AN ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF...

139
AN ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA Word count: 31.298 Korneel Merchiers Student number : 01205083 Promotor/ Supervisor: Prof. dr. Broos Maenhout Commissioner: Drs. Thuzar Linn Master’s Dissertation submitted to obtain the degree of : Master of Science in Business Engineering: Operations Management Academic year: 2016 - 2017

Transcript of AN ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF...

AN ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN

OF QUINOA

Word count: 31.298

Korneel Merchiers Student number : 01205083

Promotor/ Supervisor: Prof. dr. Broos Maenhout

Commissioner: Drs. Thuzar Linn

Master’s Dissertation submitted to obtain the degree of:

Master of Science in Business Engineering: Operations Management

Academic year: 2016 - 2017

CONFIDENTIALITY AGREEMENT I declare that the content of this Master’s Dissertation may be consulted and/or reproduced, provided that the source is referenced. Name student : Korneel Merchiers Signature

I

Abstract

Agriculture plays an important role in less developed countries. People need agriculture to be

able to feed themselves and survive. Besides this, agriculture is also responsible for the em-

ployment and revenues of a lot of local populations in these countries. Often, the productivity

of agriculture in less developed countries does not live up to its full potential. Links and pro-

portions in the value chain are not optimal and are often fragmented. In such less developed

countries, farmers face the problem of having to sell their products at too low prices. On the

other hand, too high prices are set for consumers. When applied to Quinoa, it is clear that all

these facets occur. When farmers discovered that quinoa could be cultivated on less nutritious

fields, the production started to grow. The last couple of years, the production of quinoa is re-

ally booming. This resulted in the year 2013 being named as “The international year of quinoa”.

Although Peru and Bolivia are among the poorest nations in Latin-America, more than half of

the global supply of quinoa is actually coming from these countries. It was in the early 2000s

that Western nations discovered Quinoa. Since then, the demand has risen and so has the price.

Peru and Bolivia’s gross domestic product have only benefited from this. A question that often

comes to mind is “How long can Peru and Bolivia depend on quinoa as the agent of their pros-

perity?”. Quinoa-growing farmers could no longer afford to eat the crops themselves because

the price tripled but is now again decreasing. Domestic consumption has dropped and people

that migrated to cities in search of a better life are returning to their arid homeland to grow

quinoa to export. Furthermore, farmers and ranchers associations are starting up to influence

rural development policies. These are focused on associating small producers to face national

and international markets, supporting training and capacity building. Besides these, there are

of course independent farmers, processors, exporters, retail stores and other organizations who

have linkages with each other and thus influence the value chain.

The concrete problem of my thesis involves the analysis of the value chain of quinoa from a

less developed country like Peru to a developed country like Belgium (or Europe in general). In

the literature, both Peru and Bolivia are considered because, as a neighbouring country of Peru,

Bolivia is also an important producer of quinoa in the world, just like Peru. The objective is to

identify the different stages in the value chain as well as the different actors in each stage, de-

scribe the deficiencies occurring in the value chain and look for future possibilities to enhance

II

and upgrade the critical parts of the value chain. In such a way, the impact the actors have in

the value chain and on each other is estimated based on their constraints and margins. Fur-

thermore, the influence on the value that is created by them and the total and final value that

is delivered to the customer willing to buy quinoa is assessed. Our research is mainly based on

available literature and our own findings. Since Peruvian companies were not really willing to

share their production quantities and corresponding prices, averages and approximations were

taken to be able to provide an estimate for the country as a whole. This allowed us to come up

with a reliable value chain and some recommendations for the future of the quinoa industry in

Peru.

III

Acknowledgements

I would first like to thank my master’s dissertation supervisor, professor Maenhout, for his ap-

propriate assistance and guidance during the research and writing. I would also like to thank

Inge Overmeer, Agriculture Manager at Solid International, for helping me getting into contact

with organizations in Peru and providing me with significant information and data. Further-

more, I would like to acknowledge my aunt for helping me with Spanish translations and the

Peruvians that provided me with information. Finally, I want to express my gratefulness to my

parents and grandparents for supporting and encouraging me throughout the process of re-

searching and writing this thesis. This accomplishment would not have been possible without

each of the above.

Contents

I Literature 1

1 Quinoa 3

1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

1.2 Social-Economic Context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

1.2.1 Before 2000: Food Insecurity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

1.2.2 Growth for the period 2000-2013 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

1.2.3 Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.3 Characteristics of the International Quinoa Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

2 Methods of Value Chain Analysis 15

2.1 Theory of Value Chain Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

2.1.1 Value Chain: Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

2.1.2 Creating Value in a Supply Chain Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

2.1.3 Importance of Value Chain Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

2.1.4 Global Value Chains . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

2.2 Methodology for Value Chain Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

2.3 Value Chains in Agriculture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

2.3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

2.3.2 Value Chain concepts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

2.3.3 Agricultural Value Chains and Food Security . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

2.3.4 Value Chain Analysis to Achieve Nutrition Goals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

2.3.5 Global Value Chains in Agriculture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

2.4 Game Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

2.4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

2.4.2 Application of Game Theory in Agriculture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

IV

CONTENTS V

2.5 Upgrading the Value Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

2.5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

2.5.2 "Future" Possibilities for Upgrading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

II Case Study: Illustration 35

3 Examples of Value Chain Analysis 37

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

3.2 The Coffee Value Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

3.2.1 Basic Coffee Supply Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

3.2.2 Case Study: Coffee Value Chain from Nicaragua to Finland . . . . . . . . . . 39

3.3 The Cocoa Value Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

III Case Study: An Analysis of the Value Chain of Quinoa 47

4 Socio-Economic Context 51

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

4.2 Population and Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

4.3 Participation in Economic Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

4.4 Social Impact by Outsiders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

4.5 Prospects for the Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

5 Characteristics of the Value Chain of Quinoa 57

5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

5.2 Stages of the Value Chain . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

5.2.1 Provision of Inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

5.2.2 Primary Production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

5.2.3 Storage and Basic Processing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64

5.2.4 Industrialization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64

5.2.5 Marketing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

5.2.6 Final Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67

5.3 Multi-Stage Actors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

5.3.1 COOPAIN . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

5.3.2 Vinculos Agricolas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

CONTENTS VI

5.3.3 De Guste Group SAC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

5.3.4 Avendaño Trading Company SAC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

5.3.5 Alisur SAC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

5.3.6 The Government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

5.3.7 Solid International - Solid Food Peru/Europe . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

5.4 Indirect Actors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

6 Analysis of the Value Chain of Quinoa 75

6.1 Assessing the Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

6.1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

6.1.2 Qualitative Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

6.1.3 Quantitative Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80

6.2 Upgrading the Value Chain of Quinoa . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

6.2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

6.2.2 Improvement Guidelines . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

6.2.3 Challenges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86

6.2.4 Future Possibilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88

7 Conclusion 91

Bibliography 93

Appendices 99

A Worldwide Production and Distribution of Quinoa 100

B Distribution and Production in Peru 101

C Export of Quinoa from Peru to Europe: Value and Quantity 103

D Example of a Value Chain: The Furniture Industry 105

E Participation of Nicaragua in Global Value Chains 107

F The Position of Peru and Bolivia 109

F.1 Human Development Index: Components and Trends . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

F.1.1 Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

CONTENTS VII

F.1.2 Interpretation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110

F.2 Poverty in Bolivia and Peru . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

F.2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

F.2.2 Population Trends, Health Outcomes and Education Achievements . . . . . 111

F.2.3 Interpretation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112

F.3 National Income and Composition of Resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

F.4 Employment Rates and Labour Productivity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

F.4.1 Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

F.4.2 Interpretation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

F.5 International Integration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

F.5.1 Definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

F.5.2 Interpretation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

List of Tables

1.1 The evolution of export and production (in metric tons) and the associated prices

($/kg) in Peru. Reprinted from (Vinculos Agricolas, nd). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

3.1 Consumer prices (€/kg) of conventional and Fair Trade coffee in Finland based on

purchases in one retail chain for the years 2006-2009. Copied from (Valkila et al.,

2010). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

4.1 Population and education in Peru: Region of Ayacucho and Lima. Copied from

(Censos nacionales de población y de vivienda, 2008). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

4.2 Participation in Economic Activity. Copied from (Censos nacionales de población

y de vivienda, 2008). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

5.1 Main components of the value chain of quinoa. Reprinted from (Salcedo et al.,

2013) based on data from (IDEPRO, 2012)(as cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)). . . . . 58

5.2 Harvested area, production and yield for different regions in Peru. Reprinted from

(Cenagro, 2012)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

5.3 The Net Export Volume (kg) and Price per kg ($/kg) for five exporters of quinoa in

Peru. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

6.1 The price for producers (Farm Price), for Peruvian consumers, for export, for in-

termediaries and for European consumers in $/kg for the period 2007-2016. Based

on an aggregation of data from (Vinculos Agricolas, nd), (Fallis, 2013), (Hatch

et al., 2015) and (Bio-Planet, nd). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

6.2 Margins for farmers, processors/exporters, intermediaries and wholesalers/retailers

in % for the period 2007-2016. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84

VIII

LIST OF TABLES IX

C.1 The Import Value and Quantity of Quinoa from Peru to Different European Coun-

tries for the period 2012 - 2016. Retrieved from (European Commission, nd). . . . . 104

F.1 Human Development Index and components for 2014. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117

F.2 Human Development Index for 1990-2014 and the average annual HDI growth

per country for this period. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

F.3 Poverty indices for Bolivia and Peru in 2008 and 2012 respectively. . . . . . . . . . . 119

F.4 Poverty indices for Peru from 2008 to 2012. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119

F.5 Population trends, mortality rates, literacy rate and secondary education rate for

Belgium, Peru and Bolivia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120

F.6 National income and composition of resources. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121

F.7 Employment rates and labour productivity in Belgium, Bolivia and Peru. . . . . . . 122

F.8 International integration of Belgium, Peru and Bolivia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123

