AN OPTIMAL PRICING STRATEGY FOR A SOLAR MOBILE CHARGING SYSTEM IN...

110
CELL CHARGING CHALLENGES: AN OPTIMAL PRICING STRATEGY FOR A SOLAR MOBILE CHARGING SYSTEM IN AFRICA MEGAN J. WONG PROFESSOR WARREN B. POWELL SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF BACHELOR OF SCIENCE IN ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH AND FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRINCETON UNIVERSITY JUNE 2011

Transcript of AN OPTIMAL PRICING STRATEGY FOR A SOLAR MOBILE CHARGING SYSTEM IN...

CELL CHARGING CHALLENGES: AN OPTIMAL PRICING STRATEGY FOR A

SOLAR MOBILE CHARGING SYSTEM IN AFRICA

MEGAN J. WONG

PROFESSOR WARREN B. POWELL

SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF

BACHELOR OF SCIENCE IN ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH AND FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY

JUNE 2011

ii

I hereby declare that I am the sole author of this thesis.

I authorize Princeton University to lend this thesis to other institutions or individuals for the purpose of scholarly research.

_________________________

Megan Wong

I further authorize Princeton University to reproduce this thesis by photocopying or by other means, in total or in part, at the request of other institutions or individuals for the purpose of scholarly research.

_________________________

Megan Wong

iii

ABSTRACT

Inspired by the possibility of integrating solar energy into the existing African mobile

charging industry for both personal profit and societal change, we examine aspects of

entrepreneurship from mathematical and business perspectives. We construct a prior belief from

current market estimates of costs and revenues in the solar industry and in Bababé, Mauritania,

respectively, and propose a Bayesian correlated linear belief structure for revenue as a function of

price. On the basis of profit-maximization, we compare myopic, value function approximation,

and look-ahead policies seeking to find the optimal price for a cell phone charge. A business

discussion with two contemporary case studies concludes the work.

iv

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

My first and foremost thanks to Professor Powell who not only planted the first seed of

this idea but also never failed to share his enthusiasm for my project and encouragement to

“pretend you’re actually in Africa!” His patience, dedication, and creativity for senior theses are

really quite superhuman.

Thanks also to Mohsin Sohani and Ibrahima Ba at Hip Consult for the practical

motivation for my thesis as well as the numerous emails and Skype calls from Africa. This work

is only as important as it incorporates and affects real people and real lives, and I am incredibly

grateful for their practical insight and willingness to work together on this project.

Erik Limpaecher of Princeton Power Systems was also an inspiring example of Princeton

entrepreneurship in a similar field of solar innovation. Many thanks for an informative peek into

the “real engineering” aspect of solar energy and wisdom on the challenges of developing

applications in Africa in his tour and email correspondence.

For bringing me to where I am today, I am indebted to more people than I know. To the

Jack Kent Cooke Foundation which has opened a world of opportunity for me, to my friends who

have encouraged me daily, to my family who has taught me visibly what love is , and to Him who

is able to do more than immeasurably more than all we ask or imagine, thank you.

Soli Deo Gloria.

M.J.W.

v

CONTENTS

ABSTRACT ........................................................................................................................ iii

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ......................................................................................................iv

FIGURES ............................................................................................................................vii

TABLES ............................................................................................................................ viii

CHAPTER 1 Introduction ......................................................................................................1

1.1 Mobiles Transforming Africa ...................................................................................2

1.2 The Challenge of Electricity .....................................................................................6

1.3 Existing Solutions ....................................................................................................8

1.4 Overview ..............................................................................................................10

CHAPTER 2 Cost and Revenue Assumptions........................................................................12

2.1 Cost Assumptions ..................................................................................................13

2.1.1 Solar Technology ...........................................................................................13

2.1.2 Current Market Analysis .................................................................................15

2.2 Revenue Assumptions ............................................................................................19

2.2.1 Bababé, Mauritania.........................................................................................20

2.2.2 Demand .........................................................................................................21

CHAPTER 3 Model.............................................................................................................23

3.1 Linear Belief Structure ...........................................................................................23

3.2 Specifying a Prior and a Truth Distribution..............................................................27

3.2.1 Truth Mean ....................................................................................................27

3.2.2 Truth Covariance ............................................................................................29

3.2.3 Prior Mean .....................................................................................................30

3.2.4 Prior Covariance.............................................................................................31

3.3 Mathematical Model ..............................................................................................32

3.3.1 State Variable .................................................................................................32

3.3.2 Exogenous Information ...................................................................................33

3.4.3 Decision.........................................................................................................33

3.3.4 Transition Function.........................................................................................33

3.3.5 Contribution Function .....................................................................................34

CHAPTER 4 Policy Optimization Overview .........................................................................35

vi

4.1 Pure Exploitation ...................................................................................................37

4.2 Boltzmann Exploration...........................................................................................38

4.3 Interval Estimation (IE) ..........................................................................................38

4.4 Upper Confidence Bounding (UCB)........................................................................39

4.5 Knowledge Gradient with Linear Correlated Beliefs (KGCB) ...................................39

4.6 Decision Tree (DT) ................................................................................................41

4.7 Restricted Pricing ..................................................................................................46

CHAPTER 5 Policy Optimization Analysis ...........................................................................51

5.1 Worst Case Analysis ..............................................................................................52

5.2 Average Case Policy Comparison with Different Priors ............................................56

5.2.1 When the Truth Comes From the Prior Distribution ..........................................58

5.2.2 When the Prior is Overly Optimistic ................................................................63

5.2.3 Value Function Approximation vs. Look-ahead Policies....................................69

CHAPTER 6 Business Considerations ..................................................................................70

6.1 People: Who is involved.........................................................................................71

6.2 Opportunity: Customer, Market, and Competition ....................................................72

6.3 Context: African Entrepreneurship ..........................................................................78

6.4 Deal: Financing Decisions ......................................................................................79

6.5 Two Case Studies ..................................................................................................81

6.5.1 Bababé Entrepreneur.......................................................................................81

6.5.2 Energy For Opportunity ..................................................................................84

CHAPTER 7 Conclusion......................................................................................................86

7.1 Main Findings .......................................................................................................87

7.2 Assumptions Revisited and Future Research ............................................................88

7.3 Final Thoughts.......................................................................................................90

WORKS CITED...................................................................................................................92

APPENDIX .........................................................................................................................96

Appendix 1 Linear Prior ................................................................................................97

Appendix 2 Pessimistic Prior .........................................................................................99

vii

FIGURES

Figure 1: Mobiles in Africa (Ewing/Bloomberg Businessweek, 2007) ........................................1

Figure 2: African Mobile Market Growth (Africa & The Middle East Telecom, 2010) ................3

Figure 3: Sub-Saharan Africa Statistics (World Bank, 2008)......................................................4

Figure 4: Fisherman in Chenai, India (©AP images/ America.gov, 2007) ...................................5

Figure 5: Earth at Night (NASA, 2009) ....................................................................................6

Figure 6: Charging Shop in Kiberia, Kenya (GSMA) ................................................................7

Figure 7: Mobiles Charged from a Car Battery in Katine, Uganda (Godwin/Guardian, 2009) .......9

Figure 8: Solar Cell Diagram (NASA, 2002) ..........................................................................13

Figure 9: How Solar Works (Young/QualityPoint Technologies, 2010) ....................................14

Figure 10: Solar Cost Breakdown (Frost & Sullivan, 2009) .....................................................15

Figure 11: Solar Module Prices..............................................................................................16

Figure 12: Estimated Solar Module Price with 95% Confidence Interval ..................................17

Figure 13: Map of Mauritania (Geographic Guide: Maps of Africa) .........................................20

Figure 14: Point Estimates for True Demand Means................................................................28

Figure 15: 99 Generated Truths .............................................................................................30

Figure 16: Truths and Priors for Weekly Revenue ...................................................................31

Figure 17: Decision Tree (Initial) ...........................................................................................43

Figure 18: Sample Decision Tree (One Iteration Back)............................................................45

Figure 19: Sample Decision Tree (Two Iterations Back)..........................................................46

Figure 20: Decision Tree Algorithm.......................................................................................50

Figure 21: One Sample Path of Worst Case Working Capital Using a Linear Prior ....................53

Figure 22: One Sample Path of Worst Case Cash Flow Using a Linear Prior ............................53

Figure 23: Algorithm Choices for Worst Case Sample with a Linear Prior ................................55

Figure 24: Truth from Prior, Unrestricted Decisions................................................................60

Figure 25: Truth from Prior, Restricted Decisions ...................................................................61

Figure 26: Overly Optimistic Prior, Unrestricted Decisions .....................................................64

Figure 27: Overly Optimistic Prior, Restricted Decisions .........................................................67

Figure 28: International Market Opportunity for Mobile Charging (GSMA, 2010) ....................73

Figure 29: Changes in Demand and Supply in the Market for Cell Phone Charging...................82

Figure 30: Linear Prior, Unrestricted Decisions ......................................................................97

Figure 31: Linear Prior, Restricted Decisions ..........................................................................98

Figure 32: Pessimistic Prior, Unrestricted Decisions ...............................................................99

Figure 33: Pessimistic Prior, Restricted Decisions ................................................................. 101

viii

TABLES

Table 1: Initial Capital Expenditures ......................................................................................17

Table 2: Weekly Operating Costs...........................................................................................19

Table 3: Summary of Supply and Demand Assumptions .........................................................22

Table 4: Estimates for True Demand at Various Prices ............................................................28

Table 5: Theta Estimates for True Demand.............................................................................28

Table 6: Worst Case Truth and Linear Belief Means ...............................................................52

Table 7: Solar vs. Battery vs. Generator Assumptions .............................................................76

Table 8: Solar vs. Battery vs. Generator Comparison...............................................................77

Table 9: Loan Options...........................................................................................................80

CHAPTER 1 Introduction

Figure 1: Mobiles in Africa (Ewing/Bloomberg Businessweek, 2007)

She pounds grain with a mortar and pestle. She uses kerosene lanterns for lighting, a

wood stove for cooking, and a machete for cutting grass. Her small mud home houses herself,

her husband, and her six children. She is without electricity, refrigeration, education, or sizeable

income, and yet - her family owns a cell phone.

Paradoxical though it seems, this description is becoming more and more common

throughout the developing world. On an international scale, mobile phones have bridged the

divide between rich and poor with greater speed and ubiquity than landline phones, radios,

2

computers, cars, and even electricity. Three inherent features of cell phones enable rapid

adoption and expansion. First, unlike cars or computers, a basic mobile phone can be purchased

for a reasonable price in Africa; $20 for a new phone and much less for a used phone (Ewing,

2007). In a developing society, low initial and maintenance costs are particularly vital to wide

consumer adoption. Second, mobile expansion requires minimal infrastructure needs. While

fixed line phones and computers require a constant supply of energy, mobile phones do not

necessitate connection to the grid. Finally, mobile phones are prime candidates for innovative

and diverse applications across regions. Providing a unique mix of practicality for the

businessman making a sale and of entertainment for the student chatting with a friend, mobile

phones stand as a symbol of globalization and an end to economic isolation in today’s world.

In this introduction, we discuss the obstacle of charging a phone in an un-electrified

village and consequent opportunities for an entrepreneur. In a village where lack of electricity

and telephone wires still prevents the advent of fixed lines, how do mobile phone users find an

energy source to charge their cell phones regularly? Can an entrepreneur start a profitable

business selling phone charging services to an off-grid village? The scarcity of infrastructure

coupled with the flexibility of both cell phone technology and individual charging needs lend

themselves well towards renewable energy and unconventional means of energy distribution.

1.1 Mobiles Transforming Africa

"The cell phone is the single most transformative technology for development."

– Jeffrey Sachs, Columbia University (Bloomberg Businessweek, 2007)

3

At the end of September 2010, Informa Telecoms and Media announced to the world that

the number of active mobile subscriptions in Africa had surpassed half a billion1. Hurdling over

the need for landlines right onto the mobile bandwagon, the developing world’s hunger for cell

phones was unprecedented and unpredicted. In less than six years, Africa’s mobile subscriptions

had quintupled, accounting for over 90% of the total telephone subscriptions.

Figure 2: African Mobile Market Growth (Africa & The Middle East Telecom, 2010)2

In the more fragile economy of sub-Saharan Africa where over half the population lives

on less than $1.25 per day (World Bank, 2008), cell phone prevalence is especially astonishing.

A New York Times article from April 2010 aptly observes that the number of cell phones has

surpassed the number of clean toilets in the developing world, precipitating quite a ruckus among

readers who demand that more funds be allocated to “important” needs. However, while some

1 500 million subscriptions is not an entirely accurate measure of the number of individuals who use mobile

phones, since the highly competitive market encourages people to purchase subscriptions to multip le

mobile companies. On the other hand, families often share phones in Africa, so the number might be

biased either way. 2 2009 data are estimates, as the informat ion was submitted for publication in 2008

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Percen

tag

e

Su

bsc

rib

ers

(million

s)

Year

African Mobile Market

Mobile Subscribers

Mobile Subscribers

(% population)

Mobile Subscribers

(% total telephone

subscribers)

4

may complain that the modern focus misplaced on mobile phones above more imminent

necessities like clean water, adequate sanitation, and paved roads implies a gross caricature of

today’s obsession with technology, the reality is that mobile phones have revolutionized the

African economy. Though phone minutes and charging sometimes cost over half a family’s daily

wages, there are direct economic explanations for this widespread mobile popularity.

Perhaps the most avant-garde application of cell phones is mobile banking. For millions

of rural villagers who have never even seen a bank teller, cell phones are a ground-breaking

means of money transfer. M-Pesa (M stands for “mobile” and pesa is Swahili for “money”), first

introduced in Kenya and now spreading throughout Africa, is essentially a branchless banking

service through which customers can deposit and withdraw money via codes on mobile phones

from agents stationed in prominent marketplaces and other public areas. Previously, someone

sending money to friends or relatives had either the low-cost, high-risk option of sending money

physically with an intermediary on bus or by foot, or the high-cost, low-risk option of a post

office wire transfer. Enter M-Pesa. A husband working in Nairobi can now conveniently deposit

a thousand Kenyan shillings ($13) with an M-Pesa agent, the M-Pesa agent sends a text message

to the man’s family in a western province, and the wife can then redeem the text code at a local

M-Pesa agent for cash. “Secure, low-cost, convenient, and fast”, M-Pesa costs only forty percent

of the post office money transfer rate and twenty percent of the bus rate (Aker, 2010).

Figure 3: Sub-Saharan Africa Statistics (World Bank, 2008)

In Sub-Saharan Africa

72.9% live on less than $2 per day

31% have access to improved sanitation facilities

6.5% use the internet

3% own a motor vehicle

33% have a mobile phone subscription

5

Increased communication also leads to increased market transparency and fewer third

party inefficiencies. The age when farmers and fishermen paid outside dealers a small sum to

learn crop and fish prices at the market is becoming obsolete; local artisans can now text a market

salesman in the morning, learn the going prices

for the day, and then bring the most sought-after

products to the market in the evening. This

system not only decreases product waste and

increases profits, but also reduces variation

among salespeople and results in a better price

for households. Robert Jensen at Harvard

University estimates that in a small South Indian coastal city between 1997 and 2001, the time

period capturing the first introduction of phones to 60% penetration levels among fishermen and

market salesmen, violations of the Law of One Price decreased from 50-60% of market pairs to

essentially zero. As prices converge, arbitrage opportunities decrease and the net result is

positive for almost all parties. Jensen observes that “fishermen’s profits increased on average by

8 percent while the consumer price declined by 4 percent and consumer surplus in sardine

consumption increased by 6 percent.” Not only do people benefit from a monetary gain, but they

also save time as the consumer no longer has to shop between multiple vendors to get a fair price

and the fisherman no longer has to travel and find a physical third party to acquire market

information.

Without the aid of governments or subsidies or NGOs, the theoretical benefits of the

positive externality of mobile phones seem to materialize clearly in Africa and the rest of the

developed world. MIT studies claim that “adding an additional ten mobile phones per 100 people

boosts a typical developing country’s GDP growth by 0.6 percent” (EPROM, 2009). As

entrepreneurs innovate, regional-specific applications like M-Pesa emerge to serve a local need.

Figure 4: Fisherman in Chenai, India (©AP images/

America.gov, 2007)

6

As information becomes more readily available, market prices become more uniform and people

gain time and money on the whole. As communication is simplified, the burdens of finding

customers for a small business, organizing large numbers of volunteers for a service project, and

calling hospitals during an emergency are simultaneously alleviated.

