de-obra tc-nica e produtiva e reduo de custos produtivos no ocorrero

    at haver uma normalizao das polticas industriais e de co-

    mercializao da produo local.

    Palavras-chave: Litopenaeus vannamei, carcinicultura, ris-

    cos produtivos, cadeia produtiva.

    REFERENCES

    ANTONIALLI LM. 1998. Infuncia da mudana de gesto

    nas estratgias de uma cooperativa agropecuria. Revista

    de Administrao Contempornea RAC, Rio de Janeiro,RJ 4: 135159.

    BARBIERI JNIOR RC AND OSTRENSKY NETO A. 2002.

    Camares marinhos Engorda. Viosa: Aprenda Fcil

    2: 370.

    BN C, CADREN M AND LANTZ F. 2000. Impact o cul-

    tured shrimp industry on wild shrimp sheries: analysis o

    price determination mechanisms and market dynamics.

    Agric Econ 23: 5568.

    BRUMMETT RE AND WILLIAMS MJ. 2000. The evolution

    o aquaculture in Arica rural and economic development.

    Ecol Econ 33: 193203.CHRISTOPHERM AN D TOWILL DR. 2002. Developing Mar-

    ket Specic Supply Chain Strategies. Int J Logist Manag

    13: 14.

    CORDERO RR, ROTH P AND SILVA L DA. 2005. Economic

    growth or environmental protection? The alse dilemma

    o the Latin-American countries. Environ Sci Policy 8:

    392398.

    COSTA SW, GRUMANN A, OLIVEIRA NETO FM AND

    ROCZANSKI M. 1998. Cadeias Produtivas do Estado de

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)

  • 8/2/2019 Analysis of the Shrimp Production

    9/9

    ANALYSIS OF THE MARINE SHRIMP CULTURE PRODUCTION CHAIN IN SOUTHERN BRAZIL 295

    Santa Catarina: Aqicultura e Pesca. Florianpolis, SC,

    Epagri, 62 p.

    GUIMARES MC AND BRISOLA MV. 2001. Teoria Moti-

    vacional de Maslow e sua Aplicao na Empresa Rural.

    Revista de Administrao e Contabilidade, Unai-MG 01:

    3745.

    LAZZARINI SG, MACHADO FILHO CP, LAZZARINI NETO

    S AND AIB E H. 1995. Sistema agroindustrial da pecuria

    de corte: tendncias para o prximo sculo. Revista de

    Administrao Contempornea, RAC 1(10): 277292.

    NAIM MM, CHILDERHOUSE P, D ISNEY SM AND TOWILL

    DR. 2002. A Supply chain diagnostic methodology: de-

    termining the vector o change. Comput Ind Eng 43:

    135157.

    NEIVA CRP. 2002. Valor Agregado e Qualidade do Pescado.

    Revista Panorama da Aqicultura, Rio de Janeiro, RJ,

    p. 4647.

    ORMOND JGP, MELLO GAT DE , FERREIRA PRP AND

    LIM A CA DE O. 2004. A Carcinicultura Brasileira.

    BNDES Setorial, Rio de Janeiro, RJ 19: 91118.

    PIEDADE KR, NEVES MF AND SANTOS MJM. 2002. Ca-

    racterizao da rede produtiva do camaro de gua doce

    no Brasil. Proceedings Anais XI Congresso Brasileiro de

    Economia e Sociologia Rural, Eqidade e Ecincia na

    Agricultura Brasileira Passo Fundo, Rio Grande do Sul:

    Universidade de Passo Fundo (UPF). Event CD-ROM.

    PIO MJ AND MALDONADO LMO. 2005. Cadeias Produtivas

    e Competitividade: estudos de prospeco tecnolgica.

    In: MINISTRIO DO DESENVOLVIMENTO , INDSTRIA

    E COMRCIO EXTERIOR; INSTITUTO EUVALDO LOD I

    (Ed), O Futuro da Indstria: Cadeias Produtivas. 1a ed.,

    Braslia: Athalaia Grca e Editora, p. 91111.

    QUINN FJ. 1997. Team up or supply-chain success. Logist

    Manag 36: 1039.

    RAZZOLINI EF. 2001. Supply Chain Management SCM:

    Uma tentativa de conceituao. Tuiut, Curitiba, PR,

    FCSA 24: 7997.

    RIDLER NB AND KABIRM. 1989. The economics o aqua-

    culture. In: B OGHEN AD (Ed), Cold-water aquaculture

    in Atlantic Canada, Canada, The Canadian Institute on

    Regional Development, p. 373395.

    VINATEA LAA. 1999. Aqiculturae desenvolvimento susten-

    tvel: subsdios para a ormulao de polticas de desen-

    volvimento da aqicultura brasileira. 1a ed., Florianpo-

    lis: EDUFSC 1: 310.

    An Acad Bras Cienc (2009) 81 (2)