List of Figures

1.1 Cultivated Area (in ha) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an

aggregation of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and

(Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014). Note that the cultivated area for Peru

in 2015 is an estimation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

1.2 Production (in tons) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an

aggregation of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and

(Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

1.3 Yield (in ton/ha) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an ag-

gregation of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and

(Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014). Note that the yield for Peru in 2015 is

based on the estimation of the cultivated area. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

1.4 Production and export of quinoa in Bolivia and Peru. Based on an aggregation

of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and (Documento

conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.5 Global world exports in quinoa (2012). Reprinted from (Comtrade and LAIA, nd)(as

cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)). Note: LAIA = Latin American Integration Associa-

tion; UE = EU = European Union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

1.6 Exports (tons) and the related export price ($/kg) of quinoa from Peru: 2000-2016.

Based on an aggregation of data from [LAIA](as cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)) and

(Vinculos Agricolas, nd). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

1.7 Main Exporting Countries towards the European Union for the period 2011-2015.

Reprinted from (CBI - Centre for the Promotion of Imports from developing coun-

tries, nd). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

2.1 The different stages in a supply chain. Reprinted from (Chopra and Meindl, 2016). 17

X

LIST OF FIGURES XI

2.2 A simplified representation of a food supply chain. Reprinted from (Hawkes and

Ruel, 2012). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

2.3 The Nutella global value chain. Reprinted from (Organisation for Economic Co-

operation and Development (OECD), Mapping Global Value Chains, Paris, 2012)(as

cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

3.1 The basic coffee supply chain. Reprinted from (Gilbert, 2008). . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

3.2 The marketing chain of coffee from Nicaragua to Finland. Reprinted from (Valkila

et al., 2010). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

3.3 The cocoa-chocolate supply chain. Reprinted from (Gilbert, 2008). . . . . . . . . . 45

5.1 Simple Representation of the Value Chain of Quinoa in Peru. Based on the Value

Chain as depicted by (Salcedo et al., 2013). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

5.2 Simple Structure of the Value Chain of Quinoa based on (Hatch et al., 2015) and

(Salcedo et al., 2013). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

5.3 The value chain of quinoa as considered in our case study. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74

6.1 Gross Marketing Margins (in %) for the different stages in the value chain for the

period 2013-2016. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84

A.1 Overview of the worldwide production and distribution of quinoa. Reprinted

from (FAO et al., 2011)(as cited by (Ruiz et al., 2014)). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100

B.1 Volume of quinoa production in metric tons for Peru in 2013 and 2014. Reprinted

from (Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego, 2014)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)). . . . 101

B.2 Cultivated surface used for quinoa production in Peru in 2013 and 2014. Reprinted

from (Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego, 2014)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)). . . . 102

D.1 The forestry, timber and furniture value chain. Reprinted from (Kaplinsky and

Morris, 2002). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106

E.1 Nicaragua: Curve of value added stages in the global apparel value chain. Reprinted

from (Frederick, 2010)(as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

Part I

Literature

1

2

Chapter 1

Quinoa

1.1 Introduction

(Composition and James, 2009) states that "quinoa is one of the seeds considered as pseudo-

cereals". According to (Composition and James, 2009), this crop was a valuable food for the

Incas and still remains a valuable food crop for people of the rural regions in the Andean of

Southern America: Ecuador, Peru, Bolivia, Colombia and Venezuela. Quinoa is native to these

regions and was already used more than 5000 years ago. Since the nutritional food quality of

quinoa grains is very good and the fact that there is the possibility to grow quinoa anywhere

between sea level and mountains that reach 4000m above sea level in harsh weather condi-

tions, the interest in quinoa has risen enormously in recent years. According to (Birbuet and

Machicado, 2008) scientists consider it the best food on the globe and highly appreciated by in-

ternational markets. That explains why it was declared to be the Perfect Food for Humanity by

UNESCO. The expansion has also led to other countries in the world like Kenya, India, Morocco,

Italy, Spain, the United States and Japan starting quinoa plantations (Parker-gibson, 2016). An

overview of the worldwide production and distribution of Quinoa is shown in appendix A.

1.2 Social-Economic Context

1.2.1 Before 2000: Food Insecurity

Latin-America can be seen as a region in which there was and still is a lot of poverty. Up to half

of the population was not able to provide themselves with adequate food. Therefore, the state

of food security was investigated. According to (Barraclough and Utting, 1987), this concept

3

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 4

assures that the supply and distribution of food is competent in quality as well as in quantity

by meeting the nutritional needs of several different social groups. It ensures that market de-

mands are met without severe shortages or brutal shifts in prices.

Food security in Bolivia and Peru caused the rural population to be self-sufficient in several

products because they were getting more and more support from public investments in ex-

pertise, machinery and capacity to grow production. Efforts to assure Bolivia and Peru to be

partly independent on imports did not lead to the desired result as new facilities were used

at only a small fraction of their capacity. This caused the products in Bolivia and Peru to be

more expensive than imports and extra subsidies for the processing enterprises being neces-

sary. Therefore, dependency on food imports increased in the early 1980s, mainly in the cities,

while peasants still relied on their own production. This, together with the poor transporta-

tion possibilities available, left the food system pretty vulnerable. The poor industrial base of

the countries caused its food system to be even more reliant on imports and a self-governing

food system inaccessible. To solve this problem on the one hand, an effective food strategy

focussed on the agricultural sector in terms of agricultural investments and services as well as

on economic and social policies (e.g. trade, exchange rates, health, education, infrastructure,

etc.) should be installed. On the other hand, focus on the agricultural sector calls for enor-

mous shifts in power relationships and asks for small farmers to organize themselves in greater

democratic farmer associations. Such organizations are looking to provide farmers with several

services regarding marketing, processing, agro-industrial production, etc. but also designing

and executing policies and programs in order to improve the food security systems.

(Barraclough and Utting, 1987) insist that people that have to cope with food insecurity can

only improve their situation by organizing themselves in local farmer associations and force

their governments to imply food strategies that are nationally-oriented. In this respect, there

was a high need for farmers to cooperate and re-organize in associations to stimulate farmer’s

production and employment but also to be able to have an influence on political issues. They

should aim for "policies to generate more employment, better working conditions, improved

education and health services, and access to adequate food at prices they can afford" (Barr-

aclough and Utting, 1987). Besides this, they should also try to collaborate with other Latin

American countries having to cope with similar problems and these problems would persist

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 5

if they did not try to change anything. With the establishment of the national quinoa growers

association (ANAPQUI) in 1983, the production for the international market had begun (Jacob-

sen, 2011).

According to (Janvry and Sadoulet, 2000), Latin American countries still had high rates of rural

poverty because of the highly unequal distribution of income, both between sectors and within

the rural sector, during the 1990s, despite relatively high income levels among developing coun-

tries and a lot of intentions to turn things around. Appendix F illustrates and interprets several

facts and figures regarding the poverty and development in Peru and Bolivia in recent years

as well as information about Belgium to show the significant differences between the coun-

tries. In the late 1990s, they were convinced that people leaving the countryside to go to urban

areas was something that could help the rural poverty. Thereby, (Janvry and Sadoulet, 2000) ex-

plained that an increase in the productivity of certain assets, which is affected by technological

changes, could help against the rural poverty in 2 manners: Directly because the technologi-

cal innovation will raise the welfare of poor farmers and indirectly through the influence that

technological change can have on the price of food for the consumers, on the employment and

wage rates in the agricultural but also other sectors and on foreign exchange contributions.

The best way to implement this technological change to reduce the poverty of farmers is by

initiatives that seek complementarity in interventions that are specified per region and by or-

ganizing in associations. An approach that is regionally-focused and involves local farmers is

necessary if technology is to be used to reduce poverty. And this is what farmers of quinoa

also opted to do: They wanted to implement the technological innovation in the production of

quinoa because they knew the value and important nutritional qualities of quinoa.

1.2.2 Growth for the period 2000-2013

Despite the exceptional characteristics that it always had, it was only since the beginning of the

21st century that the demand for quinoa started to grow enormously. This had several impor-

tant reasons:

1. According to (Dreibus, 2016)(as cited by (Parker-gibson, 2016)) the rising interest in ve-

gan, vegetarian and gluten-free diets played an important role. The world started to dis-

cover celiac disease which resulted in an increase in demand for grains without gluten

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 6

(Birbuet and Machicado, 2008).

2. The accelerated increase of the demand of high-quality organic products and the growth

of the market of fair trade products (Birbuet and Machicado, 2008).

3. Several countries adopted the food efficiency programs that were supported by the Food

and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) (Birbuet and Machicado, 2008).

4. People discovered that quinoa could be used as a source of food in areas that have to cope

with food insecurity (Ruiz et al., 2014)(as cited by (Parker-gibson, 2016)).

Issues

When looking specifically at Bolivia and Peru, although both countries’ production of quinoa

increased over the last 20 years because of an enlarged production area, they had a limited

capacity of quinoa production available in the beginning and were not able to fulfil the huge

increases in demand immediately. Figures 1.1, 1.2 and 1.3 show the enormous increase in culti-

vated area and production for the considered period. A reason for the continuous higher yield

in Peru than in Bolivia may be the social-economic gap that persists between the two countries,

as is discussed in chapter 4 and appendix F.

Figure 1.1: Cultivated Area (in ha) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an

aggregation of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and (Documento

conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014). Note that the cultivated area for Peru in 2015 is an estimation.

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 7

Figure 1.2: Production (in tons) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an

aggregation of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and (Documento

conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014).

(Jacobsen, 2011) states that the main problem of the agricultural sector was situated at the grain

processing link of the chain, until the early 2000s. The yearly processing capacity of quinoa in

Bolivia was only one third of the actual production of quinoa for one year. This led to a big loss

of the product itself. Half of the bigger quinoa-producing companies of the sector in Bolivia,

who were responsible for four fifth of quinoa exports, agreed to implement a subversive tech-

nological change to try to overcome the deficits. The technological innovation played a crucial

role in the processing of quinoa and this was the fundamental basis for a development program

called the "Quinoa Alliance". This united the main quinoa-producing companies and producer

associations of the sector.