1.2 The Challenge of Electricity

Pervasive and influential though mobile phones are, they may not be the “silver bullet” of

African development that some authors have proposed. There are significant obstacles for both

the provider and the consumer inherent to Africa’s long history of development and lack of

infrastructure.

Africa was once called the “Dark Continent” because it was such a mystery to European

explorers. Today, it carries the same name for a different reason – the absence of lighting in the

evening as shown by the NASA image in Figure 5. Consequently, the first setback for a cell

phone provider is the non-existent or

unreliable source of electricity in rural

areas, generating a significant start-up

cost for the project. As the nearest grid

is often hundreds of miles away,

providers often resort to off-grid diesel

or renewable sources to power their

stations. The high battery or generator

cost of the off-grid station is still less than the immense cost of connecting to the electric grid. As

a result, off-grid base stations far outnumber on-grid base stations in both South Asia and Sub-

Saharan Africa. The Global System for Mobile Communications Association (GSMA) predicts

Figure 5: Earth at Night (NASA, 2009)

7

that there will be 639,000 off-grid base stations in the developing world by 2012 (Taverner,

2010). While off-grid is not necessarily a negative aspect, renewable sources in particular

introduce added unpredictability. If a village has a week of cloudy or windless days, the tower

may well be out of service after the reserve battery life is drained.

The other setbacks for mobile operators in the developing world are more subtle with less

direct solutions. Imagine receiving a call to service a cell phone tower miles away on unpaved

roads or arriving at a station one morning to find the generator stolen and wires snipped. There

are obstacles both in the undeveloped environment itself and in impoverished populations that

always house a few desperate individuals willing to do anything for money. Customers often

bear this cost, resulting in higher per-minute charges in rural areas than urban areas. In Kenya,

Safaricom loses a vehicle a month on unpaved roads

and some mobile companies resort to armed guards to

protect their fuel, generators, and other equipment

from widespread theft (Ewing, 2007). Establishing a

new business in any area is difficult; with the

additional challenges of rampant theft and vandalism,

operators face unique maintenance hurdles.

In un-electrified areas, the primary obstacle

for the mobile consumer lies in the regular charging

of the cell battery. The NY Times featured an article

describing one Kenyan woman’s plight:

Every week, Ms. Ruto walked two miles to hire a motorcycle taxi for the three-hour ride to Mogotio, the nearest town with electricity. There, she dropped off her cell phone at a store that recharges phones for 30 cents. Yet the service was in such demand that she had

to leave it behind for three full days before returning (Rosenthal, 2010).

Figure 6: Charging Shop in Kiberia, Kenya

(GSMA)

8

Ms. Ruto is one of 500 million mobile users around the world without direct access to electricity,

according to GSMA and Wireless Intelligence research. These users typically pay per charge at a

local shop every week or every day, depending on their phone usage. In Kenya, it is estimated

that one-third of the mobile operating costs go to power instead of airtime (GSMA, 2010),

encouraging users to text rather than call whenever possible. More and more studies are being

conducted regarding off-grid mobile phone charging as companies grasp the magnitude of such a

market. When an individual gains access to a steady charging source, field studies suggest that

the mobile operator’s ARPU (average revenue per user) increases by at least ten percent because

the consumer feels comfortable making more calls. With 500 million customers, this

accumulates to a $2.3 billion market opportunity for network operators (GSMA, 2010).

1.3 Existing Solutions

Where there is an opportunity for profit, corporations and individuals will certainly rise to

the challenge. Digicel, Safaricom, and other mobile companies have already introduced solar

phones with miniature solar panels and batteries built into the back of the phone, allowing users

to leave their phone out during the day to charge. Safaricom and Ericsson have opened village

mobile charging stations in select areas monitored by a guard or other personnel, where people

can plug their phones into the charging dock for a small fee (GSMA, 2010). Since February

2009, GSMA, in partnership with mobile operators and manufacturers, has pioneered the

Universal Charging Solution initiative in hopes of standardizing all mobile chargers with an

energy-efficient micro-USB by 2012. Opening the possibility of a world without duplicate

chargers and with a 50% energy reduction in phone usage, this solution has garnered much

attention and many awards in the last two years.

9

In the midst of a few existing corporate solutions, however, there is a budding African

market for local community members to meet the charging needs of their peers. One of the most

popular and easily accessible solutions arises when an entrepreneur purchases a car battery,

charges it in town, and then returns to the village to charge phones for a fee of $0.20 to $0.30.

The entrepreneur may set up a small station in the village or alternatively pedal from home to

home, offering door-to-door charging services to whoever is willing to pay. Wealthier homes

may purchase a mini solar system for their own mobile and lighting needs and then sell the excess

power to friends.

Consider the entrepreneur

biking around the village with a

car battery and the solar powered

home selling power to its

neighbors. The biking

entrepreneur loses money in a

third party transaction paying to

charge up his battery, while the

solar powered home is concerned

first about its own needs and not

strictly about making a profit. If we merge the two ideas and encourage an entrepreneur to

purchase solar panels and only charge phones during peak sun hours such that he does not need to

purchase a large battery to store the energy, then we have an interesting and potentially very

lucrative business serving a common local need.

Compare the application of mobile phone charging to lighting. Renewable energy has

been the much applauded solution for off-grid lighting in Africa, as countless NGOs, initiatives,

Figure 7: Mobiles Charged from a Car Battery in Katine, Uganda

(Godwin/Guardian, 2009)

10

and applications have been created for this specific purpose. However, by their intermittent

charging nature and existing technological structure, mobile phones, a much less-researched

topic, are even more conducive to renewable energy than lighting. Compared to lighting which

requires energy every evening after sundown, mobile phone charging is far more adaptable to the

individual. If the user knows he needs to make a long call the next day, he can prepare in

advance and fully charge his phone the day before. The time between charges is variable and

highly dependent on user behavior and decision-making. A prudent user, alerted by the

remaining battery life of his device, can plan his calls and charge accordingly to make the most

important calls at the best times. While renewable energy lighting requires an expensive battery

to store energy collected during the day, batteries are inherent to cell phones and entail no

additional investment. Thus, Africa, a continent latent with solar energy, coupled with mobile

phone charging and local entrepreneurship bridges a broad span of potential.

1.4 Overview

In this thesis, we examine the profitability of a small scale enterprise charging cell

phones from a solar module. Although there are many factors that affect profitability, we choose

to study the optimal pricing problem in depth, as this is the most salient numerical factor an

entrepreneur can control. Given prior intuition about the revenue generated using a discretized

set of prices, we seek to understand how the entrepreneur might logically develop pricing

strategies that utilize his prior belief, but also explore new prices. In Chapter 2, we gather market

information to specify cost and revenue assumptions in the particular context of Bababé,

Mauritania. This will be used as the basis of our prior belief on revenue in Chapter 3, where we

introduce the relevant notation and mathematical framework to use a correlated linear belief

structure in which the entrepreneur believes that revenue is a polynomial function of price.

11

In Chapter 4, we propose various policies to discover the optimal revenue. Representing

a diverse range of strategies, these policies fall into the main categories of myopic policies, value

function approximation policies, and look-ahead policies. Given these policies, we examine

worst case performance and average case performance with different prior beliefs in Chapter 5.

We investigate how the policies compare not only when the prior belief is close to the true

revenue distribution, but also when the entrepreneur has been overly optimistic or pessimistic in

his projections.

We provide a broad business framework in Chapter 6 to account for other aspects of the

enterprise besides optimal pricing. Supplemented by case studies with recent examples of a small

business and a large NGO’s successful use of solar power to charge phones and other applications,

the analysis is highly qualitative and discusses the cell phone charging market, customer, and

competition in more detail. The narrow view of Chapters 4 and 5 broadens to a wider scope in

Chapter 6 as we discuss the competitive advantage of a solar charging system and present ways to

improve the entrepreneur’s business model to minimize exogenous risk.

In the conclusion, we summarize the work to draw broad lessons and propose areas for

future research. In particular, we identify the key assumptions that are too restrictive and suggest

alternative approaches to the optimal pricing problem.

12

CHAPTER 2 Cost and Revenue Assumptions

Although business success is dependent on many factors, technical details aside, the most

important numerical factor an entrepreneur can control is price. If he believes that revenue is a

function of the price he charges, how does he choose the price that maximizes revenue? In reality,

the entrepreneur has a prior notion of the revenue he can garner at any given price and a strategy

to utilize his prior belief. He may, for example, take a game theoretical approach and just try to

undercut the price that his competitors at charging shops have set for a cell phone charge.

However, he is not sure that this is the true profit-maximizing price.

To clearly formulate the entrepreneur’s question, we first establish the macro

assumptions necessary to determine cost and revenue estimates. This entails current research on

both the solar industry on the cost side and the potential market of choice on the revenue side.

Note that although we have to make several assumptions about the true cost and revenue

distributions in a particular setting, this approach is easy to adapt to new situations when the truth

does not exactly mirror the suppositions proposed in this chapter.

13

2.1 Cost Assumptions

To estimate the entrepreneur’s initial capital expenditures at the onset of this start-up, we

must understand the fundamentals of solar technology and what traditional parts are necessary in

this context. Then we can study current market prices for various parts and obtain a basic cost

model for the solar module and other physical assets.

2.1.1 Solar Technology

The primary components in a typical solar system are the modules, charge controller,

battery, and inverter. In this application of mobile phone charging, we present reasons indicating

that only the modules and the charge controller are necessary.

Made from the same semi-

conductor materials as most home

electronics, solar cells are specially

treated to create a positive electric field

on one side of the cell and a negative

field on the other. A conductor connects

the two sides of the cell such that when the sunlight hits the cell and excites electrons to a higher

energy state (i.e. the photoelectric effect), the electrons are knocked from the semi-conducting

material and form an electric current (Knier/NASA, 2002). When many cells are connected to

produce higher energy potential, the resulting system is a module.

For larger applications over five watts, a charge controller is necessary to ensure that the

energy coming into the system is the same as the energy leaving the system (Wind&Sun, 2011).

If the mobile phones connected to the module demand more energy than the module is currently

producing, then the solar panel could be damaged. If the module releases more energy than the

cell phones can hold, then the cell phone batteries could be damaged. Though the charge

Figure 8: Solar Cell Diagram (NASA, 2002)

14

controller prevents both of these undesirable situations, Hankins in his guide Solar Electric

Systems for Africa reports that only half of the solar systems in Kenya took this precaution in

1995. Although people looking to make a quick profit may be frugal on up-front costs, their lack

of foresight ultimately has long term consequences as the life of the system is significantly

compromised. Improper care of photovoltaic systems has given solar a rather poor reputation in

Africa in past years, but with the correct maintenance and the more robust parts sold today, solar

is an exceedingly viable option as an off-grid power source.

A battery is necessary for most applications when the energy is not used as it is produced.

In lighting applications, for example, batteries store energy collected from the sun during the day

and release energy for lighting at night. In this entrepreneurial setting, a battery storage system is

redundant because we plan to only charge phones when the sun is shining. If there is a stretch of

cloudy days, it is assumed that customers will know that they cannot charge their phones until the

sun shines again, and will either find an alternative charging method or adjust their calling needs

appropriately.

Because electrons only travel one

direction in a module, solar applications usually

require an inverter to convert the direct current

(DC) energy collected from the sun into

alternating current (AC) energy required for most

home applications. Since cell phones are always

charged with direct current, the entrepreneur

has no need for an inverter unless he uses the

panel to charge other devices. In general, alternating current is used for most appliances because

it is easy to change voltage using a transformer. With alternating current, a power company can

Figure 9: How Solar Works (Young/QualityPoint

Technologies, 2010)

15

send electricity over long distances to homes using various voltages for safety and money-saving

reasons. Although low current allows electric companies to use smaller wires, high voltages are

also extremely dangerous. Thus, alternating current enables companies to exploit the tradeoff

between safety and speed in different areas.

For the entrepreneur in question, we only need to consider the solar module, charge

controller (for applications above five watts), and installation and set-up costs which include a

power strip to charge multiple phones at once.

2.1.2 Current Market Analysis

By examining current market prices for various solar components, we estimate the initial

cost for an entrepreneur setting up a solar micro-grid to charge phones. The most significant

upfront expense is the solar module, which consists of just over half the cost of the entire system,

as shown in the Frost & Sullivan breakdown in Figure 10. Because solar module prices are more

readily available than controller or

installation costs for the small applications

we evaluate for mobile charging3, we

estimate the controller and installation

costs as percentages of the module price.

To make the cost predictions as

general as possible, we approximate the

price of a solar module for a variety of

sizes. The power output is the most reliable indicator of price, since a compact, heavy solar panel

may have the same wattage as a large, light solar panel. Thus, by “size” we refer to wattage,

3 The average American home uses 11,040 kWh per year (US Energy In formation Admin istration, 2008),

or roughly 30 kWh per day. We are only considering s mall portable systems under 250W, the size o f a

small PV system used for camping or other s mall off-grid purposes.

Figure 10: Solar Cost Breakdown (Frost & Sullivan, 2009)

16

since weight and physical size are usually just indicators of the value of materials or the particular

design application, not necessarily indicators of price. The potential output of a solar module is

given by its power, measured in watts or watt-peak. Watt-peak is the output of a module under

standard conditions of 1000 watts per square meter of solar irradiance, but most literature uses the

term “watt” loosely to mean watt or watt-peak.

Although there is some variation in price per watt of various companies’ solar panels,

after combining the product information from nearly a hundred modules from various online solar

stores4, we observe a general economies of scale effect. The price graph is concave while the

price per watt graph is decreasing, indicating that the manufacturing cost per watt decreases as the

size of the system increases.

Figure 11: Solar Module Prices

We run a linear regression on the logarithm of price vs. the logarithm of watts to obtain

an exponential model for the cost of a solar module with x watts of the form:

The estimated coefficients a and b for the regression and their 95% confidence intervals are

shown in Figure 12. The confidence interval is computed by taking the standard error of the

residuals from the linear regression and transforming the coefficients into exponential form.

4 www.solar-for-energy.com, www.siliconsolar.com, www.wholesalesolar.com in January, 2011

$0

$200

$400

$600

$800

$1,000

-50 50 150 250

Pri

ce

Watts

Solar Module Price

$0.00

$5.00

$10.00

$15.00

0 50 100 150 200 250

Pri

ce p

er w

att

Watts

Solar Module Price Per Watt

17

Variability in the per-watt price is generally a result of differences in the quality of materials or in

the particular application for the solar panel. Panels created for frequent transportation or easy

portability are generally more expensive than typical modules.

Figure 12: Estimated Solar Module Price with 95% Confidence Interval

We use the exponential equations given in Figure 12 to estimate the total initial cost for

the entrepreneur. Assuming that the cost of a charge controller is roughly 20% of the cost of the

solar module itself and installation costs are slightly higher to include a power strip to charge

multiple phones simultaneously; we obtain a final estimate for the initial capital expenditures of

the entrepreneur:

Initial Capital Expenditures

Solar Modules (250W) $775.00

Charge Controller $150.00

Installation and Power Strip $200.00 Table 1: Initial Capital Expenditures

$0.00

$200.00

$400.00

$600.00

$800.00

$1,000.00

$1,200.00

0 50 100 150 200 250

Pri

ce

Watts

Estimated Solar Module Price

Original Data

Estimated

Upper Bound, with 95% Confidence

Lower Bound, with 95% Confidence

M(x) = 10.3391x0.8464

M(x) = 7.4654x0.7766

M(x) = 8.785x0.8115

18

Let us confirm that 250W is the maximum size necessary for this micro-enterprise.

Assuming a mobile phone takes 11.2Wh to charge5, a 250W module with five hours of sunshine

6

produces enough power to charge over 110 phones per day. In the revenue analysis to follow, we

see that this is the maximal size necessary for the entrepreneur who should only expect on

average 70 customers per day at low prices. In general, an entrepreneur can always add more

solar modules to his system, but he will probably only buy them in increments less than 250W

because of the high capital cost.

We must also estimate the weekly operating costs of the entrepreneur. Assume the

entrepreneur funds the entire project from a microfinance lender. Other options such as personal

savings or a loan from family or friends could also provide the initial capital needed, but we will

begin by assuming the higher interest rate and regular pay-back schedule of a microfinance loan,

leaving the discussion of other financing options to Chapter 6. Microfinance lending rates are

traditionally high because lenders cannot benefit from the economies of scale of large banks. The

microfinance process furthermore requires significant human capital costs to hire specialists to

train entrepreneurs and check up regularly on sma ll businesses. Accounting for high costs to

obtain small sums of money, the possibility of loan defaults, and high transaction costs, current

microfinance interest rates are close to 30% and sometimes as high as 40-50% (KIVA, 2011).