The government’s interest in quinoa as a commodity of priority to increase the income of the

country increased the importance of the production of quinoa even more according to (Jacob-

sen, 2011). The socio-economic circumstances were very bad (We would like to refer to Ap-

pendix F for a broad elaboration on the socio-economic conditions in Peru and Bolivia in recent

years) and together with the area increase in the first years of the 21st century, the yield had to

cope with an enormous decrease. Another problem caused by the area increase is the destruc-

tion of the vegetation cover leading to an acceleration of erosion [FAUTAPO, 2008](as cited by

(Jacobsen, 2011)). Although the drop in yield, the prices kept increasing leading to an expanded

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 8

Figure 1.3: Yield (in ton/ha) in Peru and Bolivia for the period 2000-2015. Based on an aggrega-

tion of data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and (Documento conjunto

ALADI - FAO, 2014). Note that the yield for Peru in 2015 is based on the estimation of the culti-

vated area.

intensification with which quinoa was produced because farmers wanted to supply more to the

international markets (the export value had risen from $2.7 million in 1999 to $8.9million in

2006 [PNUD Bolivia, 2008](as cited by (Jacobsen, 2011)). The export of quinoa had increased

since the beginning of the new century, causing the domestic consumption to decrease. Figure

1.4 illustrates the absolute amounts of production and export for Bolivia and Peru. The differ-

ence between production and export is what is used for seeds, domestic consumption or other

uses. We can state that the domestic consumption decreased proportionally to the production,

mainly due to an increase in prices and therefore export. The figure also shows that Peru be-

came a largest exporter of quinoa, while this had always been Bolivia before 2014.

As stated by (Jacobsen, 2011), the production was in crisis because the yield decreased and

the price of quinoa tripled from 1999 to 2008, up to $2300/ton. The rising demands on the

world market and the growing commercial quinoa cultivation are leading to land degradation

caused by a much intensified production of quinoa whereas they should better adopt an ex-

tensive production to respond to the high prices (Bioversity International, 2007);[MDRyT, 2009]

and (Bosque, 2008)(as cited by (Jacobsen, 2011)).

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 9

Figure 1.4: Production and export of quinoa in Bolivia and Peru. Based on an aggregation of

data from (Jacobsen, 2011); (Hatch et al., 2015); (Fallis, 2013) and (Documento conjunto ALADI

- FAO, 2014).

Possible Solutions

Since quinoa is a product that can be cultivated in several different agro-climatic conditions

in the Andes (Jacobsen, 2003)(as cited by (Jacobsen, 2011)), a production outside the region

would decrease the enormous pressure on the soil in vulnerable regions and bolster the market

worldwide and thereby benefit others in the world because of its huge market potential (Jacob-

sen, 2003)(as cited by(Jacobsen, 2011)).

As stated earlier, farmers are no longer consuming their own production of quinoa but partic-

ularly grow it to export because the price is too high to keep it. With the money they earn from

selling it, they can buy much more other products with a lower value. Figure 1.4 illustrates the

decrease in consumption of own production towards 2010 (pink dots). (Jacobsen, 2011) indi-

cates that the consumption of quinoa in Bolivia amounts to only 2kg per person per year and

the consumption of rice or pasta has risen to more than 25kg per person per year, whereas in

Peru, a person consumes more than 20kg per year.

1.2.3 Future

Right now, some believe quinoa has already lived up to its full potential in the highlands of

Peru and Bolivia. After the international year of quinoa, production (as can be seen on figure

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 10

1.2, especially for Peru) as well as prices reached its peak in 2014. Producers could get up to

€6/kg for organic quinoa. Due to its flexibility and high potential, people started to cultivate

quinoa in the lowlands, in the north of Peru, along the coast, closer to bigger cities. Since the

yield realized in these parts of the country are a lot higher (4 000 kg/ha compared to 1 000

kg/ha in the highlands) thanks to better weather conditions and use of pesticides, the total

production started to increase enormously. Everywhere in the country new quinoa farmers

were popping up like daisies. Furthermore, the United States, Canada, European countries etc.

all started small plantations of quinoa to cultivate their own quinoa in order to reduce import

and transportation costs. These factors all led to a drop in price and loss of markets for the

Peruvian and Bolivian farmers.

1.3 Characteristics of the International Quinoa Trade

In this section, we will elaborate on the characteristics of the international trade of quinoa. The

main goal is to identify the actors of the value chain (e.g. importers and exporters) and give a

clear overview of the market access conditions and the essential elements of global supply and

demand for quinoa on which our case study can be based. Research for this section is mainly

based on (Salcedo et al., 2013)’s paper about "International Quinoa Trade".

As mentioned in earlier sections, the increase in the demand of quinoa can be explained by

several reasons. As the demand grew significantly, so did the international trade. Since the

Latin-American countries (LAIA) account for more than 80% of the export of quinoa (as can be

seen on Figure 1.5), a tariff opening for quinoa was introduced by the World Customs Organiza-

tion according to (Salcedo et al., 2013). Most of the exports go to the United States and a decent

percentage to Canada. The other exports are mostly intended to go to Western Europe. Figure

1.6 indicates the enormous growth in exports that Bolivia and Peru have witnessed. This figure

shows the amount of tons and the corresponding price at which the quinoa was exported dur-

ing the years from 1992 until 2012. The export increased more than 40 times from 600 tonnes

in 2002 to 37 000 tonnes in 2012, which corresponds to an annual growth rate of 22,8% (Salcedo

et al., 2013).

Also, the export of quinoa in Peru has increased proportionally to the export of quinoa in Bo-

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 11

livia. In the early 90s, Bolivia’s export accounted for 90% of the exports and Peru’s for 6%, while

around 2010, Peru’s export increased to 23% of the exports and Bolivia’s declined to 75% (Sal-

cedo et al., 2013). This is somewhat a vague measure given the fact that the production and

export volume in both countries has increased significantly over these periods. In recent years,

Peru is establishing itself more and more as one of the most important exporters of quinoa

while Bolivia is staggering. This remarkable turnaround is depicted in figure 1.7, which shows

the export of the main producing countries towards the European Union from 2011 until 2015.

Many say it is due to better infrastructure and more capital availability in Peru. An overview of

the production and export quantities and respective prices from 2000 until 2016 is given in table

1.3. It is clear that the production in Peru increased steadily in the beginning with a somewhat

higher rate from 2008 until 2013 to really boom in 2014 and 2015. The prices followed a similar

pattern until 2012 (as can be seen on figure 1.6). The enormous profitability of quinoa inspired

farmers and larger organizations in and around Lima, in the lowlands and along the coast in the

north of Peru to also start producing quinoa. This led to an excessive increase of the cultivated

area and the total production of Peru in 2014 and 2015, which is also shown on the figures in

appendix B. The yields, which are also discussed in section 5.2, were a lot higher in these places

than in the highlands due to better weather conditions, better infrastructure and equipment

and use of pesticides. On top of this, others such as the United States, Canada and European

countries started to establish quinoa plantations. This contributed to the steep decrease of the

price in 2015 and 2016 after it had reached its peak in 2014. The profit the farmers received

proportionally to the export prices was even lower than before. Furthermore, organizations are

losing their export markets to producers in export countries which causes expectations that ex-

ports as well as prices will further decrease relatively to production in the coming years.

Regarding the import, the United States has remained the biggest importer of quinoa with more

or less 55% of the imports. Due to European countries producing more and more quinoa do-

mestically in order to meet their own demand since a couple of years, they import less and new

countries such as Canada, Australia, Brazil and Israel are establishing as more important desti-

nation markets. Again, this should be taken with a grain of salt because the total export volume

has increased since the boom of the quinoa production due to the huge popularity of the grain

resulting from the consumer awareness of healthier diets, as can be seen in table 1.3. To have

an overview of the export quantities and values from Peru to different European countries in

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 12

recent years, we would like to refer to appendix C.

Figure 1.5: Global world exports in quinoa (2012). Reprinted from (Comtrade and LAIA, nd)(as

cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)). Note: LAIA = Latin American Integration Association; UE = EU =

European Union

Figure 1.6: Exports (tons) and the related export price ($/kg) of quinoa from Peru: 2000-2016.

Based on an aggregation of data from [LAIA](as cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)) and (Vinculos

Agricolas, nd).

CHAPTER 1. QUINOA 13

Figure 1.7: Main Exporting Countries towards the European Union for the period 2011-2015.

Reprinted from (CBI - Centre for the Promotion of Imports from developing countries, nd).

Table 1.1: The evolution of export and production (in metric tons) and the associated prices

($/kg) in Peru. Reprinted from (Vinculos Agricolas, nd).

Year Export (mt) Production (mt) Exp. Price ($/kg) Price at Field ($/kg)

2000 262,80 28.191 1.27 0.34

2001 148,10 22.269 1.29 0.34

2002 249,80 30.373 1.22 0.32

2003 321,00 30.085 1.19 0.32

2004 287,60 26.998 1.34 0.33

2005 562,30 32.589 1.21 0.35

2006 1.271,00 30.428 1.23 0.36

2007 1.551,80 31.826 1.31 0.39

2008 2.036,00 29.866 2.45 0.55

2009 2.692,10 39.398 2.69 1.12

2010 4.782,90 41.077 2.76 1.19

2011 8.035,90 41.180 3.17 1.33

2012 10.887,50 44.212 2.91 1.47

2013 18.690,80 52.092 4.26 2.33

2014 36.510,10 114.343 5.39 2.81

2015 41.636,95 105.665 3.84 1.21

2016 34.040.28 2.34

Chapter 2

Methods of Value Chain Analysis

2.1 Theory of Value Chain Analysis

2.1.1 Value Chain: Definitions

(Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002) define the value chain as "the full range of activities which are

required to bring a product or service from conception through the different phases of produc-

tion, delivery to the final consumers and final disposal after use." A simple example is given in

appendix D, in which the value chain of the furniture industry is shortly described. The value

chains can be of a different type. Based on the idea of governance, (Gereffi and Korzeniewicz,

1994) (as cited by (Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002)) distinguish two types of value chains: Buyer-

driven chains and Producer-driven chains. Governance refers to the controlling and monitoring

of the implied rules and interactions between the different actors in the value chain by setting

parameters regarding products, processes and qualifications. It is important that these rules

and interactions carefully reflect the actors, activities, roles and functions and their relation-

ships with each other. When this governance role is played by a buyer at the top of the chain,

(Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002) categorize it as buyer-driven chains. Such chains are most present

in labour-intensive sectors such as the aforementioned furniture, but also clothing, electronics,

handicrafts etc. The second type, producer-driven chains, describe the governing role to be

played by the leading producer of the chain and are most likely to be present in capital- and

technology-intensive environments (e.g. software, heavy machinery, car industry, etc.). (Ger-

effi et al., 1999) (as cited by (Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002)) further state that the different kinds

of value chains are related with different kinds of production systems. (Kaplinsky and Morris,

15

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 16

2002) complement these findings by saying that value chains not only differ within and between

sectors, but also the international, national and local context is an important factor to take into

account.

According to (Donovan et al., 2015), there are several definitions of a value chain. In his paper

’Guides for Value Chain Development: A Comparative Review’, he distinguishes three defini-

tions of a value chain as follows:

1. A value chain can be interpreted based on the value adding activities that are performed

in every step from start to end product or service. In this definition, (Donovan et al.,

2015) emphasize that the development of the chain is focused on enhancing production

processes.

2. A second possibility to see a value chain is as a combination of actors that are linked to

each other by the activities they perform. (Donovan et al., 2015) report that the weakest

actors are mainly the core of the chain development.

3. Thirdly, (Donovan et al., 2015) state that a value chain can also be interpreted to fulfil the

market demand by regarding the value chain as a strategic network. These value chains

are developed over time as the goal is to form a decent value adding chain.

Obviously, these definitions are often interpreted in a combined matter. (Donovan et al., 2015)

also gives two possible definitions of value chain development, which he describes as "an ac-

tor/chain type that focuses on strengthening certain actors and improving relations between

smallholders and other actors in a chain; a business-environment type that focuses on improv-

ing the business environment in which chain actors operate." The goal of value chain devel-

opment is very diverse but mainly looks to enhance the chain by investigating the drawbacks

of actors and activities, looking at competitors and coming up with innovations to address the

drawbacks and improve the chain and process such that all actors benefit from it.

2.1.2 Creating Value in a Supply Chain Environment

The first thing (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012) stated is that a value chain starts with a supply chain:

(Chopra and Meindl, 2016) define a supply chain as "a system consisting of all parties involved,

directly or indirectly, in fulfilling a customer request. It includes manufacturers and suppliers,

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 17

transporters, warehouses, retailers and customers." The typical supply chain consists of differ-

ent stages, as shown on figure 2.1. The arrows indicate that each stage is connected through the

flow of products, services, information, money etc. Functions used to complete the requests of

customers include new product development, marketing, operations, distribution, finance and

customer service (Chopra and Meindl, 2016).

Figure 2.1: The different stages in a supply chain. Reprinted from (Chopra and Meindl, 2016).

The definition of a supply chain allows to say that a value chain involves all the processes and

the actors that play a significant role from the origin of a product to its clearance, as can be

seen on figure 2.2, on which I will focus more in section 2.3. A value chain can be described

as a supply chain where "value is added to the product through "value-adding" activities as it

passes through the chain. These activities create value for the value chain actors." (Hawkes and

Ruel, 2012). Value creation can be in terms of the economic value of the product itself, the eco-

nomic value that is created for the actors in the chain or the value that is added to the product

as it goes through the different steps in the chain (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012). On the other hand,

(Dixit, 2014) declares that value chains unfold around the needs of consumers and these are in

turn translated in the needs for the market. A drawback of this is that the needs for the market

are not directly embedded in agriculture policy frameworks. Well-working markets are easier

when you want to improve the productivity and production. According to (Dixit, 2014), a pol-

icy framework that is based on the value chain allows to observe the link between the different

actors of the value chain: and facilitates to identify the process or actor in the chain that should

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 18

be targeted for a potential value addition.

According to (Dixit, 2014), policy makers and international communities have recently been at-

tracted to global value chains. These value chains indicate a "production process that crosses

the border of the country where it is produced in order to create a decent end product. This in-

ternational environment for production and trade causes certain threats because it is not in line

with traditional trade and the mindset of investment policies" (Dixit, 2014). (Dixit, 2014) gives

the example of tariffs and other customs restrictions on trade that may not only harm foreign

supplies but also be a barrier to indigenous exports by levying fees and therefore increasing the

cost. Quinoa can be seen as a product that is part of such a global value chain since it is pro-

duced in Bolivia and Peru and exported to multiple markets across its borders. Global value

chains are described in more detail in section 2.1.4.

2.1.3 Importance of Value Chain Analysis

(Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002) mention the three main reasons why it is important to perform a

value chain analysis:

1. Competitiveness is extremely important due to the increased division of labour and the

global diffusion of the production components.

2. A detailed value chain analysis has the possibility to enhance the production processes

and thereby enter global markets.

3. A thorough understanding of the dynamic factors in the value chain facilitates entry in

the global markets and corresponding growth.

2.1.4 Global Value Chains

For their definition of global value chains, (Hernandez et al., 2013) start with a definition of a

value chain obtained from (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark, 2016): "The full range of activities that

firms and workers do to bring a product from its conception to its end use and beyond." Accord-

ing to (Hernandez et al., 2013), this includes different activities such as the design, production,

marketing, distribution and support to the final consumer. Since these activities and actors are

not focused on one country and therefore located in several countries, the value chain is said to

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 19

be global.

It was in the beginning of the year 2000 that global value chains started to take off. This shows

similarities with the evolution of the quinoa grain. From the beginning of the new century, the

interest in quinoa rose enormously and started to expand beyond the borders of Bolivia and

Peru a couple of years later. (Hernandez et al., 2013) mention three factors responsible for the

raise of global value chains:

1. Production got more and more fragmented over several countries due to the increased

transport and infrastructure possibilities. Global value chains allow to portray the rela-

tionships of the fragmented activities and link them geographically.

2. Some countries are specialized in cultivating products that are used for production of

another good in a country that is specialized in the processing of the good. This good

may further be transferred to another country for consumption. (Hernandez et al., 2013)

state that countries are more and more specializing in processes and business functions

than in products, which leads to countries trying to position themselves in value chains.

Global value chains ease this transition process.

3. Global value chains establish networks of buyers and suppliers and allow to get a better

understanding of the controlling and monitoring structures. According to (Hernandez

et al., 2013), this is crucial to determine what influence policies have on actors and where

activities are performed.

These factors need to be taken into account in order to better understand how global value

chains operate and to be able to map a value chain like the one of quinoa. The value chain of

quinoa can be interpreted as being fragmented over producing and processing countries Peru

and Bolivia, where it is also consumed or from where it is transferred to other distributing and

consuming countries like the US, Canada, France, Spain, Germany, Australia etc. Networks of

producers, processors, exporters, wholesalers and retailers are established to deliver a quality

product to the customers. An example of a Latin-American country participating in global value

chains is given in appendix E.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 20

2.2 Methodology for Value Chain Analysis

As mentioned earlier, (Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002) stated that value chains differ within and

between sectors. Thereby, the context in which they operate alters too. (Kaplinsky and Morris,

2002) ranked several issues and factors to focus on when analyzing a supply chain: A first and

far most important step is the understanding of the market. To be able to conduct a secure

value chain analysis, (Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002) outlined the following key aspects and steps

of value chain analysis:

1. The way a chain is looked at determines which relations and actions are to be the key

processes, functions, roles etc.

2. Mapping value chains is a second important consideration. This involves the determina-

tion of constraint, the selection of appropriate variables and the assignment of numbers

and values to the respective variables for each actor or step in the value chain. In the case

of quinoa in Peru and Bolivia, the main variables of importance are the produced, trans-

ported and exported quantities and corresponding prices. This is on which the case study

will focus.

3. Since more and more systems use the ’pull-principle’, the characteristics of the final stages

should get primary attention and should be clearly defined in order to recognize critical

factors such as a clear segmentation of the market, definition of critical success factors

(e.g. low cost, quality, differentiation etc.) and the rapid changing environment.

4. The way producers approach end markets, benchmarking the efficiency, controlling, mon-

itoring and upgrading value chains (Kaplinsky and Morris, 2002).

Not all but most of these aspects should be considered and utilized in a value chain analysis.

When we want to expand this analysis to broader horizons such as new international markets

like the one of quinoa, a global value chain analysis should be applied, like explained in section

2.1.4 above.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 21

2.3 Value Chains in Agriculture

2.3.1 Introduction

As stated before, a lot of people in Southern American countries suffer from hunger and food

insecurity. (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012) indicate that these people are denied easy access to such

foods due to a limited availability, economic constraints, lack of knowledge and information,

and related lack of demand for nutritious foods. In their paper, they assume that agriculture

could partly solve this problem by providing aid to people that are at risk and by enhancing

the availability, affordability, acceptability and quality of the nutritious foods such as quinoa.

Installing development programs focused on the agricultural production and consumption by

small farmers is not sufficient to improve the nutrition. All what happens between production

and consumption has to be mapped. According to (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012), this can be done

by adopting several concepts, analysis and approaches regarding the value chain. The analy-

sis is concentrated on identifying the actors and its relationships and on the activities that are

performed throughout the value chain. Figure 2.2 clearly illustrates the different activities and

corresponding actors that are needed to achieve and enhance the concepts of food availability,

food affordability, food acceptability and food quality. There are also several alternative ap-

proaches to agricultural development that are used to encourage poor groups of people to be

part of more modern value chains. These approaches want to increase the return to the farmers

as a means of improving processes, products, functions, volume and coordination (Hawkes and

Ruel, 2012).