Solar is applauded for its low maintenance fees, so we set aside 0.1% of the initial cost of

the modules for maintenance each week. To garner business in the early weeks of the enterprise,

assume the entrepreneur hires an employee on commission for $0.01 per customer each day. He

then pays $0.01D(p) each week, where D(p) represents the weekly demand for phone charges at a

set price p. This advertising scheme is necessary for the first eight weeks, and then the

entrepreneur will be well-known enough to attract his own customers. And finally, the

5 7V and 0.8A over 2 hours charges a typical American phone (cellphoneshop.net, 2011)

6 Mauritania’s eastern neighbor Mali gets 5-7 peak watt hours per day (areed.org). Conservatively, we can

expect 5 peak watt hours per day for Mauritania.

19

entrepreneur must sustain his family. Assuming he takes $10 per week as pay and saves the rest

to invest in the business later, this yields the following estimate for weekly operating cost:

Operating Costs (weekly)

Loan Pay-back $31.20

Salary $10.00

Advertising (for the first 8 weeks) $0.01D(p)

Maintenance $0.78 Table 2: Weekly Operating Costs

2.2 Revenue Assumptions

Since revenue can be represented as revenue per customer times the number of customers,

an assumption about revenue implicitly includes an assumption about the number of customers

who will purchase charges at different prices, or in economic terms, the price elasticity of demand.

Mobile phone charging strikes an interesting balance between an inelastic and an elastic demand.

On one hand, no matter what the customer’s income or mobile phone usage patterns, he must find

a way to charge his phone. Whether in the city or in the local village, with a car battery or with a

generator, from a friend or from a stranger, the mobile phone battery must be charged. Perhaps

this is why the price of a charge is so high, forcing users to choose between charging their phones

and purchasing air-time. On the other hand, cell phone needs in Africa vary in degrees of urgency.

Some calls must be made right away, yet others can wait a few days or even be entirely forgone.

A prudent user knows how to juggle his needs to stretch his remaining battery life for a given

amount of time. Thus, while all phones must eventually be charged, customers have some control

over how often they want to charge their phones. Therefore, we expect a demand curve that is

neither perfectly inelastic nor perfectly elastic.

Revenue is a function of the price, but also a function of the population of the area and

the maximal market share. Though this analysis is fairly universal, it is helpful to contextualize

20

the entrepreneur and pick one specific area to study. We first provide an overview of a village in

Mauritania with high potential for solar energy and then discuss how to build a prior belief about

demand and revenue as a function of price in the following chapter. From the entrepreneur’s

perspective, we approximate the market demand for mobile phone charging, erring on the

conservative side for all numerical estimates.

2.2.1 Bababé, Mauritania

One of the poorest countries in Africa, Mauritania is a large, sparsely populated country

bordering the Atlantic Ocean, with population 3.3 million and annual GDP per capita $921 (USD).

A significant portion of Mauritania’s population live

on less than $1 a day, less than 50% have access to

an improved water source, and less than 25% have

access to improved sanitation. Poverty, as usual, is

most stark in rural communities (World Bank, 2011).

Although roughly three-quarters of the

country is desert, Mauritania is rich in natural

resources, as mining and iron ore account for nearly

half of the country’s exports. A historically nomadic

country, Mauritania’s main industries include

agriculture, livestock, and fishing. Severe droughts in the 1970’s greatly affected the country as a

result of heavy dependence on crops, accumulating much of the debt that still remains today.

Plagued historically by ethnic schisms and an entrenched practice of slavery, their recently-turned

republic has had a shaky start. President Taya was overthrown by a military coup in 2005 after

twenty years of authoritarian rule, shortly to be followed by another military coup in 2008.

Figure 13: Map of Mauritania (Geographic

Guide: Maps of Africa)

Bababé

21

The village of Bababé in the southwest corner of Mauritania has roughly 10,000 residents.

Households are fairly large in Mauritania since a typical family unit is built around the male head,

including his wives, children, parents, and unmarried sisters.

Regulated by the government through a Public-Private Partnership initiative, two diesel

generators currently provide electricity to 600 households and small businesses in Bababé

(Sohani, 2011). These generators currently run from 10am to 3am, but as the customer base

expands, it will be profitable for the generators to run all day and this will naturally threaten an

entrepreneur’s prospects at a successful solar charging industry.

2.2.2 Demand

We obtain a general approximation for cell phone charging demand in Bababé by

estimating the population of cell phone users without access to electricity. Note that in Africa the

percentage of people with access to electricity is much higher than the percentage that actually

have homes with solar panels or grid connections, since people often charge phones or watch TV

at the homes of friends and relatives. In 2009, there were 66.32 mobile subscriptions for every

100 people in Mauritania (International Telecommunications Union), a higher percentage than

those with improved water source access. Because Bababé is a smaller, more rural part of

Mauritania, we conservatively assume that cell phone coverage is closer to 35 subscriptions per

100 people. With the advent of electric generators, it is estimated that 50% of the population still

do not have access to electricity (Sohani), leaving a market of 1750 mobile users who need a

method to charge their phones. More realistically, the entrepreneur will probably only be able to

garner 10% of this market share even if he charges low prices, because each cell phone user

already has some existing way to charge their phone. Many have probably begun friendly

working relationships with bikers with car batteries and owners of local charging shops, so

convincing these people to switch to new-fangled solar technology may be more difficult than

22

merely charging a lower price. Averaging two cell phone charges a week and assuming the

entrepreneur only works five days per week, we expect the entrepreneur to have up to 70

customers per day for the lowest prices.

ESTIMATED SUPPLY QUANTITIES Low Est Med Est High Est

Solar hours per day (kWh/m2) 4 5 6

Watts produced per day 1000 1250 1500

Max phones can charge per day 89.29 111.61 133.93

ESTIMATED DEMAND QUANTITIES Low Est Med Est High Est

Population 9750 10000 10250

Cell phone users 2925 3500 4100

Cell phone users without electricity 1316.25 1750 2255

Customers per week if charged $.10 per charge 105.30 175 270.60

Customers per day if charged $.10 per charge 40.01 70 113.65

Table 3: Summary of Supply and Demand Assumptions

23

CHAPTER 3 Model

Central to the quantitative study of any real world problem is a clear and succinct

mathematical model that describes how we process relevant information. Given the assumptions

in the previous chapter, we introduce the Bayesian framework and notation necessary to make the

entrepreneur’s pricing decision. After proposing a revenue structure polynomial in price, we

utilize the previous chapter’s cost and revenue assumptions to obtain precise notions of both the

entrepreneur’s belief and the truth about the revenue that any price will generate. Using a

normal-normal model with linear beliefs, this entails specifying a mean and covariance structure

for the linear parameters. The last section of this chapter establishes the mathematical notation

needed to describe the process by which the entrepreneur makes weekly pricing decisions and

updates his belief about revenue with each new observation.

3.1 Linear Belief Structure

To determine an estimate for revenue as a function of price, we must have a notion of the

demand curve, the number of customers who will pay to charge their cell phones at a given price.

Intuitively, we know the demand curve is decreasing, because fewer people will charge their

24

phones at higher prices. From various newspaper articles and reports, we also know that the

going rate in Africa is $0.20 to $0.30 per charge (GSMA, 2010; Rosenthal/NY Times, 2010;

Edwards/Energy for Opportunity, 2011). However, beyond this basic knowledge, we can only

estimate. As we observe real demand values, Bayesian statistics later serves as a powerful tool to

update our prior belief and learn the true demand most efficiently.

Demand (D) and revenue (R) are both functions of price and are related by:

since revenue is simply the number of customers multiplied by the price paid per person. The

most simple and expressive form for the two functions is a polynomial function, linear in

coefficients. We choose a cubic demand model so that we can capture a logistic curve effect

when the demand is not as sensitive to price for extreme high or low prices. Revenue must

consequently be quartic because its degree is one greater than demand’s.

Although demand and revenue are non-linear with respect to price, they are both linear

with respect to the estimated parameters , and so the structure is correctly labeled a linear belief

model. With this structure, the entrepreneur only has to estimate the vector , and not the

individual values of R or D for the discrete set of prices.

In reality, the entrepreneur can only choose from a discrete set of prices, which can be

represented as an M X 1 vector with M alternatives, . Then we represent

the possible prices and corresponding revenues with vectors and R, respectively, and write the

above equation in shorthand:

25

(3.1)

where is an M X K matrix, and K is the number of linear terms in our model. Each row of is

the vector of terms corresponding to the coefficients.

(3.2)

Using a normal prior distribution and a normal sampling distribution, our belief about the

vector can be described by our belief about its mean vector and covariance matrix . We

use a normal-normal model to fully utilize our belief about covariance, the fact that we believe

the values and are related. If we are fairly certain, for example, that demand is

downward sloping and concave, then the linear and quadratic demand terms (corresponding to the

quadratic and cubic revenue terms) will be negatively correlated. For this reason among others,

we see the benefits of an additive linear belief model for demand. In addition to relating beliefs

about the general form of the demand curve, a linear belief structure is far more descriptive than a

regular correlated belief structure where the revenues for various prices are related. Imagine we

observe revenue much higher than what we believe is possible for a given price. The underlying

linear construction allows us to always update our belief about alternatives according to a natural

structure instead of arbitrarily making the belief about revenue for the observed price very high

and leaving the rest of the revenues low. Furthermore, the linear belief model reduces our

updating equations to only a K X K covariance matrix instead of an M X M matrix, and a K X 1

mean matrix instead of a M X 1 mean matrix. For a large number of alternatives, this

computational saving is immense.

The relationship between the mean and covariance of the parameters and the actual

alternatives p is given by simple linear algebra. Let us use the notation that after making n

26

observations of the true revenue, we believe the linear parameters are distributed normally

according to and the revenues are distributed normally according to

. is a K X 1 vector and is an M X 1 vector. It is already clear that =

by our linear assumption on revenue. The covariance between our beliefs at time n regarding two

prices and is given by:

(3.3)

where is the (i, k) entry of X.

Generalizing to matrix form, we can represent the M X M covariance matrix of the

alternatives by:

(3.4)

so that our belief about the alternatives normally distributed according to:

(3.5)

27

3.2 Specifying a Prior and a Truth Distribution

In the Bayesian model, we must specify two probability distributions for the vector.

The first is a distribution from which we generate the truth about revenue, and the second is a

distribution an entrepreneur might use as his initial belief before he begins to discover the truth.

To completely characterize the distribution in a normal-normal model, we must specify a mean

vector and a covariance matrix for both the prior and the truth. In reality, the truth is not

generated from a distribution; it simply exists and people try their best to discover it. However,

in this setting where we do not know the truth, but have an idea of what it might be, it is

necessary to establish a set of truths so we can observe the behavior of learning algorithms in

different states of the world and average them to see the broad behavior of the algorithm.

The learning process involves generating a true revenue curve and then using a learning

algorithm to discover that curve as fast as possible, starting with a prior belief about the revenue

curve. In the following sections, we first propose a truth distribution by doing a cubic regression

on point estimates of demand. Then, we generate a set of truths and determine the best, median,

and worst case scenarios for revenue. To provide a complete framework for the policy

optimization to follow, we finally propose various prior beliefs that an entrepreneur might have.

3.2.1 Truth Mean

Let us begin by assuming a true demand distribution of alternative means, since demand

for various prices is easier to visualize and estimate than revenue as a continuous function of

price. Although the linear belief model is more mathematically descriptive, it is also more

difficult to intuitively think of means and variances for values than it is to think of demand

approximations. After we assume demand point estimates, we use a cubic regression model to

obtain an estimate for the mean and covariance of the truth distribution, and .

28

Using the guidelines assumed earlier – that demand is a decreasing function of price and

less sensitive to price changes at extreme high or low prices, we propose the following numerical

low, medium, and high estimates for how demand should vary with price. Recall that the going

price is generally $0.20 to $0.30 per charge, so demand decreases significantly in this range, as

competition is stronger for these prices. Also, we are more certain about the behavior for extreme

prices, so the three estimates vary less for prices of $0.10 and $0.50 than for prices of $0.20 or

$0.30.

Price Med Est High Est Low Est

$0.10 350 360 340

$0.15 340 360 320

$0.20 300 340 240

$0.25 225 310 140

$0.30 150 250 70

$0.35 100 175 30

$0.40 60 100 15

$0.45 30 50 5

$0.50 10 20 0

Table 4: Estimates for True Demand at

Various Prices

Figure 14: Point Estimates for True Demand

Means

Given these point estimates, we calculate the linear parameters corresponding to our

belief by running cubic regressions on these three curves. The cubic regressions yield the

following results for the three demand estimates:

Estimated

Med 11144.78 -9482.68 1386.75 301.27

High 11750.84 -11984.85 2703.20 192.22

Low 9158.25 -5876.62 -171.92 422.66 Table 5: Theta Estimates for True Demand

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

0 0.2 0.4 0.6

Cu

sto

mers

per w

eek

Price

Point Estimates for True

Demand

Med

High

Low

29

3.2.2 Truth Covariance

Since estimates for the standard deviation of the values given by the regressions are

extremely high, we use half of the absolute value of an average of the difference of the estimated

’s as proxies for standard deviation. That is,

This can also be viewed as though we want our high and low estimates of the demand to be two

standard deviations above and two standard deviations below our best estimates when we

generate truths. Since the estimates are not exactly centered on the medium estimate, we take an

average of the two differences. This short exercise also makes it clear that for the desired shape

of the demand curve, and are negatively correlated with and . When one group

increases, the other decreases.

With estimates for the standard deviations of each term, we create a covariance matrix

to generate truths. Because a slight change in proportions of the terms yields drastically

different results, we set a very high correlation co-efficient between and , for all

. Then, each element of the covariance matrix for truths is:

Using the mean vector and covariance matrix as described, we produce 99 truths from the

distribution, shown in Figure 15(a).

30

Figure 15: 99 Generated Truths

3.2.3 Prior Mean

Let us now determine reasonable prior beliefs that an entrepreneur might have. Of course,

the entrepreneur could use the mean and covariance matrix we just used to generate the truth, but

he might also have less sophisticated beliefs. We use four prior distributions in the analysis of

Chapter 5:

1. Truth: a prior which is the same as the mean used to generate the truth.

2. Linear: a prior with a linear belief about demand and hence a quadratic belief about

revenue, in which demand decreases linearly from 70 customers per day at $0.10 to 0

customers per day at $0.50.

3. Optimistic: a prior in which the entrepreneur generates $80 in revenue per week,

regardless of the price he sets.

4. Pessimistic: a prior in which the entrepreneur generates $10 in revenue per week,

regardless of the price he sets.

0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.50

20

40

60

80

100

120

99 truths for revenue

Price to charge one cell phone

Weekly

Revenue (

$)

0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.50

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

50099 truths for demand

Price to charge one cell phone

Weekly

Dem

and (

custo

mers

)

Figure 15(a): 99 Truths for Revenue Figure 15(a): 99 Truths for Demand

31

The four prior beliefs are shown below, along with the best, median, and worst truths

from the 99 truths generated in Figure 15. The best, median, and worst truths are chosen by

integrating the revenue curve over all prices and choosing the truths that yield the highest, median,

and lowest revenues. Note that as the truth gets “worse” and the entrepreneur makes less revenue

for each price, the optimal price decreases. The truth and linear priors resemble the truth much

more closely than the optimistic and pessimistic priors.

Figure 16: Truths and Priors for Weekly Revenue

3.2.4 Prior Covariance

The final aspect of a normal prior distribution is a prior covariance matrix. This time, let

us approach the problem from the other perspective, first specifying and then certifying that

is a reasonable covariance matrix for means. The entrepreneur is not as confident

about the correlation structure between the parameters as in the truth distribution, so let us

assume instead of . Because the entrepreneur has less intuition about the

means, we will also use the same of 60 for each value. Using the same correlation

structure specified for the truth distribution, we obtain highly correlated alternative means with

0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.50

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Price

Revenue

Maximum Truth

Median Truth

Minimum Truth

Truth Prior

Linear Prior

Optimistic Prior

Pessimistic Prior

32

standard deviations of near 60-70. This is reasonable for our entrepreneur, who probably has

little idea what the true revenue for any price is. Now, with a specific set of truth and prior

distributions, we explore which policies are most effective at learning the truth in Chapter 5.