2.3.2 Value Chain concepts

Value chain concepts have the potential to influence both the supply and the demand of nu-

tritious foods such as quinoa. The analysis gives an indication of the availability, the price and

the quality of the foods together with the interference of the government. (Hawkes and Ruel,

2012) give an example of value chain analysis where it is used to identify the type of value that

products need to supply to enhance the demand and the acceptability of that product as well as

determining whether extra nutritional value changes the value perception and the willingness

to pay for consumers.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 22

Figure 2.2: A simplified representation of a food supply chain. Reprinted from (Hawkes and

Ruel, 2012).

(Hawkes and Ruel, 2012) write that when the nutrition goals are clearly stated and solution-

oriented, the convenience of value chain concepts allows to accomplish the goals more easily.

In section 2.3.4, their view on how to apply value chain concepts to achieve nutrition goals is

illustrated.

2.3.3 Agricultural Value Chains and Food Security

Value chain analysis that is focused on achieving nutrition goals as mentioned in section 2.3.4

is very closely related to the agricultural value chain and the associated food security and there-

fore also to the value chain of quinoa. The concept of food insecurity is something Bolivia and

Peru already have to cope with since a long time, although not to the same extent recently. It

can be seen as the base, from which it all started, of the quinoa production. Since there was

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 23

and is food insecurity in Bolivia and Peru, people look for new products and strategies, mainly

situated in the agricultural sector, to overcome the problems. (Dixit, 2014) states that a value

chain perspective on the agricultural sector delivers guidelines to address certain constraints

and restrictions related to the development of the agricultural sector and the realisation of food

security objectives. Due to the increasing globalization and the increased acquisition and dis-

tribution channels, research of the value chains is becoming more important in agriculture.

Although (Dixit, 2014) argues that this is why agricultural value chains are more buyer-driven

instead of producer-driven, the value chain of quinoa is also producer-driven because the pro-

duction process is influenced by "foreign value that is added in domestic agricultural produc-

tion and exports" (Dixit, 2014).

(Dixit, 2014) states that a value chain-based policy framework can facilitate food security con-

siderations. He mentions ’food availability on the national market’, ’food accessibility for peo-

ple’ and ’food utilisation’ as the core aspects of assuring food security. The first aspect, food

availability, is in line with improving the agricultural productivity because a better productivity

assists its availability. Secondly, access to food is said to be the most important factor because it

supports people’s security. Food utilisation mainly focuses on achieving nutrition goals. (Dixit,

2014) is convinced that a policy framework would improve the whole value chain by imple-

menting extra investments for production systems and infrastructure for the market and for

distribution. This will in turn lead to an agricultural sector that is flexible and able to handle

possible issues in the future. According to (Dixit, 2014), a policy framework with multilateral

trade rules, installed under the World Trade Organisation (WTO), enhances the performance of

actions to achieve food security goals for example by decreasing tariffs and other barriers. First

of all, multilateral rules would restrict the extent to which the government subsidises farmers

who are considered to have a negative impact. Secondly, a reduction in tariffs and trade trans-

action costs would improve the access and utilisation factors of food security and therefore also

the value chain. Thirdly, (Dixit, 2014) states that the WTO would also like to provide predictable

access to supply and therefore retain its reliable source of food supply. It would install limits on

export for a certain product to prevent a shortage for this product. A last thing that WTO would

like to inaugurate are the multilateral rules on food safety and quality standards because they

are crucial for a good working value chain.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 24

We can conclude that "upstream and downstream markets are the main avenues of value addi-

tion" (Dixit, 2014) in agriculture. (Dixit, 2014) states that markets are the drivers for outside ac-

tors to join the value chain. He is convinced that a value chain-based framework can empower

the authorities to acknowledge markets’ influence when there are more connections with the

private sector and when the agricultural value chains’ importance keeps increasing. This will

lead to governmental involvement in some of the activities in order to assist production and

productivity and create better functioning markets. This will further lead to an increasing and

growing agricultural sector that is supported by the government. When we look at quinoa in

this respect, the government is indeed trying to provide support for poor farmers, but larger

farmers and processors are still too often reaping the benefits away from the small farmers by

abusing their power towards the government or exporters.

2.3.4 Value Chain Analysis to Achieve Nutrition Goals

When looking more specifically to value chain analysis in the agricultural sector, the most com-

mon and important objective is related to nutrition goals. In this respect, (Hawkes and Ruel,

2012) investigate whether value chain concepts can help to achieve nutritional goals. They state

that adopting concepts of the value chain has the possibility to enhance the supply and demand

of nutritious foods, especially for the poor people. "Value chain concepts enable the potential

of assessing the availability, the price and the nutrient quality of foods in specific communities.

Thereby they indicate what an influence public interventions and policies have on the integra-

tion in the value chain." (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012). Since they embody the different steps in the

chain and recognize that the coordination among the actors enhances the ability of the sector

to create value, they are able to provide a framework for coordinating actions and actors and

for identifying and engaging the sectors that need to be involved. And this is very relevant to

the agricultural sector. Therefore, (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012) give a detailed overview of steps to

follow in order to achieve nutritional goals:

1. Starting from a clearly-stated and outcome-oriented nutrition goal is important.

2. Define the nutrition problem and identify the gaps in food and nutrients by targeting one

or more food value chains.

3. First create economic value for value chain actors. This will in turn lead to an increase in

value for nutrition. This is illustrated below.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 25

4. It is important to search for comprehensive solutions that are adapted to the context.

"The search for solutions should take the whole value chain, including different sectors

and actors at different scales, into account, but the application of solutions should be

tailored to circumstance" (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012).

5. Focus on improving the coordination of the actors within the chain by intervening where

necessary and developing alliances between the actors involved.

6. Look for solutions that both add value for nutrition as well as for actors of the value chain.

7. Add value for consumers by offering new attributes and add value for producers by allow-

ing them to produce more or supply a larger market.

8. Aim attention at meeting, increasing and creating demand.

9. Develop a policy environment which gives incentives to the actors in the chain to value

nutrition.

An example of a project with explicit nutrition goals and related activities according to (Hawkes

and Ruel, 2012) is the "Enhancing of the bean value chain in Uganda". This is very similar to

the projects involving quinoa in Peru and Bolivia because it’s a project focused on improving

the production, marketing and consumption of beans in order to improve the living conditions

of the people. "In a value-chain framework, actions included research into increasing yields,

improving nutrient quality after harvest, understanding consumers’ preferences and demand,

increasing their awareness of the nutritional and health benefits of beans, and promoting bean

consumption" (Mazur et al., 2011)(as cited by (Hawkes and Ruel, 2012)).

2.3.5 Global Value Chains in Agriculture

Global value chains are not restricted to products or services in a manufacturing industry. (Her-

nandez et al., 2013) state that agriculture can be linked to the value chains of the downstream

activities, the so called "agrifood business". According to (Hernandez et al., 2013), it is becom-

ing more and more a trend to structure these downstream activities in global value chains.

These global value chains are said to be managed by processors and retailers who are part of

the chain. (Hernandez et al., 2013) mention supermarkets as an example of retailers who are

part of the chain and have contracts with importers as well as exporters to exert a monitoring

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 26

Figure 2.3: The Nutella global value chain. Reprinted from (Organisation for Economic Co-

operation and Development (OECD), Mapping Global Value Chains, Paris, 2012)(as cited by

(Hernandez et al., 2013)).

function over the production of crops. They kind of act as intermediaries between the exporting

country and the importing country, which is also the case in the quinoa value chain. By exer-

cising vertical coordination, the ones with a monitoring function want to guarantee quality and

food safety standards along the chain. The value chains in the agrifood industry are known to

comprise companies and actors in less developed and developing countries. A good example

of agrifood value chains that include such countries is that of the Nutella global value chain,

given by (Hernandez et al., 2013). Nutella, a product which most of the world is very familiar

with, is produced in huge quantities (more than 300.000 tons every year). Figure 2.3 depicts the

different headquarters, international suppliers, factories and sales offices involved in the value

chain of Nutella. In 2013, ten factories all over the world were producing Nutella, as can be

seen by the red triangles on the figure. It is evident from the picture that a lot of ingredients are

supplied globally (indicated by the green dots): Cocoa comes from Ivory Coast, Ghana, Nige-

ria and Ecuador; Sugar from Europe; Palm oil from Papua New Guinea and Brazil; Hazelnut

from Turkey and Vanillin from the USA and Europe. Of course, there are still ingredients and

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 27

attachments which are locally supplied (e.g. Milk). The main sales offices are indicated with

a purple cross and are located all over the world. Note that there are a lot more locations than

those shown on the figure. Nutella has positioned the factories in such a way that Nutella can be

easily supplied to the markets with the highest demand (think of Europe, North-America, Aus-

tralia and Brazil). Until now, Nutella isn’t that well known in Asia and therefore, no factories are

installed yet. We can conclude from this example that the value chains in the agrifood indus-

try are significantly focused internationally and involve ingredients produced in less developed

and developing countries such as cocoa from Central Africa. This value chain of Nutella has

several similarities with the quinoa value chain in such a way that quinoa is mainly cultivated

and processed in less developed countries (Bolivia, Peru) before it is transported to countries

with a higher demand (Europe, North-America). It is also different in such a way that all the

inputs for quinoa production are available in Peru. Producers or processors don’t need to get

inputs from other continents, which is the case for the production of Nutella.

2.4 Game Theory

2.4.1 Introduction

(Turocy et al., 2003) defines a game theory as "the formal study of decision-making where sev-

eral players must make choices that potentially affect the interests of the other players." It is

actually an inquiry of the degree of cooperation and competition or conflict between the differ-

ent parties involved in particular activities and interdependent on each other. Its strength lies

in the methodology it uses to structure and analyse problems of strategic choice (Turocy et al.,

2003). It is very important to have a list of the actors and their strategic options, taking into

account their preferences and actions/reactions. A game theory can be established if there is

competition between the actors of the considered value chain and outside value chain actors.