3.3 Mathematical Model

Given a prior belief about the coefficients of a linear model, we describe the revenue

learning process. The entrepreneur makes a pricing decision based on his prior belief, observes a

noisy instance of the true revenue at that price, and updates his linear belief structure using

Bayesian statistics. In this correlated linear belief model, one observation of price changes the

entrepreneur’s belief about all the coefficients in his model. We assume that the entrepreneur

can change price once per week, so time is indexed by n measured in weeks. Using Powell’s

notation (2010) to define the entrepreneur’s pricing problem, we express the entrepreneur’s

process of learning consumer demands by his state variable, exogenous information, decision,

transition function, and contribution.

3.3.1 State Variable

The state variable is defined as “the minimally dimensioned function of history that is

necessary and sufficient to compute the decision function, the transition function, and the

contribution function” (Powell, 2010). Thus, the state variable captures all the knowledge

necessary to the decision-making process. We use the general notation that superscript n

indicates information known at week n, after making n measurements. Any information with

superscript is random at week n, but known at week . The state of the enterprise after n

price measurements includes the entrepreneur’s belief about the mean and covariance of the

coefficients that guide the general revenue equation (3.1). It is written as follows:

33

By convention, the state variable only includes dynamic information that is updated over time.

Other static information necessary for computation are considered parameters, such as the matrix

X and the measurement noise .

3.3.2 Exogenous Information

We know that the true revenue is a function of price, but even with an unchanging truth

we only obtain imperfect observations of revenue because of measurement noise. In this setting,

exogenous information is the random revenue generated from setting a certain price x.

where =

and the measurement noise is normally distributed according to .

3.4.3 Decision

The entrepreneur’s primary decision is which price to set for a mobile phone charge on

week n. In Chapter 4, we propose different policies to make such a pricing decision, but for now,

we write in general notation:

where is the price chosen on week n and is a decision made by using policy from a

given state .

3.3.4 Transition Function

As mentioned before, the power of the Bayesian model lies in the fact that the

entrepreneur updates his belief each time period based on the price he chose and the

corresponding revenue observation. Using the state notation introduced above, the entrepreneur

updates his state based on the model M according to:

34

The recursive updating equations are described more thoroughly in both Powell and Ryzhov

(2010) and Negoescu et al. (2009), but here we present the results without proof. and are

just intermediate calculations used to simplify the notation.

(3.6)

(3.7)

(3.8)

(3.9)

where is a column vector containing the row entries of X corresponding to the price chosen

on week n:

3.3.5 Contribution Function

The entrepreneur’s goal is to maximize his total profit, the difference between revenue

and cost. By the assumptions given in Chapter 2, we give the weekly contribution of making a

particular decision in state as:

(3.10)

where is the cost for the entrepreneur as a function of revenue, since he pays

advertising costs as a portion of revenue in the early weeks of the business. This current profit

for a single period specifies how we determine the efficacy of a policy. By summing the

contribution over each period to obtain cumulative profit, we know which policies are most

effective in profit generation.

CHAPTER 4 Policy Optimization Overview

Posed with the problem of choosing an optimal price, the entrepreneur has several

decision-making options. After checking market prices for mobile charges in comparable

businesses and estimating their weekly demand, he formulates a prior belief in a manner similar

to our analysis in the previous chapter. Recall that a prior distribution includes a belief about the

mean and the covariance of various prices, so the entrepreneur must quantify both his intuition

regarding the revenue that various prices will yield as well as the uncertainty he has for each

estimate. Given this prior belief, the entrepreneur is faced with the classic “exploration-

exploitation” question of decision-making. He must balance exploiting his hunch about the

optimal price and exploring new prices that he is uncertain about, in fear that his original belief

was wrong. If the entrepreneur’s intuition is correct, then an exploitation policy is optimal. Yet

in the more likely event that the entrepreneur’s belief is not entirely correct, the best general

policies allow for a balanced mixture of exploration and exploitation and thus permit the

entrepreneur to learn the best price over time.

In this chapter, we examine several decision-making policies and introduce an additional

pricing restriction to mirror the actual situation more closely. The pricing problem is part of a

widely studied class of ranking and selection problems in which the decision maker must choose

one of many alternatives to measure in each time period, given a measurement budget. In this

36

online context with correlated beliefs, the revenue from each period accumulates over time and

the entrepreneur believes that the revenues from various prices are not independent.

For a summary of correlated belief research in ranking and selection, see Frazier et al.

(2009) and for a description of online policies, see Ryzhov et al. (2010). The most common

solution to the online “multi-armed bandit problem” in which early decisions affect the final

objective function is the Gittins index policy (Gittins (1974)), chosen to be optimal for an infinite

measurement budget with discounted rewards. To avoid the difficult computation of Gittins

indices, the knowledge gradient policy maximizes the value of making an additional

measurement (see Frazier et al. (2009) for initial derivation and Ryzhov et. al (2010) for

extension to the online case).

However, in all the policies mentioned thus far, the problem size is still linear in the

number of alternatives. Because it is ideal to analyze the pricing problem with a continuous

alternative set, we choose to analyze a revenue structure that is linear in its parameters instead,

thus simplifying the problem from an infinite alternative set to a small number of parameters. It

is possible, of course, to use existing policies to choose an alternative and then update the

parameters according to Bayesian updating equations, but few policies exist specifically for this

linear belief framework. In the context of drug discovery, an adaptation of Frazier’s knowledge

gradient policy for an additive linear model is proposed by Negoescu et al. (2009), and we

compare this policy to others in Chapter 5.

To adapt to the entrepreneur’s pricing problem to the ranking and selection framework,

we discretize the alternative set so that the only available prices during any time period are in

increments of $0.05 between $0.10 and $0.50 per cell phone charge. Many simple algorithms for

the ranking and selection problem have been suggested (see Powell and Ryzhov (2010) for more

details), each with favorable qualities and unfavorable shortcomings. The first pure exploitation

policy describes what is most likely to happen in reality as an entrepreneur chooses whatever

37

price he believes at that time will generate optimal revenue. The entrepreneur only takes into

account his profit for the current period in this classic myopic policy. The next three policies,

Boltzmann exploration, interval estimation, and upper confidence bounding are in a class of value

approximation policies that describe metrics for assigning values to alternatives. They seek a

finer balance between exploration and exploitation based on how much better we believe an

alternative is than its peers, how uncertain we are about an alternative, and how many times we

have already measured an alternative. In a different class of look-ahead policies, knowledge

gradient and decision tree resemble a more sophisticated entrepreneur who projects his current

beliefs into the future and makes decisions that maximize reward over a period of time.

4.1 Pure Exploitation

A very confident entrepreneur would use a pure exploitation policy that simply chooses

whatever price he believes is best each week. After observing a price, he updates his belief as

given in (3.6) - (3.9) and then chooses again what he believes is best. We use the notation that

is the price chosen on week n given some policy on the current belief state. That is,

. Recall that the belief state includes an estimate about the mean and

covariance matrix of the revenues for each price alternative x.

The pure exploitation policy can then be written as:

(4.1)

as the entrepreneur chooses the price he believes yields the highest mean revenue. Although this

policy has great potential if the entrepreneur’s prior belief is very accurate, it also has little

chance of discovering the true optimal price in any other case.

38

4.2 Boltzmann Exploration

This “soft max” policy picks a price to measure probabilistically, picking prices that the

entrepreneur believes yield more revenue with high probability. It samples each alternative x

with probability:

(4.2)

where is a tunable parameter such that for small , the policy samples each alternative with

equal probability (pure exploration), but for large , the policy samples the alternative with

the highest mean with probability one (pure exploitation). We simulate the policy over many

truths, and pick the that maximizes our expected profit. Then, the Boltzmann policy specifies

that we choose an alternative probabilistically according to:

4.3 Interval Estimation (IE)

The interval estimation method is based on the concept of a confidence interval. The

entrepreneur believes that of the time, the sample revenue will fall within the

interval

where is the estimated standard deviation of

, found by

taking the corresponding diagonal term of the covariance matrix . As usual,

), leaving in the upper tail of the standard normal distribution.

If the entrepreneur was to create confidence intervals with confidence level for the

revenue expected for each price, and pick the price with the highest upper bound of the

confidence interval, he would choose according to the following equation:

(4.3)

In this case, the confidence level has no real meaning and is simply treated as a tunable

parameter like in the Boltzmann exploration case. For small , interval estimation acts

39

like a pure exploitation policy, but for large , the term dominates and interval

estimation chooses the alternative with the highest variance.

4.4 Upper Confidence Bounding (UCB)

Upper confidence bounding is a variant of interval estimation, which also picks

alternatives based on a “bonus” term added to the belief means. In this case, however, the bonus

term is a function of the number of times the alternative has already been measured, favoring

alternatives that have not been measured often. For Gaussian rewards, the UCB policy is given

by:

(4.4)

where is the number of times alternative x has been measured, including the current

measurement (see Auer et al., 2002).

UCB is considered a good policy when the prior belief is very different from the truth,

because it encourages exploration of new alternatives. It also has the desirable UCB Optimality

property that specifies a maximal bound on how often non-optimal alternatives will be sampled.

If price x is not the best alternative, then the number of times we measure x under the UCB policy

is , or in general terms, less than , where is a constant. Although the bound is

not very helpful for large or a large number of measurements, it still ensures in the general case

that we will not continue to measure the same non-optimal alternative over and over again.

4.5 Knowledge Gradient with Linear Correlated Beliefs (KGCB)

The knowledge gradient (KG) concept of a Bayesian look-ahead policy for ranking and

selection was first proposed by Gupta and Miescke (1996). Frazier et al. (2009) later extended

40

the idea and coined the name “knowledge gradient” to describe how the policy maximizes the

value of information gained by a single measurement. How does one quantify the value of

making a measurement? It is simply the difference between the value of being in the next state

and the value of being in the current state. In our entrepreneur’s terms, it is the belief about the

revenue gained in period n+1 minus the revenue gained in period n. Because the policy is

contingent upon looking into the future and estimating the value of being in the next state, the

knowledge gradient is classified as a one-period look-ahead policy.

Imagine that after n weeks of running his business, the entrepreneur follows a pure

exploitation policy and chooses to measure the price he thinks is best:

Then the value of being in state is the revenue he believes he gains by choosing price :

(4.5)

After the entrepreneur observes revenue for the chosen price, he updates his belief

according to the updating equations (3.6) – (3.9) and transitions to a new belief state

. He then follows another pure exploitation policy with his newest beliefs

and thinks he will gain a new value:

(4.6)

Thus, the value of measuring alternative x is given by the difference between these two

values:

(4.7)

where and are given by (4.5) and (4.6). We take an expectation because the observation

is random and unknown at time n.

The KG policy maximizes this marginal value of information and chooses to make a

measurement according to:

41

(4.8)

The derivation of the KG policy for correlated linear beliefs (KGCB) is shown by Negoescu et al.

(2009), but we present the results here without proof. The policy is given by:

(4.9)

where

is the xth row of the original X matrix given in (3.2) and Z is a standard normal random

variable. is a vector giving the change in the variance of the entrepreneur’s belief about

the set of alternatives after measuring option x and is a function we maximize over.

Negoescu et al. (2009) also suggest an algorithm to calculate without taking an explicit

expectation, but we omit the details here.

4.6 Decision Tree (DT)

Decision trees are commonly used in the operations research and machine learning

communities to depict the flow of decisions and random information in a way that is easy to

visualize. A clear and concise overview of the current popular literature on decision trees can be

found in Utgoff (2010) and we summarize his findings here.

In a world with increasingly complex decisions, decision trees arose out of a need to

model and automate the way a rational person makes decisions. They are often used in the

medical field to trace the factors a doctor must consider to make a diagnosis or prescription.

Although decision trees can also be used to model categorical data (i.e. a classification tree), we

are only interested in modeling quantitative data (i.e. a regression tree) in this application.

Decision trees are usually computed using top-down recursion (see Friedman, 1977 for a

42

recursive classification rule and Quinlan, 1986 for the ID3 algorithm using top-down recursion),

and our recursive algorithm is shown in Figure 20. Today, the most common methods to build

and compute decision trees are the CART (Classification and Regression Tree) and the C4.5

algorithms (developed by Breiman et al., 1984 and Quinlan, 1993, respectively).

A decision is usually made using some greedy ranking system that specifies some

heuristic to order the alternatives. In our algorithm, this heuristic is the expected value of

choosing an alternative, but in other cases, this heuristic is not so obvious and much research has

been done to find good heuristics, particularly for classification problems.

We illustrate the practical concept of a decision tree with a simple example using only

two price alternatives and two possible outcomes, each of which occurs with probability 0.5 (see

Figure 17). The numbers and updating equations are based on a correlated normal-normal prior

belief on alternatives without a linear structure:

= 4

And the correlated normal-normal updating equations on alternatives are as follows:

(4.10)

(4.11)

where is a column vector of 0’s with a 1 in entry x.

In this example, the entrepreneur believes that pricing a cell phone charge at $0.20 will

yield $45 in revenue with standard deviation of $10, and that pricing at $0.40 will yield $40 in

43

revenue with standard deviation $15. He thus has to choose between the price which leads to

higher revenue and the price which leads to a more uncertain revenue, according to his current

belief. In the following figure, the square nodes are decision nodes where the entrepreneur has to

choose between the two prices and the circular nodes are outcome nodes where the entrepreneur

observes a random outcome with certain probability.

Figure 17: Decision Tree (Initial)7

For sake of clarity, we simplify the problem considerably in this diagram so that at Level

(1a) of the tree, the entrepreneur only has two pricing options: $0.20 and $0.40. If the

7 All probabilities in Level (2b) of the tree are also 0.5, but are omitted for visual simplicity.

Level (1a) Level (1b) Level (2a) Level (2b) Level (3)

44

entrepreneur picks a price of $0.20 this week, then according to his prior belief, he thinks he can

make either $35 or $55 in revenue with equal probability (shown in the Level (1b) outcome

nodes). This is also a simplification of the normal-normal model, assuming that in a

discretization of the normal distribution , we observe an outcome:

(4.12)

Pretending that he actually observes these values, the entrepreneur then updates his prior

belief to predict new outcomes in Level (2b), enumerating possible revenues given his choice in

Level (1a). Note the effect of the updating equations. The entrepreneur’s belief about revenue

for a price of $0.20 or $0.40 in Level (2b) is higher if he observes high revenue in Level (1b) than

if he observes low revenue. This is a result of updating within the tree, as the entrepreneur tries

to mimic his exact decision-making process over time.

To make a single decision, the entrepreneur projects his beliefs into the future, calculates

the profit gained from any possible pathway (Level (3)), and iterates backward from the end of

the tree to find the optimal decision. Each outcome node is replaced by the expected value of

choosing a certain price, and each decision node chooses the price that maximizes the expected

outcome. See Figure 18 for the sample decision tree after iterating one step backwards in the tree

where the highlighted lines represent the price chosen from each decision node.

45

Figure 18: Sample Decision Tree (One Iteration Back)

The outcome nodes in Level (2b) now just give the expected value of making a decision

in Level (2a). A rational entrepreneur would choose the price in Level (2a) that maximizes his

expected revenue, and thus, as we iterate backwards to Level (1) of the tree, we replace each

decision node with the values from the highlighted decision. Then we repeat the same exercise

and take the expected value of these numbers to obtain Figure 19.

Level (1a) Level (1b) Level (2a) Level (2b)

46

Figure 19: Sample Decision Tree (Two Iterations Back)

From this simplified decision tree analysis, we see that the entrepreneur maximizes his expected

reward by choosing a price of $0.20 in the current time period.

The decision tree is a discretized, multiple look-ahead period version of the knowledge

gradient policy with added ability to change sampling distributions or implement other

restrictions easily, but without the mathematical elegance of the KG formula. Notice that even

though we “make decisions” for multiple intermediate steps in the tree, the only real decision we

implement is the first node. Then we observe a revenue sample, update our beliefs, and draw a

new tree for the current time period.

4.7 Restricted Pricing

One unique aspect to this revenue problem in the context of other ranking and selection

literature is that of pricing psychology. If an entrepreneur bounces between charging $0.10 and

$0.50 for a mobile charge each week, customers will soon become exasperated with the volatile

pricing scheme and go to the nearest competitor who can actually decide on a decent price. Or

Level (1a) Level (1b)

47

perhaps customers will just wait for the next $0.10 charge since they know the $0.50 price will

not remain for long. In all respects, it is best for the entrepreneur to keep price fluctuation

between weeks as low as possible. Thus far, in the traditional ranking and selection problem and

policies, we assume that the same alternative set is available each week. In any time step, the

entrepreneur can potentially choose any of the M prices. However, to refine this model further,

we now add a new dimension – a restricted pricing set. An entrepreneur can only price charges

within $0.10 of last week’s price.

This restriction can be implemented in all the policies in a simple manner. Let the policy

choose the alternative it would normally choose. Then modify this choice as follows:

(4.13)

If is not within $0.10 of the previous week’s choice, then choose the closest price to the

originally chosen alternative in the restricted set. If is within $0.10 of the previous week’s

choice, then let .

Without significant re-derivation, all of the policies except the decision tree lack the

ability to anticipate how this pricing restriction will affect future decisions. However, in the

decision tree, it is very simple to foresee this restriction by just expanding the tree on the

alternatives within $0.10 of the past price. If the last alternative chosen was an extreme price,

then we expand on the five alternatives nearest to the price endpoint. This has the additional

advantage of “pruning” the decision tree and greatly improving its computation time. Because a

decision tree with K alternatives, L discretized observations, and M look-aheads has paths

to evaluate, many methods have been proposed to prune the decision tree to reduce K. See

48

Mingers (1989) for an empirical comparison of five pruning methods based on training sets and

valuation methods to determine the importance of a given node.

Because the decision tree grows polynomially with the number of alternatives or

discretizations, and exponentially with the number of look-aheads, it is important to limit each of

these factors to small, yet still descriptive, numbers. In our full decision tree implementation, we

allow the entrepreneur to pick any of the alternatives each time period, but when simulating the

decision tree into the future, we only expand on restricted alternatives. This is only for the sake

of computational savings; it does not accurately reflect how the entrepreneur actually thinks about

his decisions. In the restricted implementation of the decision tree, each decision node has five

alternatives. If pricing psychology is taken into consideration, this accurately mirrors an

entrepreneur’s actual decision-making thought process, as he knows that the price he chooses

today will certainly affect the price he can choose next week.

In both the full and restricted trees, we discretize each outcome node into five possible

outcomes by taking equally spaced portions of the normal distribution, each outcome with

probability 0.2 of occurrence. And finally, since the restricted tree with M look-ahead periods has

paths and the regular decision tree has paths, we limit the number of look-

aheads to 3.

To summarize these points more lucidly, we give the restricted decision tree

implementation below, where the Decision Tree algorithm calls the recursive Build Tree

algorithm each time it makes a decision. To edit the policy for the full decision tree described,

we just initialize the price set in the Decision Tree algorithm to the full set of alternatives, instead

of the restricted set.

49

Decision Tree algorithm

N = Number of remaining weeks in the simulation

M = Number of look-ahead periods

Step 0: Initialization

Step 0a: Initialize price set to = {0.10, 0.20, 0.30, 0.40, 0.50}

Step 0b: Set M = 3, N = 50

Step 0c: Initialize state

Step 0d: Initialize contribution = 0

Step 1: Do for n = 0, 1, … N-1

Step 1a: If (N-n) < M, then M = N – n

Step 1b: Call Build Tree al gorithm with M levels, using belief and price set to

make a decision

Step 1c: Observe revenue from the truth

Step 1d: Update the state =

Step 1e: Update price set = { – 0.10, – 0.05, , + 0.05, + 0.10}. If any

price in is outside of the range of alternatives, then update as the lowest 5 or

highest 5 price alternatives.

Step 1f: Update the contribution

Figure 20(a): Decision Tree Algorithm

50

Build Tree algorithm

Step 0: Initialization and outer loop

Step 1: Initialize look-ahead periods M, price set , and state

Step 2: For

Step 3: For , discretizations of the normal distribution

Step 4: Assume we observe

Step 5: Initialize cumulative profit:

Step 6: Go to Step 9 to calculate

Step 7: Calculate

Step 8: Return

to Decision Tree algorithm

Step 9: Recursive algorithm to calculate the value of making decision in state with M

look-aheads left and cumulative profi t :

Step 10: If M = 0, then return cumulative profit

Step 11: Update state =

Step 12: Update indices: { – 0.10, – 0.05, , + 0.05,

+ 0.10. If any price in is outside of the range of al ternatives, then update as

the lowest 5 or highest 5 price al ternatives.

Step 13: For

Step 14: Assume we make decision

Step 15: For , discretizations of the normal distribution

Step 16: Assume we observe

Step 17: Update cumulative profi t:

Step 18: Repeat from Step 9 to calculate

Step 19: Calculate

Step 20: Return

Figure 20: Decision Tree Algorithm

Figure 20(b): Build Tree Algorithm

51

CHAPTER 5 Policy Optimization Analysis

If an entrepreneur was actually to use the learning algorithms in the previous chapter to

find the optimal price, his potential profit and risk would vary according to the selected policy

and the accuracy of his prior belief. In this chapter, we compare policies in various contexts to

determine which perform the best in the worst case and on average.

Worst case analysis is perhaps the most important as it signals to investors that the

entrepreneur has carefully considered potential risks and is not running carelessly with an idea

that sounds much better on paper than it is in practice. By showing the results of the algorithms

when revenue prospects are lowest, we obtain a general idea of how poorly this enterprise might

fare and how an extremely cautious entrepreneur might proceed to choose prices week by week.

Following worst case analysis, we compare restricted and unrestricted policies in the

general case averaged over many truths generated from the distribution specified in Chapter 3.

Although four possible revenue priors are described in Chapter 3, we only include analysis for the

prior that is the same as the truth distribution and the prior that is overly optimistic as examples of

“good” and “bad” priors, respectively. The same results for linear and overly pessimistic priors,

additional examples of “good” and “bad” priors, are given in the appendix. Through this average

case analysis, we seek to understand a number of practical questions such as how profit depends

52

on the truth distribution’s maximal revenue and how the value function approximation and look-

ahead policies compare to pure exploitation, the entrepreneur’s default strategy. With these

predictions, we furthermore obtain basic profitability estimates over the first weeks of the

entrepreneur’s business. As in the cost and revenue estimates of Chapter 2, we err on the most

conservative side and consequently only give simulated results for the first year of the business,

when costs are the highest as the entrepreneur pays back his micro-finance loan.

5.1 Worst Case Analysis

For the worst case truth, it is almost impossible for the entrepreneur to make a profit

above his regular salary under the given cost assumptions. Costs, including loan payments, are

between $40 and $45 per week and maximum potential revenue is only $43 if we price $0.15 per

cell charge. The true mean revenue in the worst case for the various prices is shown below, along

with the measurement variance of each price and the linear prior belief about each alternative.

(price)

$0.10 $35.24 $4 $35.00

$.15 $43.05 $4 $45.93

$.20 $42.14 $4 $52.50

$.25 $32.47 $4 $54.68

$.30 $15.59 $4 $52.50

$.35 $0 $4 $45.94

$.40 $0 $4 $35.00

$.45 $0 $4 $19.69

$.50 $0 $4 $0

Table 6: Worst Case Truth and Linear Belief Means

Unless the entrepreneur finds the optimal price within the first few weeks, he cannot sustain his

enterprise. If the entrepreneur starts with $75 cash initially and a belief that demand is linear, his

53

working capital and weekly cash flow over one sample path of the unrestricted pricing algorithm

are shown in Figures 21 and 22. Note that only KGCB, DT, and UCB would allow the

entrepreneur to stay in business with a positive working capital during the first year of the

enterprise. As illustrated by this sample path, pure exploitation does very poorly when the prior

belief does not match the truth.

Figure 21: One Sample Path of Worst Case Working Capital Using a Linear Prior

Figure 22: One Sample Path of Worst Case Cash Flow Using a Linear Prior

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-500

-400

-300

-200

-100

0

100Working capital with minimum truth, linear prior

Week

Work

ing C

apital ($

)

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10Cashflow with minimum truth, linear prior

Week

Cashflow

($)

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

54

For sake of comparison, we use the same random sample path for each policy. That is,

when we observe

, where , we use the same Z observation for

each policy. Each week, of course, we generate a new Z value, but notice that the fluctuations in

the above graph are the same. This stipulation furthermore reduces the size of our confidence

intervals when we later compare policies as it strengthens the basis of comparison.

Figures 21 and 22 show a single sample path of choices, when observations are generated

with noise from the true distribution

. From this single path analysis, we make

two general observations. First, we note that weekly cash flow is highly variable, ranging from

-$25 to $8 under the given policies and making leaps of up to $10 per week, even when

measuring the same prices. In the case with many truths to follow, this variability is hidden

beneath averages. However, in reality, the entrepreneur has one truth and one prior, and his cash

flow variability will likely be closer to that of Figure 22.

Second, we gain insight into specific algorithmic behavior as we examine pricing choices

in Figure 23. Because the policies maximize an online objective, they naturally favor exploitation

over exploration and thus measure prices near $0.25 in early iterations. As the number of

iterations increases, all policies except pure exploitation begin to sample other prices. Although

the KGCB policy finds the optimal price fastest in this case, all the policies except pure

exploitation eventually settle on the optimal price of $0.15. DT’s behavior does not resemble

KGCB’s in this case, despite the fact that they are in the same class of look-ahead policies. By

nature of the prior belief with high variance for each alternative, the extra look-ahead periods bias

DT to choose a higher price than KGCB during the first iteration. After that, DT’s beliefs are

updated and the algorithm steadily moves downward in its choices until it settles on the optimal

price. In contrast, KGCB tends to choose lower prices than the rest of the policies, which is

helpful for this minimal revenue case when the optimal price is low.

55

Figure 23: Algorithm Choices for Worst Case Sample with a Linear Prior

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

KGCB Linear Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Exploitation Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Boltzmann Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Interval Estimation Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Decision Tree Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 550

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

UCB Choices

Week

Price m

easure

d

Figure 23(a): KGCB Choices Figure 23(b): Exploitation Choices

Figure 23(f): UCB Choices Figure 23(e): DT Choices

Figure 23(d): IE Choices Figure 23(c): Boltzmann Choices

56

One reason for the relatively strong performance of all six policies except pure

exploitation is the correlated linear belief updating. After observing a price, the entrepreneur

updates his belief about each of the pricing alternatives in a way that assumes a certain correlation

between each linear parameter. This parameter updating is much more powerful than updating

individual beliefs and greatly aids in the process of finding the optimal price. Also, the

parameters are tuned for the Boltzmann, IE, and UCB policies for each of the different priors to

give optimal results. Because of this, Boltzmann exploration does not look as random and UCB

does not sample as many alternatives as expected, since the tuned parameters bias both policies

towards exploitation.

We omit the restricted pricing results in this case, because the unrestricted choices do not

vary significantly, so the pricing restriction would have a negligible effect.

If the entrepreneur does find himself in the worst case truth where it is very difficult to

make money, his best option is to use a policy besides pure exploitation, and KGCB seems the

best alternative in this sample path. This closely matches reality when an entrepreneur finds that

his intuition is causing him to lose more and more money, and consequently explores prices more

freely. If he can survive his first year, prospects for profitability are high, since in following

weeks the entrepreneur no longer has to pay back $31.20 to the microfinance agency.

5.2 Average Case Policy Comparison with Different Priors

In the average case, the entrepreneur hopes to find the policy that gives maximal profit in

the first year of operation. In the notation introduced in Chapter 3, we denote this policy

optimization as:

(5.1)

57

where is the contribution, or generated profit, from making decision in state . To

simplify notation, we rewrite the expected value in (5.1) as , the profit generated from

using policy given a sample path of observations.

We now give an objective basis for comparison between policies. If we simulate each

policy N times, we can calculate confidence intervals for , the average difference in

profit between policies and according to:

(5.2)

where = ) and the average difference is:

(5.3)

The sample standard deviation for differences is:

(5.4)

The entrepreneur, of course, wants to know if the confidence interval is above or below 0 to

conclude with a high degree of confidence that one policy outperforms the other on average.

We have six primary questions in our average case analysis, each answered by a different

plot in the figures of this section. The questions are summarized as follows:

a. Does KGCB give a more optimal solution than DT? We want to understand whether a

discretized multi-period look-ahead policy with restricted alternatives makes better

decisions than a continuous one-period look-ahead. Because the policies are so similar, it

is illustrative to scrutinize their relative behavior. We give a 95% confidence interval for

the difference between the two policies during each week according to (5.2).

b. Do other polices outperform an entrepreneur’s default strategy of pure exploitation? In

other words, is “typical” human behavior is optimal? We give 95% confidence intervals

for the differences between all other policies and pure exploitation during each week

according to (5.2).

58

c. What is the entrepreneur’s average cash flow in the first fifty weeks of his enterprise?

d. What is the entrepreneur’s average working capital in the first fifty weeks of his

enterprise?

e. How does the entrepreneur’s profit vary with the true maximal revenue? Of course, if

one truth allows the entrepreneur to make higher revenues than another, the former

situation will be more profitable for the entrepreneur. If we eliminate this source of

variability, how do policies compare? Do certain policies perform better in cases when

demand and revenue prospects are lower?

f. If the entrepreneur was to continue his business for a time greater or less than fifty weeks,

how much revenue would he generate? In this analysis, we assume the same micro-loan

payments in each situation for comparison sake. However, in reality, if the entrepreneur

only kept his business open for ten weeks, he would have to make much higher loan

repayments than if he kept his business open for fifty weeks.

We simulate the first five questions over 1000 truths generated from the distribution given in

Chapter 3, and we simulate the last question over 100 truths for N = 5, 10, … 95, 100 weeks.

5.2.1 When the Truth Comes From the Prior Distribution

We first examine the case when the truth comes from a distribution with the same

alternative means as the prior. Unlike an overly optimistic or overly pessimistic prior that

anticipates the same revenue for each price, this prior has a maximum and the entrepreneur has a

clear idea of which price is optimal. However, his belief might not match the true optimum of the

randomly generated truth, so there is some benefit to exploring new alternatives.

59

The results for the unrestricted and restricted analysis are shown on the following two

pages. Because the prior is a very good estimate of the truth, policies find the optimum price

fairly quickly in all cases without wild fluctuations in price choice. As in the worst case truth

with linear prior case, the restricted and unrestricted graphs are almost identical, because the

restriction does not impede any of the algorithms.

60

Figure 24: Truth from Prior, Unrestricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 504

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Week

Cash f

low

Cash flow over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 500

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1000

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 24(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 24(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 24(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 24(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 24(d): Working Capital Figure 24(c): Cash Flow

61

Figure 25: Truth from Prior, Restricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 504

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Week

Cash f

low

over

tim

e

Cash flow

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 500

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

40 50 60 70 80 90 100-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1000

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

2000

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 25(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 25(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 25(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 25(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 25(d): Working Capital Figure 25(c): Cash Flow

62

In both the restricted and unrestricted simulations, KGCB’s performance is the worst in

early iterations. As shown in the worst case sample path in the previous section, this is because

KGCB tends to sample lower prices. Because of this propensity, DT makes better decisions than

KGCB in early iterations (Figures 24(a) and 25(a)). However, over time, KGCB’s exploratory

steps pay off and KGCB averages slightly higher revenue than all the other policies. IE,

Boltzmann, and UCB all perform very similarly and very well with a good prior.

Because the prior is very close to the truth, pure exploitation is a fairly good policy.

Although it does not always find the true optimum, its decisions are not so poor in this case, and

its cumulative performance is better than KGCB’s. The other policies, however, still outperform

pure exploitation, even when the truth comes from the prior.

Working capital and cash flow estimates are also high for all policies, as the prior belief

is very good and the entrepreneur finds the optimal price quickly in almost all cases. Over a 50

week period, the entrepreneur can make nearly $900 using value function approximation policies

under our assumptions.

Another notable feature of this particular prior distribution is that there is little variation

in Figures 24(e) and 25(e) which display the cumulative fifty week profit as a function of the

maximum revenue available. This is because the prior is close to the truth and all policies, no

matter what the maximum revenue, have a good general idea of the revenue curve. Thus, they

settle on a fairly good alternative quickly in all cases. When the maximal revenue is low, all

policies accumulate similar revenue; however, as maximum revenue increases, pure exploitation

and KGCB fall behind the rest of the policies. In general, as maximum revenue increases, the

optimal price also increases because when demand increases overall, the entrepreneur can charge

a higher price for a cell phone charge. Since KGCB tends to choose lower prices and pure

exploitation thinks $0.20 is the optimal price in the linear prior case, both policies are penalized

for an increase in the optimal price.

63

No policy performs relatively better with a small number of measurements or a large

number of measurements in Figures 24(f) and 25(f). The more time periods, the more the

behavior of the individual policies is emphasized.

5.2.2 When the Prior is Overly Optimistic

We next examine the situation when the entrepreneur has a very poor prior belief,

thinking that every possible price will yield $80 in revenue per week. In this case, the

entrepreneur has no intuition about the optimal alternative, so the results are likely to be more

varied than in the case where the truth comes from the prior distribution because the early choices

and random observations greatly influence the future belief. Mathematically, for small n,

is more dependent on and x in this case than in the previous case

when the prior was very close to the truth.