In reality, this competition is always imperfect. (Stiegert, 2008) defines imperfect competition

as the ability of a company to charge prices that are above marginal costs. It is a market situation

in which many sellers are present that sell heterogeneous products. Firms are expected to be

able to determine prices that result in ending up with significant margins and profits. The game

theory related to imperfect competition is referred to as the non-cooperative game theory.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 28

2.4.2 Application of Game Theory in Agriculture

Since agriculture has to cope with a time lag between investment and pay-off (it can take up to

a year or more from seed to harvest and sale), price-taking principles and unexpected weather

conditions etc., uncertainly is said to be omnipresent in agriculture. Game theory models that

address the uncertainty and decision-making processes in agriculture need to be investigated:

On the one hand, this concerns long-term decisions regarding the location, the type of farm-

ing, the size of the farm, purchase or rental of land, materials and machines to invest in and

timing of investment, human capital and other resources (Agrawal and Heady, 1968). On the

other hand, short-term decisions need to be made such as when to sell, how long to store, the

kind of manure and the amount, whether other techniques are more useful etc. (Agrawal and

Heady, 1968). Another important factor that enforces uncertainty is of course the lack of knowl-

edge about the decisions and moves of competitors. (Agrawal and Heady, 1968) give some game

theories that can be applied in agriculture but they refer to the late 60s and are somewhat out-

dated. (Sexton et al., 1994) also examined game theories in agricultural markets and stated

that agricultural products are expensive to transport because they are bulky and perishable.

Therefore, the markets for raw agricultural products are actually geographical markets where

imperfect competition will certainly occur. It is said to be present in the international trade

of multiple agricultural products because trading agencies, the government and other author-

ities intervene in import and export to get control of the situation. According to (Sexton et al.,

1994), uncertainty or lack of information that causes asymmetries between the actors is an im-

portant source of strategic behaviour. As stated earlier and again confirmed by (Sexton et al.,

1994), informational asymmetries are omnipresent in agricultural markets. An example given

by (Sexton et al., 1994) mentions that processors may have more information regarding markets

overseas than farmers which gives them incentives to misuse these advantages. On the other

hand, farmers may have informational advantages regarding the characteristics and quality of

their crops.

The models established by (Sexton et al., 1994) include Principal-Agent Models, Auctions and

Collective Bargaining. All of these are more or less present in the quinoa industry. Collective

Bargaining is a method commonly used by the associations of farmers in order to negotiate

better prices with exporters etc. Auctions are sporadically present in the quinoa industry. They

can be used to boost the quinoa price enormously, although this can have a lot of negative

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 29

effects in the long term.

Principal-Agent Models

(Sexton et al., 1994) define Principal-Agent Models as models in which the principal is the entity

who hires the agent to perform some task. The principal may be a farmer who is looking for a

marketing firm to act as an agent and sell the farmer’s products. The agent may have an infor-

mational advantage in this case, as he is better informed about market conditions etc. Another

example is a processor who acts as a principal and is looking for a farmer to cultivate speci-

fied products. In this case, the farmers have an informational advantage because they have the

knowledge about productions costs and quality etc. This is not restricted to farmers and pro-

cessors but can also be applied in other parts of the value chain (e.g. An exporter can act as the

principal while retailing firms as the agents or vice versa). (Sexton et al., 1994) make a distinc-

tion between three models based on the information asymmetries between the actors. These

models are:

1. Moral hazard models: Models in which actions taken by the agents are executed without

the principal knowing or seeing it. It may be most relevant in agriculture when the proces-

sor acts as the principal and the farmer as the agent. This allows farmers to influence the

quality of products and reap more benefits for example. It is the processor’s responsibility

to be totally informed by means of contracts and financial terms.

2. Adverse selection models: Models in which the agents have secret knowledge which they

don’t want to share with the principal, already from before getting in contact. These mod-

els may result in the elimination of products of higher quality because of the inability to

recognize and reward quality and may lead to overage of low-quality products. Thereby, it

also provides motives for the government to intervene with certain quality standards and

certifications.

3. Vertical control: This kind of model includes contracts in which upstream entities (e.g.

Farmer) restrict the behaviour of downstream entities (e.g. Processor or exporter). These

contracts involve exclusive sales arrangements, fees, fixed quantities, bundling of goods,

etc. It is the goal of the farmer to select contractual tools appropriately in order to maxi-

mize his/her profit and propose them to the processors. These models can be found quite

often in the food retailing part of agriculture.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 30

Auctions

Auctions are mainly used in case prices are fluctuating constantly, when fixed prices don’t work

accordingly (e.g. fish, eggs, fruits and vegetables) or when quality of a good is variable (e.g.

livestock, wool, used equipment). In order to thrive on a continuous basis and establish value,

many actors on both the selling side and the buying side are needed to facilitate the move-

ment towards a competitive market price that reflects true value. (Sexton et al., 1994) states

that monopoly’s (one supplier) and monopsony’s (one buyer) can also be favourable with re-

gard to auctions (e.g. governments can act as a monopolist for oil and mineral exploitations

but can also act as a monopsonist for public services and construction projects because they

are the one providing the capital to build these projects). The main reason for monopolists and

monopsonists to use auctions is asymmetry of information (Sexton et al., 1994). Since a mo-

nopolist is the only provider of a particular product, he is able to set take-it-or-leave-it prices

to maximize his own value when buyers know the value of the product. The other way around

counts for monopsonists.

Collective Bargaining

Collective bargaining normally occurs in a market where multiple buyers are present. How-

ever this market structure often evolves into a bilateral monopoly in which we have a single

seller and a single buyer negotiating with each other. (Sexton et al., 1994) mention two different

states in which collective bargaining can occur in agriculture. First of all, it can appear by means

of voluntary initiatives of farmers. Secondly, the government can force farmers to collectively

produce and market their products. The driver for collective bargaining is most likely the ability

to create more value by cooperating with the association than when working on their own. The

bargaining associations are said to be looking to arrange division of costs, quality premiums

and several discounts. This is something that often happens in the quinoa industry in South-

ern America, although people argue the trustworthiness of these associations. Too often, the

greatest players of the association reap most of the benefits and leave nothing for the smaller

players, whose working conditions are then even deteriorated.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 31

2.5 Upgrading the Value Chain

2.5.1 Introduction

Since the demand market for quinoa keeps increasing and seems to be guaranteed for many

years to come, an amount sufficient to fulfil all this demand should be provided. An expansion

of the cultivated area and production together with stimulating public policies will be needed

to be able to contribute to the increase in internal and external consumption (Documento con-

junto ALADI - FAO, 2014). Even more important is the productivity and therefore yield per

hectare, which increased only very little from 2000 until 2012, because it can be seen as a direct

method to enhance the income level of farmers. An upgrade of the value chain seems manda-

tory in this respect. Upgrading a value chain refers to "actors gaining higher returns by joining

or moving between different stages of the value chain" (Hernandez et al., 2013). According to

(Hernandez et al., 2013), these returns can be obtained by:

1. Upgrading the product: Switching towards a product with a higher value or enhancing

the intrinsic value of a product through the steps outlined below.

2. Upgrading the process: Increasing the efficiency of machinery and systems. This is often

focused on installing new technologies.

3. Upgrading functionalities: Advance to other (higher) stages in the value chain that call for

more challenging skills.

4. Upgrading chains and sectors: Facilitating the entrance into newly established value chains

by exploiting the knowledge and skills available in the current chain.

When actors are looking to achieve economic development, a value chain analysis can help to

embed new actors in the value chain (1) and enhance the current position of actors that are

already present in the chain (2).

Embed New Actors in the Value Chain

(Hernandez et al., 2013) describe the actors in the first option as most likely being companies

in developing countries that are on the verge of joining global industries or companies that are

less developed and still at a considerable distance from joining such industries. By embedding

new actors in the chain, strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats for new actors can

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 32

be determined. (Hernandez et al., 2013) mention examples such as the Aid for Trade initiative

led by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the World

Trade Organization (WTO) that uses global value chain analysis to identify and reduce threats

for companies in developing countries on the verge of joining global industries. The second

example given by (Hernandez et al., 2013) points out to country-specific agencies focused on

development that try to govern the situation and come up with new initiatives that can serve

as guidelines. These guidelines for companies in developing countries can help to upgrade the

value chain and therefore create more value for the actors involved (Barrientos et al., 2011);

(Fernandez-Stark et al., 2012); (Humphrey and Navas-Alemán, 2010); (Meyer-Stamer and Wal-

tring, 2006) (as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)).

Enhance the Current Position of Actors in the Chain

The second option, enhancing the position of actors already present in the chain, entails a

global value chain analysis to decompose the total industry in her most important actors and

activities. This, likewise the first option, enables to identify strengths, weaknesses, opportu-

nities and threats of the activities already present in the chain (Gereffi and Fernandez-Stark,

2016) (as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)). On top of this, guidelines for agencies etc. can be

derived from a thorough global value chain analysis. (Hernandez et al., 2013) give the example

of the governments of Chile and Costa Rica using a global value chain analysis to construct rules

and policies that facilitate exploiting opportunities and thereby upgrade the value chain. The

economic development agency CORFO in Chile uses a global value chain analysis to improve

the value created in the offshore services industry. This helped the company to assess the in-

dustry’s potential at a global level, identify the country’s position and look for opportunities in

specific industries that are in line with the country’s potential (Hernandez et al., 2013). In Costa

Rica, the Foreign Trade Ministry uses global value chains to investigate four sectors that are be-

coming more and more important. This comprises the medical devices sector, the electronics

sector, the aerospace sector and the offshore services sector. Again, the goal involves assess-

ing the sector at a global level, looking whether there are significant changes, identifying the

country’s position and looking for opportunities to exploit in order to upgrade the value chain

(Hernandez et al., 2013).