First, we give the results for the unrestricted case:

64

Figure 26: Overly Optimistic Prior, Unrestricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

Week

Cash f

low

Cash flow over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-300

-200

-100

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

40 50 60 70 80 90 100-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-600

-400

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 26(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 26(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 26(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 26(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 26(d): Working Capital Figure 26(c): Cash Flow

65

Again, KGCB performs worse than the DT in early iterations because of its tendency to

pick low prices, but after nearly twenty-five iterations KGCB does significantly better than DT

(Figures 26(a) and 26(b)). With this poor prior, we also see the similarities of KGCB and DT

more clearly than in the last case where virtually every policy did well. Especially in Figures

26(c) and 26(f), we observe close behavior of KGCB and DT as the policies settle on close

revenue means, but do not reach the better alternatives discovered by UCB, IE, and Boltzmann.

As the number of weeks in the simulation increases, KGCB and DT also have remarkably similar

performance.

Pure exploitation does very poorly in this case, since the prior is very different from the

truth. As a result, all policies yield much higher revenues and cash flows than pure exploitation

(Figure 26(b)).

With a less accurate prior belief than the previous case when the truth came from the

prior distribution, cash flows and working capital estimates are lower. Instead of making up to

$900 per year, the entrepreneur can only make up to $600 in his first year with the best policies.

As in reality when worse revenue predictions leads to poor decision-making, a bad prior belief

can greatly inhibit profit, even with a good policy.

As predicted, Figure 26(e) with a flat prior shows more variable results than Figure 25(e)

with a curved prior, especially for KGCB. This is because the random observations have greater

effect on future decisions in the case of an overly optimistic flat prior. Because the original prior

is flat, early observations significantly reshape the prior belief on revenue and consequently

induce more varied behavior for different sample paths . From Figure 26(e), it is also clear that

KGCB performs the best for the worst truths, DT performs the best for the best truths, and UCB

performs the best for the average truth from this diagram; possibly a result of KGCB picking

lower prices and DT picking mid- to high-range prices in early iterations of the simulation.

66

For a small number of measurements, DT exhibits the best behavior, but as the number of

measurements increases, UCB leads the other policies in Figure 26(f). One hypothesis for this

result is that UCB explores more in early iterations when we are very uncertain about the

alternative means, because it makes choices depending on which alternatives have not been

measured often. In the case of a flat prior, this is good initial behavior. As the entrepreneur

becomes more certain of which prices are the best, the “bonus factor” of the UCB policy becomes

relatively small and the entrepreneur exploits whatever alternative seems best. Thus, UCB offers

an optimal mix of exploration and exploitation in the case of a flat prior, but also needs a

significant number of iterations to attain this optimal blend. On the other hand, DT performs well

in the beginning by picking mid-range prices because of their high variability. As the number of

iterations increases, DT also begins to exploit its current beliefs because the combination of

observations and the linear belief structure encourages a revenue peak at mid-range prices.

However, because DT begins exploiting too early, as the number of iterations increases, its

performance becomes relatively weaker.

Because policies pick more varied prices in this situation with a flat prior, a pricing

restriction has more notable results than in the previous analysis with a quadratic prior and a clear

maximum. In Figure 27, we repeat the same analysis with a restricted pricing scheme.

67

Figure 27: Overly Optimistic Prior, Restricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

Week

Cash f

low

over

tim

e

Cash flow

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-300

-200

-100

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110-2000

-1500

-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-600

-400

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 27(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 27(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 27(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 27(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 27(d): Working Capital Figure 27(c): Cash Flow

68

All policies are more volatile with the restricted pricing scheme, but most of the general

behavior is the same as that of Figure 26 with the unrestricted prices. Relative behavior of

policies as well as the magnitude of cash flow and working capital estimates is the same, so we

only discuss the effect of increased volatility in price choices.

Each of the policies gives more variable average cash flow and working capital (Figures

27(c) and 27(d)) in early iterations using the restricted pricing scheme and furthermore takes

slightly longer to reach a steady revenue stream. This is because restricted pricing constrains the

entrepreneur to move his price slowly from week to week and thus forces more measurements of

poor alternatives in early iterations if the first revenue measurement was particularly low.

However, this also has long term benefits, as the entrepreneur on average reaches a higher

revenue stream than in the unrestricted case (compare Figures 27(c) and 26(c)). Just as the

KGCB algorithm generally samples more poor alternatives than DT in early iterations and later

outperforms DT because of the perspective gained by the initial exploration, so the entrepreneur

with restricted prices reaches a more optimal revenue in the long run than in the unrestricted case.

Figures 26(e) and 27(e) show that in the unrestricted case, KGCB demonstrates the most

volatile behavior, while in the restricted case, DT exhibits the most variation in cumulative profit.

One possible explanation for this occurrence is that the pricing restriction has more influence with

more look-ahead periods. That is, with a pricing restriction, DT’s initial prices are highly

dependent on the revenue observation in the first week, as this determines whether DT should

pick a higher or lower price in the following week. This decision impacts all future decisions,

and thus one random observation has great influence on the performance of the algorithm.

KGCB’s behavior is not as volatile with the restricted pricing scheme because KGCB does not

anticipate price restrictions in its algorithm.

69

5.2.3 Value Function Approximation vs. Look-ahead Policies

From this analysis, it appears that the value function approximation policies outperform

the look-ahead policies with good (truth) and bad (overly optimistic) priors on average. This is

perhaps counterintuitive, since the look-ahead policies are more mathematically complex as they

project into the future and use more sophisticated algorithms to make a decision. We then come

to the age old question - whether more complex processes necessarily imply better results.

However, the question is not as obvious as stated above. The “hard” part of KGCB and

DT is the looking forward and taking expectations of future rewards. The “hard” part of interval

estimation, Boltzmann exploration, and upper confidence bounding is the tuning of parameters to

yield optimal results. Without properly tuned parameters, all three policies can result in

arbitrarily poor performance. Thus, in practice the value function approximation policies are

much harder to implement, since we must have some notion of the truth distribution to adequately

simulate scenarios and pick the best parameters for each prior case. KGCB and DT, on the other

hand, require more computational power to calculate expectations, but are not contingent on a

parameter for their results.

Also, from the analysis of this chapter, it appears that an entrepreneur can make between

$10 and $18 per week on average in addition to his $10 weekly salary. These figures also include

loan payments, so after the first year of paying back his loan, the entrepreneur could make $40 to

$48 profits which are impressive in Africa. However, because of all the assumptions listed in

Chapter 2, we caution the reader to view the numerical results in this chapter not as definitive, but

rather as illustrative of a decision-making process and finding an optimal policy. Though profits

are also important, the numbers here are not as important as the methodology.

70

CHAPTER 6 Business Considerations

A successful business is not merely a product of rosy financial projections and optimal

pricing algorithms; it is rather the unity of an important problem and a viable solution in a

favorable context. In this chapter, we seek to shed light on the non-financial aspects of a solar

mobile charging enterprise using the framework of William Sahlman of Harvard Business School

(1999). Sahlman states that the primary “dynamic components” of the entrepreneurial process are

the people, opportunity, external context, and financial deal. Together, these four aspects paint a

vivid picture for the prospects of an actual business founded upon the principles already

mentioned in this thesis.

We begin with an evaluation using the four concepts proposed by Sahlman and conclude

with two case studies of actual solar charging businesses that have been formed on similar

concepts; one a formal NGO and the other an informal entrepreneurial venture. Together with the

more narrow scope of the previous chapters, this analysis gives a more balanced view of the

entrepreneurial process and shares insight from real solar efforts in Africa.

71

6.1 People: Who is involved

Venture capitalists often say they invest in people, not ideas. Any number of factors can

prevent a technology from succeeding, but even the best technology will not go to market with

the wrong entrepreneur handling day to day business. The primary quality in the ideal

entrepreneur to run this solar cell charging business is not necessarily experience or technical

expertise, but rather, creative adaptability. Because many factors are highly variable in this

scheme – the number of customers, the hours of sunlight, customer expectations – an

entrepreneur must be flexible in his dealings with customers. When a customer tries to negotiate

a charging price down to half in typical African fashion, the entrepreneur must strike a balance

between the customer’s expectations and his own. During a week of cloudy days, he must

prioritize which customers really need their cell phones charged at any given time and turn the

rest away to other vendors. When cash starts to run out, he must consider whether to move his

business to another area with higher demand or ask for more funding. When the competitor with

a battery on a bike starts undercutting his pricing scheme, he must be ready to retain customers in

another fashion; perhaps promote his business as safer for the user’s cell phone , run a special

charging deal for a week, or even allow customers to watch TV while their phones are charging.

To gain a substantial market share quickly, it is also imperative that the entrepreneur has

local connections. Personal ties cannot be understated in African culture and people consequently

often charge their phones with their friends or relatives. A successful entrepreneur, then, must be

familiar with his market and his market must be familiar with him.

Finally, an entrepreneur must be committed to this project as more than simply a money-

making business, although it will hopefully also be that. He must carry the vision of solar power

changing Africa and communicate this to his clients, allowing them to share a breakthrough

technology that will eventually revolutionize their way of life. In this way, people are attracted to

his business not only for its superior cost, but also for its excit ing and transformative prospects.

72

Looking ahead towards a larger goal, the entrepreneur is also motivated to continue in his

business even during rough periods with panel break-downs, lack of customers, or unanticipated

change in demand.

6.2 Opportunity: Customer, Market, and Competition

When evaluating potential opportunity in a business, broad market analysis is essential.

We first think realistically about the target customer’s needs and wants, and then proceed to

assess what structural aspects make the market easy or difficult to penetrate. To gain a further

understanding of how an entrepreneur can add and protect value in his enterprise, we lastly

provide a brief comparative cost analysis between solar and other charging options.

There are two potential customers for the solar mobile charging station. The first is the

individual cell phone user on whom we have focused most of the analysis thus far. Without

another source of electricity, an individual user charges his phone at the entrepreneur’s station for

a small fee. This user is highly sensitive to price, personal relationship with the entrepreneur, and

ability to charge other appliances.

The second less obvious customer that the entrepreneur should consider is a mobile

network operator. Since making a charging solution widely available has great potential to

increase an operator’s revenues, it is in the operator’s best interest to provide a low-cost charging

solution to allow users to talk more freely on their phones. An entrepreneur might also be able to

set up a deal with a local network operator wherein the latter subsidizes the charging station so

the former can undercut competing prices. The operator would allow the entrepreneur to keep

most of the charging profits and would make its pr imary revenue through increased air time from

customers. This arrangement is beneficial for both parties. With little investment besides cash,

the operator builds a green reputation by subsidizing a solar power solution in addition to a

73

sizable profit as mobile users spend more money on minutes. The entrepreneur, on the other

hand, obtains a base fee from the operator and gains both a steady customer base and a

distribution channel for his services.

The market for solar mobile phone charging is structurally attractive in some ways and

unattractive in others. Profit margins are quite high, since the marginal cost of selling another

charge is virtually zero when the sun is shining. Because a typical customer needs to recharge his

phone at least once per week, a good business is also likely to get many repeat customers once it

establishes itself in an area. Perhaps the most compelling part of the mobile charging market is

its unprecedented growth and geographic universality. By nature of the mobile revolution

throughout the developing world, if the business model is successful in one area, it can be easily

adapted to other sunny un-electrified areas of the world. The market opportunities are enormous;

GSMA (2010) estimates a $1.3 billion market in sub-Saharan Africa alone, and a $3.2 billion

market worldwide8.

Figure 28: International Market Opportunity for Mobile Charging (GSMA, 2010)

8 In the introduction, we cite another GSMA figure of a $2.3 billion market opportunity worldwide. Both

these numbers appear in GSMA publications from the same year (one estimates 500 million people with

mobile phones without electricity, another estimates 600 million). We can assume that one figure is more

conservative and the other is more optimistic.

74

Another favorable aspect of this enterprise is that the entrepreneur’s initial investment in

solar modules and related equipment is not restricted to mobile charging. If the entrepreneur

finds that cell phone charging is not in as high demand as he originally suspected, he can

purchase an inverter at fairly low cost and also allow customers to charge other appliances,

particularly lights and lamps. Though pricing schemes for such an operation are not mentioned in

this thesis, they could be derived in a similar fashion to the analysis in Chapters 2 and 3 as the

entrepreneur builds up a prior belief regarding the demand curve for other devices. This

versatility makes solar a particularly good investment.

The barrier to entry in the solar charging market is not unequivocally high or low. In

argument of a low barrier, initial capital costs just over $1000 are not so high that a fairly wealthy

local could not purchase his own solar panels and start his own business. It seems that only cash

or other financing options prohibit others from entering this fairly simple market. However,

considering that rich locals must have some other source of income to account for their wealth, it

is unlikely that they would have the time, desire, or commitment to invest in a start-up.

Furthermore, a relatively poor entrepreneur has a greater likelihood of succeeding in this industry

since he knows how to be frugal in his expenses and he knows more potential customers

personally, as a community’s lack of electricity tends to be highly related to poverty. Local

contacts, procurement of initial investment, and a commitment to protect and maintain solar

equipment consequently raise the barrier for other entrepreneurs to enter this industry.

From the perspective of a poor entrepreneur, the most unattractive aspects of the mobile

charging market are the high capital costs, high risk, and strong competition resulting from the

commodity nature of mobile charging. If an entrepreneur finds himself in an area where the he

simply cannot make enough profit to sustain himself because the market is too small or people are

unwilling to try a new technology, he has lost a great deal of cash. Though he can salvage his

75

costs by charging other products or selling his modules to a willing buyer, heavily front-loaded

costs are generally bad from a business perspective because the entrepreneur has more at stake in

the early stages of his enterprise.

Because a cell phone charge is a commodity good, only differentiated by price in most

customers’ minds, the entrepreneur has to introduce a new way to protect value in his enterprise

besides cost-competitiveness. In the African context, this value protection can be personal

customer ties, a reputation for quality charging, or versatility in other services.

In commodity markets, competition is generally fierce and cell phone charging is no

different. Competition from other off-grid sources can be strong in these emerging markets,

mostly from portable car batteries and diesel generators. Besides the obvious advantage that

equatorial Africa receives high-intensity sunlight for many hours each day, solar, however, does

possess significant quantitative and qualitative advantages over these two competitors. Solar

energy requires no additional fuel, can be easily scaled upwards by adding additional panels, and

calls for little day-to-day maintenance. In remote rural areas, the initial cost of a diesel generator

($0.65 per watt) is much lower than that of a solar system ($5 per watt), especially with the

purchase of a used generator. Despite early savings, the time and monetary costs of obtaining

fuel and performing oil and filter change maintenance quickly add up. Solar, on the other hand,

has a higher initial cost, but negligible operating cost.

Batteries are a popular option for cell charging entrepreneurs, because of the low initial

cost and portability. In the short term, when the rapidly changing environment makes

entrepreneurs fearful of longer term investments, a battery is a good choice. However, while this

current practice of charging a car battery in town and then selling the power to neighbors is most

pervasive at present, high operating costs to repeatedly charge the battery from a third party and

short battery lifetimes yield significant expenses over time. Though batteries under ideal

76

conditions can last up to five years, improper usage and external factors such as weather often

reduce lifetimes to one or two years in Africa (Hankins, 1995).

To obtain a brief cost comparison of the three technologies, assume the following:

Initial cost of a diesel generator is $0.65 per watt new, $0.35 per watt used (OffGridKnowHow.com, 2002).

Initial cost of solar panels and installation is $5 per watt (Limpaecher, 2011). Operating costs are slightly less than 1% of the initial cost per year.

Wattage of a comparable diesel generator is at least four times that of a solar panel, assuming the solar panel gets four hours of sunlight per day

9.

A generator takes ½ liter of fuel to produce 1 kWh of electricity (Solar Electric Light Fund, 2008).

Diesel costs $1 per liter in Mauritania (Index Mundi, 2011).

Diesel generators sell power to entrepreneurs with batteries at a premium of $0.25 per kWh.

The entrepreneur does business 250 days in the year. Each day, he needs to produce 1 kWh of electricity.

The real discount rate is 5%.

Solar Battery Diesel

Generator

Size 250W 12V 1 kW

Initial Capital Expenditure

$1,250.00 $75.00 $350.00

Cost per kWh negligible $0.75 $0.50

Lifetime (years) 20 3 20 Table 7: Solar vs. Battery vs. Generator Assumptions

9 A conservative estimate for sunlight hours

77

YEAR Solar CD10 Solar

Battery CD

Battery Diesel

Generator CD

Generator

0 $1,250.00 $1,250.00 $262.50 $262.50 $350.00 $350.00

1 $10.00 $1,259.52 $187.50 $441.07 $125.00 $469.05

2 $10.00 $1,268.59 $187.50 $611.14 $125.00 $582.43

3 $10.00 $1,277.23 $262.50 $837.90 $125.00 $690.41

4 $10.00 $1,285.46 $187.50 $992.15 $125.00 $793.24

5 $10.00 $1,293.29 $187.50 $1,139.06 $125.00 $891.18

6 $10.00 $1,300.76 $262.50 $1,334.95 $125.00 $984.46

7 $10.00 $1,307.86 $187.50 $1,468.20 $125.00 $1,073.30

8 $10.00 $1,314.63 $187.50 $1,595.11 $125.00 $1,157.90

9 $10.00 $1,321.08 $262.50 $1,764.32 $125.00 $1,238.48

10 $10.00 $1,327.22 $187.50 $1,879.42 $125.00 $1,315.22

11 $10.00 $1,333.06 $187.50 $1,989.05 $125.00 $1,388.30

12 $10.00 $1,338.63 $262.50 $2,135.22 $125.00 $1,457.91

13 $10.00 $1,343.94 $187.50 $2,234.66 $125.00 $1,524.20

14 $10.00 $1,348.99 $187.50 $2,329.36 $125.00 $1,587.33

15 $10.00 $1,353.80 $262.50 $2,455.62 $125.00 $1,647.46

16 $10.00 $1,358.38 $187.50 $2,541.52 $125.00 $1,704.72

17 $10.00 $1,362.74 $187.50 $2,623.33 $125.00 $1,759.26

18 $10.00 $1,366.90 $262.50 $2,732.40 $125.00 $1,811.20

19 $10.00 $1,370.85 $187.50 $2,806.60 $125.00 $1,860.67

20 $10.00 $1,374.62 $187.50 $2,877.27 $125.00 $1,907.78 Table 8: Solar vs. Battery vs. Generator Comparison

The highlighted portions of the chart show that in this simplified analysis, solar is more

cost-effective than a lead-acid battery after six years and more cost-effective than a diesel

generator after eleven years. Over time, the solar entrepreneur’s profit margins are higher than

his competitors and he can offer lower prices. In the short-term, however, if an entrepreneur

hopes to ride the wave of cell phone charging demand, a battery is the best option.

As a long-term investment, solar equipment is a worthwhile purchase. The entrepreneur

must first find a feasible market with a clear demand for mobile charging or with a viable

network operator partner. In a highly uniform industry where cell phone charging is a commodity,

he must think of ways to protect value in his enterprise by offering superior prices or additional

10

CD refers to the cumulative discounted cost

78

services for his customers. If the charging market evaporates suddenly with the introduction of a

large electricity provider, the entrepreneur must adapt to the changing environment and diversify

his offerings accordingly or in extreme circumstances, sell his panels and seek another area to

establish the same type of business.

6.3 Context: African Entrepreneurship

Starting a business in Africa is quite a different experience than starting a business in

America. In a study on “Ethnic Entrepreneurship”, Mitchell of South Africa’s University of

Natal states that financing, labor regulations, crime, and theft are the most problematic practical

policy aspects to African new businesses establishment (2003). Perhaps the most unusual barrier

to African entrepreneurship is a sector of customers quick to vandalize, steal, and criticize new

technology. An entrepreneur has to be especially wary of theft when he carries expensive pieces

of equipment such as solar modules that can be pawned for cash. Numerous horror stories detail

the potential dangers of starting a business in Africa: angry customers who destroyed a generator

after the power went off for a night, vandals who clipped wires to protest rising electricity prices,

unofficial customers who hacked the grid connection to add a wire to their own home for free

electricity access (Limpaecher, 2011).

The IFC and World Bank ranked Mauritania 152 out of 183 world economies in the ease

of starting a business (2011). The most apparent reason for the low rating is that Mauritania

requires an entrepreneur to deposit slightly under $4000 in a bank or notary before registration

and up to three months after incorporation. Though this paid-in capital figure is not high

objectively, it relatively represents 412% of Mauritania’s GNI (gross national income) per capita,

most likely a result of a weak banking system coupled with a fear of bad start-ups. However,

these metrics are for small to medium start-ups funded by traditional loans from banks; so the

79

entrepreneur could hopefully avoid some of the regulations by obtaining a microfinance loan or a

personal loan from friends.

6.4 Deal: Financing Decisions

Assuming the entrepreneur has little or no cash of his own, there are three primary

options for the entrepreneur to fund his initial capital expenditures. The entrepreneur can pay for

his solar module and other equipment via a loan from friends and family, a bank, or a

microfinance institution. A loan from family or friends is certainly the most flexible option, but

the entrepreneur does not receive the same advice, training, and accountability he would obtain

from a microfinance institution. If the entrepreneur takes a loan from personal friends, he also

has more at stake than just monetary investment in his company. If he fails to provide a positive

return on his friends’ investment, he also jeopardizes their welfare and possibly their relationship.

Compared to a microfinance institution, the entrepreneur may save on interest payments

with a commercial bank. Nevertheless, there are unfortunately other drawbacks besides even

outrageously high paid-in minimum capital laws. Because there are only ten commercial banks

in all of Mauritania according to the Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (2011), obtaining a

loan may be near-impossible if the entrepreneur has little credit history. As only 0.1% of

Mauritanian adults have data in the past five years listed the public credit registry (World Bank &

IFC, 2011), it is extremely difficult to take out a loan. Even if the entrepreneur is able to procure

credit, his legal rights are minimal should the lending institution declare bankruptcy.

With a microfinance institution, the entrepreneur receives business training and support,

but also must pay back his loan with high interest on a very strict schedule. Though the regular

check-ups and loan repayments encourage the entrepreneur to be disciplined about making his

business thrive quickly, these additional responsibilities from the lending institution make

80

microfinance loans especially expensive to disburse. As a result, interest rates on microfinance

loans are notoriously high.

We summarize the important aspects of the different financing options below. One way

to view Table 9 is that the financing structures are arranged from top to bottom as the most to

least preferable, but also the most to least difficult to obtain. A personal loan, or even better, a

business founded entirely from personal savings requires the entrepreneur to pay back little or no

interest on a loose schedule. A bank loan offers medium interest rates conditional on the

entrepreneur’s credit history, while a microfinance institution offers the highest interest rates, but

also can provide loans to poor entrepreneurs with little financial history.

Interest Rate Time to pay back

loan

Loan from family/friends

0%-10%11 indefinite12

Loan from bank 10-30%13 1-5 years14

Loan from microfinance lender

30-40%15 1-2 years16

Table 9: Loan Options

Yet, interest rates should not be the only deciding factor in the entrepreneur’s decision.

There is also something to be said for the work ethic and discipline that comes with managing

someone else’s money and staying on a predictable schedule. Because of this, the entrepreneur

should think carefully through the options given his past experience running a business and his

current personal financial situation.

11

Estimated 12

Estimated 13

Estimated; bank lending rates were unavailab le 14

Estimated 15

KIVA, 2011 16

Field & Pande, 2007

81

6.5 Two Case Studies

It is difficult to imagine the potential successes and downfalls of a solar business in

Africa without concrete examples. We now draw lessons from two African enterprises that have

successfully sold electricity to locals using solar panels. The first is a local entrepreneur in

Mauritania and the second is a large NGO in West Africa.

6.5.1 Bababé Entrepreneur

Although reality is never as exact as numerical assumptions, it is promising to see that

actual entrepreneurs have undertaken similar small-scale solar enterprises in recent years. In

1991, a local entrepreneur in Bababé, Mauritania, Abdoulaye Ba, bought two solar panels for

approximately $180 (USD) each to light his home with renewable energy. The panels had the

capacity to run five lights or three lights and a TV. Ba began an unofficial movie theater business,

charging locals to watch soccer games from his television.

As cell phones became more and more prevalent, neighbors demanded a paid charging

service in 2005. In response, Ba added two larger solar panels to his existing modules for $400

(USD) each. On average, ten customers came to Ba each day to charge their phones for $0.20

each. With a burgeoning cell phone market and a stagnant electricity supply, it was the ideal time

to start a charging business in Bababé. From rudimentary supply and demand, we know that

when demand shifts outward from to and supply remains the same, equilibrium price and

quantity both increase, as in Figure 29(a). Thus, when Ba later increased the price per charge to

$0.40, he actually had more customers than in early stages of the business as a result of the sharp

increase in demand for electricity.

82

Figure 29: Changes in Demand and Supply in the Market for Cell Phone Charging

Recently, large electrification advances were made in Bababé, and the supply for cell

phone charging increased from to in Figure 29(b). As a result, equilibrium quantity rose,

but price fell from to . Because Ba did not solely depend on the charging business for his

income, he was not as intent on finding the profit maximizing price as the hypothetical

entrepreneur presented in the thesis, and he continued to charge the same $0.40 per phone. As

expected, demand consequently dropped to only five customers from remote villages per month.

Over time as the business became less profitable, Ba sold all but one of the panels for roughly

half of the original purchase price. Today, he keeps his remaining panel to light his home and run

his makeshift movie theater.

As illustrated by Ba’s experiences, a business-savvy entrepreneur must be highly aware

of changing infrastructure and changing consumer tastes. Supply and demand can shift at any

time based on the actions of the government, a network operator, or a nearby NGO. We can

capture this in our simulation model by using non-stationary demand and supply distributions,

wherein the true demand and supply change week by week with or without a general trend.

However, the actual dynamics of an expanded cell phone network or the advent of electricity in a

community are very difficult to predict mathematically. It is often better to adapt according to the

Figure 29(a): Increased Demand Figure 29(b): Increased Supply

83

information one gathers day by day than to err on the overly cautious side by accounting for a

shifts in supply and demand during every time period.

The greatest threat to the cell phone charging business is a shift in electricity supply.

With a new generator in town or a new series of wires strung from a nearby village, villagers can

purchase the electricity needed to charge a phone for a few cents. A business founded upon cell

phone charging is then obsolete unless the entrepreneur can make some quick changes. He has at

least two options: first, to terminate the business and sell the solar panels and second, to tweak his

business to offer a different service such as charging batteries for lanterns. Ba did a combination

of the two. Note, however, that by 2009 estimates, 85.7% of rural sub-Saharan Africa still live

without access to electricity (IEA), and even with the UN’s Millennium Development Goal to

eradicate extreme hunger and poverty by 2015 by providing electricity to 395 million people

worldwide, gaping infrastructure needs will still leave the majority without electricity. Thus, this

need for cell phone charging is not likely to be eliminated completely in the near future.

It is also important to consider the benefit of diversifying service offerings to protect

against such a market shift in supply. Ba charged batteries and ran a TV for profit in addition to

charging cell phones. Each of these offerings has a different consumer base and a different

barrier to entry. While businessmen and young people are the primary customers for cell phone

charging, TV services appeal to the non-working sector during the day and virtually everyone in

the evening. Lighting needs are also universal. Because running a television or charging a

battery requires more energy than charging a cell phone, it is more difficult for another

entrepreneur to offer the same service. Furthermore, a TV is another high initial cost that

prevents others from running a home movie theater. In contrast, there is not considerable

distinction in the cell phone charging market; as long as the battery is charged properly,

customers get the same service with any entrepreneur. A movie theater, on the other hand, has

84

more opportunity for the entrepreneur to offer superior service by providing concessions,

showing the most exciting soccer matches, or attracting the biggest crowd.

6.5.2 Energy For Opportunity

Specializing in small scale solar installation, Energy For Opportunity (EFO) was founded

in 2009 by two social entrepreneurs passionate about spreading solar throughout West Africa.

Simon Willans and Paul Munro first met while working on renewable energy projects in Sierra

Leone, Liberia, and Uganda and now focus on a holistic approach to renewable energy adoption

in Benin, Mali, and Sierra Leone, eventually hoping to expand services throughout West Africa.

While many organizations are focused strictly on installing solar panels, EFO takes a longer term

attitude, training students to use solar technology in conjunction with local schools and

encouraging government and international offices to adopt solar as well.

EFO’s four primary areas of focus are Skills Training, Development and Livelihoods,

Education, and Health. Their current Development and Livelihoods project is a community

charging initiative in which they hope to establish ten solar stations in Benin and then transfer

ownership to trained members of the community. Although EFO provides initial funding, they

seek to build self-sustaining enterprises that not only generate profit for the local owners of the

stations, but also reduce dependence on kerosene and batteries in the communities. EFO is more

than just a solar-focused micro-finance lending institution; the organization procures initial

equipment and provides complete training for the entrepreneur in business management and solar

maintenance. Because EFO already has contacts in communities, they are able to tailor

community charging applications specifically for local needs; allowing a particular focus on

lighting, cell phone charging, radios, or the most imminent and popular appliances. EFO seeks to

raise $100,000 for this project, which is considerably more than our estimates for ten individual

mobile charging enterprises because of the greater capacity and wider range of services provided.

85

Since EFO is a non-profit organization funded primarily by grants and contracts, it is not

as dependent on revenue streams as an individual entrepreneur’s business. Only 2% of their total

revenue in 2009-2010 came from sales, because most of the emphasis was on contract jobs for

hospitals and government buildings rather than on projects that brought direct revenue from

consumers. EFO’s first year of operation is certainly not representative of the future of the

company, however, it nonetheless illustrates the general principle that a non-profit has

significantly different objectives and much more flexible funding than an individual entrepreneur.

Although we have focused primarily on a small-scale for-profit business thus far, it is

helpful to also consider the option of a more broad non-profit founded upon the same principles.

A large non-profit has the capacity to engage more in-depth in communities, work toward long-

term change in attitudes towards renewable energy, and obtain funds from governments and

donors. Optimal pricing is not as important in this context, since the chief goal is not profit, but

rather long-term introduction of renewable energy in developing communities.

86

CHAPTER 7 Conclusion

Opportunity creation is the goal of modern innovation. Cell phones create opportunity

for the users by increasing communication efficiency and eliminating third party intervention in

commerce and banking. Solar creates opportunity for a developing nation by allowing villages to

meet small electrification needs with micro-grids rather than wait for a big electricity company to

expand the grid where infrastructure is lacking. A solar cell phone charging business creates

opportunity for an entrepreneur by providing personal profit and business development while

simultaneously promoting the positive externalities of both cell phones and solar power in the

community.

The goal of this thesis was to maximize the opportunity created by a solar micro-grid

charging enterprise. We obtained not only numerical estimates of profit in different scenarios,

but also established a general structure guiding the entrepreneur’s decision making process from

the creation of the prior belief to policy optimization to real business considerations. In reality,

most decisions are made with fairly simple policies that mix exploration and exploitation

according to the decision maker’s self-confidence and risk-aversion. However, in an increasingly

technological world where more and more “easy” decisions are being made by computers, it is

instructive to see how well selection algorithms compare to human intuition and to one another.

87

With this analysis, we understand the pros and cons of various policies in a diverse range of

scenarios.

7.1 Main Findings

From basic cost-revenue analysis, we learned that mobile charging is a highly lucrative

market with significant unmet demand. Even in our most conservative analysis, with the right

policy, the entrepreneur can make profits in the first year of his enterprise while still paying off

his initial loan.

In the worst case analysis where the entrepreneur received minimal revenue each week,

KGCB and DT performed slightly above the other policies. Pure exploitation, of course, behaved

the worst because revenues in the truth were lower than revenues in the prior.

For a good prior which closely resembled the truth, all policies performed well without

much variation over many truths. With the exception of pure exploitation which continued to

sample the same alternative even with belief-updating, all policies found optimal or near-optimal

alternatives fairly quickly. KGCB had a tendency to pick lower prices in early iterations, which

affected its initial performance negatively.

For a bad prior which assumed all prices yielded the same revenue, the entrepreneur’s

average profit was significantly lower than average profit with a good prior, most notably in early

iterations of the algorithm. Out of all the policies, pure exploitation suffered the most with a bad

prior. Just as in reality, one should not strictly follow intuition, so in our model, we learned that

over many truth possibilities, pure exploitation is a poor policy.

The restricted pricing scheme had the most effect in the bad prior case when choices were

naturally more volatile as the entrepreneur’s intuition was incorrect. Restrictions increased the

number of iterations needed to find the optimal price for nearly all policies and also introduced

88

higher variability to DT, which projected restrictions into the future and was subsequently highly

dependent on the first few sample observations.