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 33

2.5.2 "Future" Possibilities for Upgrading

Leveraging Local Resources

Although most of the companies in Latin American countries have not been able to enhance

the added value and are restricted to the lower half of the value chains, there are possibilities

for these countries by leveraging the wealth and experience of the natural resources that they

have available in order to supply higher value products for export (Hernandez et al., 2013). An

example of where knowledge is created to enhance the value chain concerns the cattle industry

in Uruguay. This sector counts more than 12 million cattle, while the population of Uruguay is

only quite more than 3 million. It is no secret that therefore, beef is the main export product

of Uruguay. The problem with this sector, comparable to that of quinoa, is its vulnerability for

health and food safety issues (Hernandez et al., 2013). In the year 2000, Uruguay wasn’t allowed

to export to Europe and the United States due to severe foot-and-mouth disease. This led to an

enormous loss of revenues and a serious economic drawback for Uruguay. A collaboration of

producers, local governments, transport staff, the private sector, IT companies and the central

government wanted to solve this problem by installing a tracking system in cattle to prevent

and detect the source of such diseases or other problems early enough. Until 2013, it was "the

only tracking system in the world with real-time monitoring of 100% of the national cattle herd"

(Hernandez et al., 2013). Chips are inserted in a calf’s ear at birth which work as a tracker and

allow to stay updated with information concerning that specific cow (e.g. when a cow is sold

to a butchery). Thanks to successful installment of this tracking system, Uruguay is able to

take advantage of its skills, knowledge and experience present in this sector by offering this

system to countries that face comparable problems (Hernandez et al., 2013). By exporting the

system to Colombia, Uruguay established an important role in the value chain of cattle across

its own borders. The system is more and more evolving into a system that can be used in other

industries than the cattle industry and therefore offers an enormous competitive advantage

for Uruguay, since strict food safety standards must be met in every country (Hernandez et al.,

2013). This clearly illustrates how a country can upgrade its value chain by leveraging its local

resources into a global value chain.

CHAPTER 2. METHODS OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 34

Workforce Development

(Gereffi et al., 2011)(as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)) state that skills and workforce develop-

ment are crucial elements for enhancing the value in global value chains. In order to maintain

and upgrade their position in a global value chain, countries have to align their development

policies with international labor requirements. People who possess the knowledge, skills and

expertise are needed to continuously being able to adapt to changes in demand. Several Latin

American countries developed their own systems to improve its global value chain.

(Local) Innovation Systems

Although there still exists a gap between the requirements of the sector and the skills available,

local innovation systems are able to provide a basis for upgrading value chains by enhancing

the skills, knowledge and expertise of the actors present in the chain. In both Workforce De-

velopment and Local Innovation Systems, a large diversity of stakeholders has to be present:

Private firms, public and private educational institutions, government, NGOs, associations etc.

(Hernandez et al., 2013). Even of more importance is the way these stakeholders cooperate and

collaborate in order to improve the global value chain.

In order to achieve appropriate innovation, strong networks that integrate the required re-

sources and capabilities need to be established with other actors. By doing so, actors are able

to get the necessary resources and expertise they lack. The effectiveness of an established net-

work strongly depends on the capacity of the actors to exchange information and resources,

defined by (Spielman et al., 2009) as the network’s navigability. In a complex environment, the

social outcome is said to be the result of individual actions determined by actions of others,

interactions between actors and institutional organizations that influence the actions.

Part II

Case Study: Illustration

35

Chapter 3

Examples of Value Chain Analysis

3.1 Introduction

In this chapter, two examples of value chains of products in less developed or developing coun-

tries, that will act as representatives for the description of the quinoa value chain, will be dis-

cussed: First of all the coffee value chain in section 3.2, which is not very complex and has a

focus on the processing phase. Around the turn of the century, the prices of coffee everywhere

in the world were very low due to multinational companies that were responsible for the pro-

cessing phase. The concentration on the processing phase allowed them to capture value away

from the local farmers. The kind of monopoly that existed for these multinational companies

faded away with years passing by and the market is said to be almost fully competitive right now

according to (Gilbert, 2008). (Gilbert, 2008) argues that the lower price was due to the fact that

only part of the final price is attributable to unprocessed coffee. The other part mainly consists

of processing and distribution costs, most likely attributable to the consumers.

The second value chain that is discussed in section 3.3 is that of cocoa. This chain is more com-

plex because the final product, chocolate, requires more different input products and has a lot

more possible applications. Thereby, the prices did not have to cope with significant decreases

but the price of cocoa has remained steady over time. (Gilbert, 2008) states that the market of

cocoa is, like the coffee market nowadays, almost fully competitive. Similar to coffee, where

only a part is attributable to unprocessed coffee, the remainder is induced by the consumers.

Both products are traded on terminal markets around the world. Terminal markets are orga-

37

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 38

nized markets where agricultural products are distributed and sold. Since only a small amount

of coffee and cocoa goes to these markets, it is left out of the value chains on figures 3.1 and 3.3.

However, terminal markets are important instruments to measure the value of coffee and co-

coa because they make a distinction between production markets and retail markets (Gilbert,

2008): On the one hand, processors may buy coffee at a pre-arranged price from foreign coun-

tries while they do not have to be familiar with the prices of coffee in the concerning country.

On the other hand, exporters sell their coffee to processors at a fixed price without taking the

retail price into account. This is complicated by the fact that there is an increasing trend of ver-

tical integration between the exporters and the processors of coffee and cocoa. "The quantity

of coffee beans that processors might want to buy from farmers based on producer prices and

the terminal market price may differ from the quantity they might want to process, given the

terminal market and retail prices" (Gilbert, 2008). A second advantage of terminal markets is

that processors may restrict their supply to increase retail prices which encourages exporters to

directly sell to the terminal market and increase their sales. This eliminates monopolies from

the market. (Gilbert, 2008) states that processors and exporters will be allowed to make quan-

tity decisions most of the time, but they are not allowed to come up with price objectives when

entering the market.

3.2 The Coffee Value Chain

3.2.1 Basic Coffee Supply Chain

Coffee is mainly produced by small and large farmers in Latin America and Africa. These are

represented by ’Farmers’ in figure 3.1. So-called green coffee (i.e. unprocessed coffee) goes

from these farmers to the processors, which are most likely local traders or cooperatives in case

of small farmers. For further processing, the coffee is transported from these local traders to

independent exporters or exporting processors (indicated as ’roasters’ in the figure). They may

transfer it to independent roasters who spray-dry or freeze-dry the coffee before it goes to re-

tailers or they may sell it directly to retailers to be sold as such. The final product may be roasted

coffee in the form of beans or grounded, or soluble (instant) coffee (Gilbert, 2008). As said in

the Introduction, the processing phase is the one most intensified. According to (Gilbert, 2008),

branding is the most prominent cause of this intensification. Since there are many different cof-

fee species, processors can rely on the wishes of customers in specific regions to decide which

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 39

kind of tastes to supply from the wide variety of possibilities. According to (Sutton, 1991)(as

cited by (Gilbert, 2008)), branding of the different types of coffee leads to the establishment of

barriers to market entry. A specific case study of the coffee value chain from Nicaraguan Fair

Trade farmers to Finnish Consumers is outlined below.

Figure 3.1: The basic coffee supply chain. Reprinted from (Gilbert, 2008).

3.2.2 Case Study: Coffee Value Chain from Nicaragua to Finland

This section illustrates the value chain of Fair Trade coffee from the cultivation in Nicaragua

until the consumption in Finland for the period 2005-2009 as described by (Valkila et al., 2010).

Valkila’s research is mainly focused on two retail chains containing data on coffee sales and on

the prices established by producers and consumers for different types of coffee.

First of all, a lot of coffee in Europe comes from Latin-America. Nicaragua was seen as a poor,

undeveloped country relying on the production of coffee to get some revenues. It focuses on

producing Fair Trade coffee while Finland is one of the main consumers of coffee in the world

according to (Valkila et al., 2010). The fact that farmers are often in a subordinate position in

poor countries compared to farmers in rich, developed countries led to the rise of Fair Trade

products and in particular Fair Trade coffee. (Bacon et al., 2008); (Kilian et al., 2006); (Mendoza

and Bastiaensen, 2003); (Zehner, 2002)(as cited by (Valkila et al., 2010)) state that the price re-

tailers ask for Fair Trade products is a lot higher than the price they actually have to pay for it to

the producers. This gap is still increasing, causing so-called transnational corporations in the

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 40

consuming countries to be able to get more revenues and power and at the same time causing

farmers to get a smaller amount of the retail price and therefore become poorer (Daviron and

Ponte, 2005); (Ponte and Gibbon, 2005); (Talbot, 1997) (as cited by (Valkila et al., 2010)). On

the other hand, Fair Trade is also seen as a means to protect against too low or changing coffee

prices.

Recently, several actions were undertaken to take into account the social responsibility and

the environmental sustainability of the coffee production and trade (Valkila et al., 2010). This

is necessary due to the social injustice created by the heterogeneous production of coffee as

mentioned by (Valkila et al., 2010). Coffee can be produced by small farmers, often character-

ized by poor working conditions, or by larger organizations who have more possibilities than

small farmers due to their wealthiness. An option to reduce the poor working conditions cited

by (Valkila et al., 2010) entails the regulation of coffee prices so as to increase the price farmers

would receive. However, this is not a guarantee for an improved working environment and

sufficient wages. The coffee price is determined by the mechanism of supply and demand

and affected by several other factors such as weather, exchange rates, consumer patterns, en-

ergy prices, economic and technological growth, policies etc., making prices very sensitive to

changes (McCalla, 2009)(as cited by (Valkila et al., 2010)). Fair Trade coffee is said to be focused

on coffee produced by small farmers and sets a minimum price such that these farmers get suf-

ficient revenues to build for the future and improve working conditions. On top of this, Fair

Trade products are supposed to be purchased by consumers with a sense of social awareness.

Such consumers are ethically oriented and buy the product because they keep in mind their so-

cial contribution. The price is not the main purpose of buying the product, it is the underlying

way of thinking that is the driver of purchasing a Fair Trade product. Therefore, the consumers

of Fair Trade coffee are willing to pay a higher price if they are assured that the small farmers

in Nicaragua get an acceptable return. Increasing the price of Fair Trade coffee would first in-

crease the revenues of the retailer and in turn also increase the revenues of the farmers, which

opens perspectives for future growth for the farmers, as mentioned earlier in this paragraph.