In the average case analysis over many truths, UCB performed the best with all four

priors tested, but most significantly for priors that were overly optimistic or pessimistic. While

the policies with tunable parameters slightly outperformed the look-ahead policies for bad priors,

they also required tuning for each possible prior, which assumed foreknowledge of the truth

distribution. If an entrepreneur was to actually enter an area with a poor prior and a poor tunable

parameter, the look-ahead policies would certainly outperform the tunable policies.

From a business perspective, it is best to broaden notions of the customer market and also

consider deals directly with mobile network operators or existing cell phone companies. Solar

has great potential in Africa, but its success in the cell phone charging industry is highly

contingent on finding the right entrepreneurs who are adaptable to the rapidly changing

environment. The same swift evolution that makes revenue projections so unpredictable and

consequently introduces immense uncertainty for an investor also creates a wealth of unexplored

market opportunities for entrepreneurs.

7.2 Assumptions Revisited and Future Research

As illuminated by the strictly business analysis of Chapter 6, the most unrealistic

assumption in our model was that the entrepreneur only meets one type of demand with his solar

panels. Both business models in the case studies diversif ied offerings to hedge against the

possibility of a steep increase in electricity supply or a new cell phone technology that eliminates

the need for traditional charging. Although this assumption of only meeting cell phone charging

demand lent to a more reliable prior belief as the number of variables and estimation quantities

were minimized, it also restricted the entrepreneur’s ability to enter other markets.

89

However, this assumption is not as impractical as it may seem. Our mathematical model

was never meant to be taken as a holistic business plan, but rather, as a framework to examine a

particular type of decision making process. If unmet cell phone charging demand is high enough,

a specialty charging shop that only charges cell phones could be very successful for a short period

of time. When new entrepreneurs jump into the market or the village gains access to a new large-

scale generator or charging station, the entrepreneur then has enough capital to purchase extra

inverters and batteries to offer unique services such as TV or even refrigeration. He can perform

the same analysis to build up a prior belief and use a policy to make pricing decisions in the new

market as well.

Throughout our model, we also assumed that the entrepreneur could change price freely

from week to week. Though we partially remedied this vast simplification by introducing a

restricted decision set in all the policies, there are other ways we could further refine this

assumption and reflect it accurately in our model. Future research could either re-derive all the

policies to restrict pricing sets or account for user pricing psychology by introducing some

penalty factor for changing price by a large amount. True demand could be a non-stationary

function of the change in last week’s price to this week’s price, such that angry customers would

avoid a business if it sharply increased the price from last week or grateful customers would

return if the business sharply decreased the price from last week. If DT was modified to reflect

this non-stationary assumption, it would most likely outperform the other policies as it would

possess the ability anticipate a future reward from gradually decreasing one’s price.

Practically, the most imminent future topic of research regarding this business is actual

field data. Although data for costs and revenues were gathered as averages through online

sources and a few local contacts, it is likely that government subsidies or socially conscious

suppliers might offer discounts that would drive down the high initial cost of solar panels in

Africa. Concerning demand estimates, nothing can compare to the experience of actually starting

90

such a business and viewing the consumer market firsthand. From a simulation window, we only

see demands, revenues and costs; from a ground perspective, we see the real charging needs of

people and the tangible change that cell phones bring to rural communities.

There are many other questions proposed in this model that could be examined in a

rigorous mathematical framework. We could solve for an optimal stopping policy for the

entrepreneur. After how many weeks of consistently low revenue should the entrepreneur decide

that his best option is to either fold the business or move to another location? If customers arrive

faster than they can be serviced, we could calculate queuing statistics such as the average wait

time in line for a customer, or the utilization rate of the entrepreneur’s charging outlets. These

are only a few of the other approaches one could take to this problem.

7.3 Final Thoughts

A solar mobile charging system in Africa has potential not only to facilitate the adoption

of a clean renewable energy source to a developing continent, but also to bring profit to the

entrepreneur himself. Though starting a new enterprise is a multi-faceted undertaking whose

success is contingent on both exogenous and endogenous factors to the entrepreneur, by

providing policies for the optimal pricing problem, we give the reader a taste of one of the many

challenges in entering an emerging market such as this. With a policy that creates a metric to

evaluate price alternatives besides just their expected revenue, the entrepreneur has a high

likelihood of finding the profit-maximizing price. Though tunable policies performed best in

simulation, look-ahead policies are easier to implement in reality.

Neither cell phones nor solar technology are Africa’s “silver bullet” of development.

However, by continually thinking of new ways to use cell phones to practically bridge

91

communication gaps and inefficiencies, and by slowly introducing solar as a viable energy

source, we stand at the cusp of a an exciting epoch in world history.

92

WORKS CITED

"African Mobile Subscriber Growth and Penetration, 1998-2010." Africa & The Middle East Telecom 11.3 (2010). January 22, 2011.

Aker, Jenny C. and Issac M. Mbiti. "Africa Calling: Can Mobile Phones make a Miracle?" Boston

Review, March/April 2010. October 12, 2010. Auer, P., Cesa-Bianchi, N. & Fischer, P. "Finite-Time Analysis of the Multiarmed Bandit

Problem." Machine Learning 47.2-3 (2002): 235,235-256. Ba, Ibrahima. Personal Communication, 2011. Breiman, L., J. H. Friedman, R. A. Olshen, and C. J. Stone. Classification and Regression Trees.

Belmont, CA: Wadsworth International Group, 1984. "Charge controllers and regulators for PV systems." Wind & Sun.

<http://www.windsun.com/ChargeControls/ChargeCont.htm>. "Compare Solar Panels Before You Buy." Wholesale Solar. 2011.

<http://www.wholesalesolar.com/solar-panels.html>. Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP). "Market Intelligence." CGAP. 2011.

<http://www.cgap.org/p/site/c/template.rc/1.26.2301/>. Edwards, Nizette. Personal Communication, 2011. "Energy for Opportunity." 2011. <http://www.energyforopportunity.org/about/>. Ewing, Jack. "Upwardly Mobile in Africa." Bloomberg Businessweek. September 24, 2007.

January 22, 2011. Field, Erica and Rohini Pande. "Repayment Frequency and Default in Microfinance: Evidence

from India." Institute for Financial Management and Research: Centre for Micro Finance 20 (2007). March 30, 2011.

Frazier, Peter et al. "The Knowledge-Gradient Policy for Correlated Normal Beliefs." INFORMS

Journal on Computing 21.4 (2009): 599-613. Friedman, J. H. "A Recursive Partitioning Decision Rule for Nonparametric Classification."

Computers, IEEE Transactions on C-26.4 (1977): 404-8. Giridharadas, Anand. "Where a Cellphone is Still Cutting Edge." New York Times. Week in

Review: WK4. April 10, 2010. January 23, 2011. Gittins, J. C. and D. M. Jones. "A Dynamic Allocat ion Index for the Sequential Design of

Experiments." Progress in Statistics. Ed. J. Gani., 1974. 241-266.

93

Gope, Gideon. "A Review of the Photovoltaic Industry and its Development in Africa." Solar Energy 59.4-6 (1997): 217-25.

GSMA Development Fund. Green Power for Mobile: Charging Choices. GSMA Development

Fund, 2010. January 15, 2011. GSMA. "Off-Grid Market Sizing." Green Power for Mobile. 2010.

<http://www.gsmworld.com/our-work/mobile_planet/green_power_for_mobile/off-grid_market_sizing%20.htm>.

Gupta, Shanti S., and Klaus J. Miescke. "Bayesian Look Ahead One-Stage Sampling Allocations

for Selection of the Best Population." Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 54.2 (1996): 229-44.

Hankins, Mark. Solar Electric Systems for Africa. London: Commonwealth Science Council,

1995. Hughes, Nick and Susie Lonie. "M-PESA: Mobile Money for the “Unbanked"." Innovations

(2009). January 23, 2011. International Energy Agency. World Energy Outlook 2010., 2010. The Electricity Access

Database. November 20, 2010. International Telecommunication Union. ICT Indicators Database. 14th ed. Geneva, Switzerland:

International Telecommunication Union, 2010. January 27, 2011. ---. "ITU Sees 5 Billion Mobile Subscriptions Globally in 2010." February 15, 2010. January 22,

2011. Jensen, Robert. "The Digital Provide: Information (Technology), Market Performance, and

Welfare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector." Quarterly Journal of Economics 122.3 (2007): 879-924.

Kalba, Kas. "The Adoption of Mobile Phones in Emerging Markets: Global Diffusion and the

Rural Challenge." International Journal of Communications (2008): 631. KIVA. "About Microfinance." 2011. <http://cgap.org>. March 19, 2011. Knier, Gil. "How do Photovoltaics Work?" NASA Science, 2002. January 26, 2011. Lenardic, Denis. "Photovoltaic economics." January 22, 201.

<http://www.pvresources.com/en/economics.php>. Mali Report. Ed. Mali-Folkecenter and AREED, 1998. March 18, 2011. "Mauritania - pump price for diesel fuel." Index Mundi. 2008.

<http://www.indexmundi.com/facts/mauritania/pump-price-for-diesel-fuel>. Middleton, James. "Africa Crosses 500 Million Mobile Subs Mark." Telecoms.com . November

10, 2010. January 22, 2011.

94

Mingers, John. "An Empirical Comparison of Pruning Methods for Decision Tree Induction." Machine Learning 4.2 (1989): 227-243.

Mitchell, Bruce. "Ethnic Entrepreneurship: Preliminary Findings from a South African Study."

Journal of Small Business and Entrepreneurship 17.1 (2003): 47-62. March 29, 2011. MIT. "Why Africa?" Entrepreneurial Programming and Research on Mobiles (EPROM). 2009.

September 22, 2010 <http://media.mit.edu/ventures/EPROM/whyafrica.html>. NASA. Earth at Night. 2009. NASA Images. January 25, 2011. Pellerin, Cheryl. "World Governments to Discuss Radio-Frequency Airwaves in October."

America.gov, sec. Science/Technology: October 17, 2007. January 23, 2011. Pouris, Anastassios. "The Cost of Photovoltaic Cells in South Africa." Energy (Oxford, England)

12 (1987): 117-21. Powell, Warren B. and Ilya Ryzhov. Optimal Learning. Hoboken: Wiley, 2010. Powell, Warren B. "Modeling Dynamic Programs." Approximate Dynamic Programming. 2nd ed.

John Wiley & Sons, Inc, 2010. Quinlan, J. R. C4.5: Programs for Machine Learning. San Mateo, CA: Morgan Kaufmann, 1993. Quinlan, J. R. "Induction of Decision Trees." Machine Learning 1.1 (1986): 81-106. Rosenthal, Elizabeth. "African Huts Far from the Grid Glow with Renewable Power." New York

Times (2010). January 5, 2011. Ryzhov, Ilya O. et al. "The Knowledge Gradient Algorithm for a General Class of Online

Learning Problems." Operations Research (To appear). April 10, 2010. Sahlman, William. "Some Thoughts on Business Plans." The Entrepreneurial Venture. 2nd ed.

USA: Harvard Business School Press, 1999. 138-176. Smith, David. "Mobiles Give Africa's Farmers the Chance to Set Out their Stall." Guardian

January 4, 2009. January 24, 2011. Sohani, Mohsin. Personal Communication, 2011. Solar Electric Light Fund (SELF). A Cost and Reliability Comparison between Solar and Diesel

Powered Pumps., 2008. March 28, 2011. "Solar Panel Price Comparison." Solar For Energy. 2011. <http://www.solar-for-

energy.com/solar-panel-price.html>. "Solar Panels." Silicon Solar. 2011. <http://www.siliconsolar.com/solar-panels.html>. "Solar Power vs. A Diesel Generator." OffGridKnowHow.com. 2002.

<http://www.homepower.htmlplanet.com/solar-vs-diesel-generators.html>.

95

Taverner, David. Green Power for Mobile: Community Power. GSMA, 2010. November 14,

2010. US Energy Information Administration. "FAQ: Electricity." 2010.

<http://www.eia.doe.gov/ask/electricity_faqs.asp#electricity_use_home>. Utgoff, Paul. "Decision Trees." MIT Cognet Library. 2010.

<http://cognet.mit.edu/library/erefs/mitecs/utgoff.html>. World Bank & IFC. "Doing Business: Measuring Business Regulations." 2011.

<http://www.doingbusiness.org/data/exploreeconomies/mauritania/#starting-a-business>. Young, Barbara. Quick Way to Learn how Solar Power Works, 2010. January 26, 2011.

96

APPENDIX

We analyze the various policies using the same metrics as those in Chapter 5 to compare

policies over many truths with the other two priors proposed in Chapter 3: the linear prior as a

“good” prior and the pessimistic prior as a “bad” prior. Because the results with the linear prior

are almost identical to those of the truth prior, we omit analysis here, but we do provide insight

into the behavior of the overly pessimistic prior.

97

Appendix 1 Linear Prior

Figure 30: Linear Prior, Unrestricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 504

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Week

Cash f

low

Cash flow over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

40 50 60 70 80 90 100-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1000

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 30 (a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 30(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 30(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 30(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 30(d): Working Capital Figure 30(c): Cash Flow

98

Figure 31: Linear Prior, Restricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 504

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Week

Cash f

low

over

tim

e

Cash flow

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

40 50 60 70 80 90 100-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1000

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

2000

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 31(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 31(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 31(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 31(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 31(d): Working Capital Figure 31(c): Cash Flow

99

Appendix 2 Pessimistic Prior

Figure 32: Pessimistic Prior, Unrestricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-20

-10

0

10

20

30

40

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

Week

Cash f

low

Cash flow over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-200

-100

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

40 50 60 70 80 90 100-1500

-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-400

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 32(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 32(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 32(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 32(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 32(d): Working Capital Figure 32(c): Cash Flow

100

Perhaps the most notable aspect of the pessimistic prior result is the “hiccup” in the

KGCB policy near week 20. When KGCB realizes it is already half-way through the simulation

period, it tries a few other prices in hopes of finding a new maximum. This only occurs in the

pessimistic prior scenario, not the optimistic prior scenario. One possible explanation is that

KGCB finds that all the prices measured so far yield much higher revenues than originally

expected, so the algorithm is more willing to try new prices even after 20 measurements. Recall

that KGCB maximizes the amount of learning we can gain from measuring a certain price, so

after measuring many alternatives that greatly improved our belief means, it wants to try the

remaining prices. Although it measures a few poor alternatives, it eventually finds a price that

yields higher revenue than the previous optimum, and then performs on par with DT until the end

of the business. DT does not exhibit the same behavior, because it projects three periods into the

future and does not account for how many weeks are left in the simulation, except when it reaches

the very last iterations.

The extremely volatile pure exploitation behavior is also illustrative of pure

exploitation’s susceptibility to the first random revenue observation with a flat prior far below the

truth. Because the first observation is inevitably higher than expected, pure exploitation

continues to sample alternatives near the first. Depending on how high the observation is, pure

exploitation can have very different behavior for the remainder of the algorithm.

If we did not update parameters, but instead updated correlated alternatives, the

performance of all the algorithms would be much worse. Since the prior is overly pessimistic,

almost any price would yield a much higher observation than expected, encouraging the

entrepreneur to continue measuring the same price over and over again. This is a taste of what

happens in the pure exploitation case, but still not as extreme as it would be with a non-

parametric belief structure.

101

Figure 33: Pessimistic Prior, Restricted Decisions

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

KGCBLin vs DecTree

KGCBLin - DecTree

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

Week

Diffe

rence in c

ash f

low

All Policies vs Exploitation

KGCBLin - Exploitation

DecTree - Exploitation

Boltzmann - Exploitation

IE - Exploitation

UCB - Exploitation

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

Week

Cash f

low

over

tim

e

Cash flow

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 500

100

200

300

400

500

600

Week

Work

ing C

aptial

Working Capital over time

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110-2000

-1000

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

Maximum Revenue

Cum

ula

tive P

rofit

Cumulative Profit as a function of Max Revenue

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 1000

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

N (number of weeks)

Avera

ge c

um

ula

tive p

rofit

Average cumulative profit

KGCBLin

DecTree

Exploitation

Boltzmann

IE

UCB

Figure 33(a): KGCB vs. DT Figure 33(b): All policies vs. Exploitation

Figure 33(f): N week profit as fn. of N Figure 33(e): 50 week profit as fn. of max revenue

Figure 33(d): Working Capital Figure 33(c): Cash Flow

102

The observations about the unrestricted algorithms are assuaged by the pricing restriction.

The aberrant KGCB behavior is lessened in this case when KGCB cannot choose such extreme

prices to sample. Similarly, exploitation behavior is also much more stable with restricted prices

because its choices are less variable.