In their research, (Valkila et al., 2010) compared four kinds of conventional coffees with two

kinds of Fair Trade coffees. The coffees were all first transported to Finland before being roasted

and wrapped up in packages to be sold by retailers. According to (Valkila et al., 2010), the value

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 41

of the sales of the two Fair Trade coffees was only 1.3% of all the sales present in the data, while

the value of the sales of the four conventional coffees amounted to 91.3% of the sales in the data.

Obviously, products that are scarcer are expected to be more expensive than products that are

available in large quantities. Table 3.2.2 below shows the evolution of the prices of conventional

and Fair Trade coffee for the period January 2006 until June 2009. It is clear that Fair Trade coffee

is always around 50% higher than conventional coffee, mainly due to the ethical value added as

outlined above. The data collected by (Valkila et al., 2010) suggested that consumers preferred

to buy cheaper coffees instead of more expensive ones like the Fair Trade coffee, except when

people are committed to social awareness in the world and Southern America in particular. Al-

though there are fluctuations in the price of coffee, Fair Trade coffee never gets really cheap due

to the settlement of a Fair Trade minimum price. If the market price is greater than this mini-

mum price, then an extra premium, the so-called ’social premium’ is added to the market price

to make the distinction between conventional and Fair Trade coffee. On the other hand, if the

market price is smaller, then the minimum price, the set floor price, is applied. How the price

is distributed to retailers, cooperatives and farmers depends on the quality, the market prices,

costs for the different actors etc. In the following paragraph, an example of the distribution of

the price in case a cooperative offers both conventional and Fair Trade coffee is given.

According to (Valkila et al., 2010), back in 2006, a cooperative (An organization that brings to-

gether several farmers to act as a larger entity) sold 40% of its coffee as Fair Trade coffee for

around €2,62/kg (Note that this price is significantly lower than the consumer price depicted

in table 3.2.2). This was the minimum price a cooperative received before the price increased

steadily over the years. The social premium amounted to €0,10/kg or 4% of €2,62/kg. This so-

cial premium was merely used to improve working conditions in the cooperative. The price

the cooperative charged for conventional coffee was €2,38/kg. 60% of the coffee was sold as

conventional coffee. The average price of the coffee sales of the cooperative equals €2,44/kg

(= 40% x €2,52/kg + 60% x €2,38/kg), not taking the Fair Trade social premium into account.

The farmers that were part of the cooperative were required to pay several costs, such as export

costs, processing costs, administrative costs etc. which amounted to €0,58/kg. This resulted

in €1,86/kg being the price farmers received per kg coffee (= €2,44/kg - €0,58/kg). It is allowed

to state that farmers receive an amount that is actually only 70% of the price cooperatives re-

ceive. When calculating the average consumer price for 2006 (40% x €7,42/kg + 60% x €4,79/kg

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 42

Table 3.1: Consumer prices (€/kg) of conventional and Fair Trade coffee in Finland based on

purchases in one retail chain for the years 2006-2009. Copied from (Valkila et al., 2010).

2006 2007 2008 2009

Conventional coffee 4,79 4,66 4,94 4,83

Fair Trade coffee 7,42 7,36 7,82 7,92

= €5,84/kg), farmers only get 32% (= €1,86/kg / €5,84/kg) of the price consumers pay. We can

conclude that farmers get significantly diluted in percentages the longer the chain gets. (Valk-

ila, 2009)(as cited by (Valkila et al., 2010)) states that Fair Trade farmers in Nicaragua only have

a small surface of 3 ha to cultivate coffee together with very low yields around 300kg/ha while

conventional farmers have yields up to 2000kg/ha in the same region. It is for this reason and

because quality standards are quite high for cooperatives that farmers often want to get around

cooperatives and sell directly to mainstream markets. We have to say that all the above num-

bers are for one specific cooperative and farmer. These numbers differ for each cooperative and

farmer due to the occurrence of extra costs, rules, location dependent factors etc.

Figure 3.2 illustrates the itinerary conventional and Fair Trade coffee follow from the producing

country Nicaragua to the consuming country Finland. The arrow in bold indicates the most

important direction that is followed. The normal arrows show the different possible routes to

follow while the dashed arrows represent the route that was originally chosen by farmers when

Fair Trade did not exist yet. According to (Valkila et al., 2010), the dashed arrows are also called

the "more direct trade", as this is the route roasters use to get coffee directly from small farmers.

Although the concept is very different, conventional and Fair Trade coffees’ chains are almost

exactly identical. Only large farms are not present in the case of Fair Trade coffee as this type

of coffee is only produced in small farms. As can been seen, roasters often use trading houses

and export companies to get the coffee from the cooperatives to them. Since there are a lot of

actors involved in the value chain, it is difficult to get accurate information on traded quantities

and prices. Some estimations regarding the distribution of the retail price for consumers and

producers in the conventional and Fair Trade coffee chain from Nicaragua to Finland for the

period 2006-2009 are given by (Valkila et al., 2010) and outlined in what follows. The market

price of coffee is assumed to be moderate and the price of Fair Trade coffee in the producing

country amounts to €2,22/kg, the minimum price for Fair Trade coffee at that time. Assuming

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 43

roasters pay a moderate price for their raw materials (green coffee), we can state that a price

of €1,95/kg is what Finnish companies are charged. Thereby, a transportation and insurance

cost for one container of coffee (21000kg green coffee) has to be included, both together cost-

ing around €1550 or €0,07/kg at that time according to (Valkila et al., 2010). Organizations in

producer countries were expected to receive a higher share since the Fair Trade price is higher

than the conventional price. However, conventional coffee producers were the ones who even-

tually received a larger amount than the Fair Trade coffee producers. According to (Daviron

and Ponte, 2005) and (Talbot, 1997)(as cited by (Valkila et al., 2010)), a larger amount of what

the consumers in Finland paid for conventional coffee was received in the producing country

than in other countries due to the low prices charged for conventional coffee in Finland. These

prices for conventional coffee are low on the one hand because retailers want to attract cus-

tomers by asking low prices. The margins for Fair Trade coffee are kept pretty high on the other

hand. Since premiums resulting from the sales of Fair Trade coffee are not or at least ineffi-

ciently transferred to Nicaragua and most likely end up in Finland, the share of conventional

coffee price that ends up in Nicaragua is higher.

We can conclude from this case study example considering the coffee value chain from Nicaragua

to Finland that market prices determine Fair Trade prices and its advantages to a large extent

(Valkila et al., 2010). Fair Trade prices are expected to be higher than market prices. This nor-

mally is an advantage for farmers in the producing countries. However, while consumers in

Finland paid a larger amount for Fair Trade coffee during the considered period, producers in

Nicaragua did not reap appropriate and proportional benefits due to coffee market prices being

too close to the Fair Trade minimum price. Furthermore, Fair Trade segments customers who

are able and willing to pay more for the social and ethical idea behind the purchase of coffee. It

also enables companies to depict themselves as a socially responsible company. Although Fair

Trade is very popular and trendy to help local farmers in less developed countries, it might need

some further investigation and re-design of the value chain.

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 44

Figure 3.2: The marketing chain of coffee from Nicaragua to Finland. Reprinted from (Valkila

et al., 2010).

3.3 The Cocoa Value Chain

As described in the introduction, the value chain of cocoa is more complex than that of coffee.

The value chain of cocoa as part of the final good chocolate is depicted in figure 3.3. First of

all, cocoa is a crop that is mainly produced by small farmers in Latin America. They sell it to

local traders or cooperatives, who sometimes process it locally but mostly sell it to exporters or

converters (domestic or multinational). The exporters ship the cocoa beans to Europe or North

America, where the beans are processed into butter, which is the basic ingredient for chocolate,

and powder, which is also an ingredient for chocolate but sometimes used in confectioneries.

Sometimes, exporters directly sell to large manufacturers that are able to process the beans.

This is shown by a broken arrow on the figure, which indicates the lower importance of the

link. At last, the produced chocolate is sold to supermarkets and specialist retail outlets who

CHAPTER 3. EXAMPLES OF VALUE CHAIN ANALYSIS 45

sell it to the public. The complexity of the cocoa-chocolate value chain lies in the fact that

cocoa is only one of three ingredients necessary for the production of chocolate. As indicated

on the figure, dairies such as milk, and sugar are the other required ingredients. The supply

chain of chocolate is therefore disposed of three supply chains that are in relationships with

each other. (Gilbert, 2008) mentions that cocoa farmers may see themselves as crucial actors

for the chocolate manufacturers, while chocolate manufacturers see the cocoa farmers as just a

supplier of one of their ingredients. This allows (Gilbert, 2008) to state that the cocoa-chocolate

value chain is more dubious and dependent on factors than the coffee value chain.

Figure 3.3: The cocoa-chocolate supply chain. Reprinted from (Gilbert, 2008).

Part III

Case Study: An Analysis of the Value Chain

of Quinoa

47

48

49

Introduction

This case study presents the different stages in the value chain of quinoa from Peru to Bel-

gium/Europe. First of all, an investigation of the social-economic context was done for two

specific regions in Peru: Puno and Ayacucho. These regions are the most important for quinoa

production and, especially Ayacucho, also the most dependent on quinoa production. After the

analysis of the current situation, some future insights on quinoa production are given to con-

clude this chapter. Secondly, the characteristics of the value chain are described: what does the

chain look like, what are the different stages of the value chain, what are the constraints every

stage has to cope with, which prices are paid, which actors have multiple roles, which stages

do they cover, an elaboration on the actors etc. Since most of the companies are not easily ac-

cessible and not willing to share their private information with the public, an estimation of the

impacts by the different actors in all the stages is done. This is based on information for Peru

in general and information or data we were able to gather through interviews with a Belgian

wholesaler and importer and Peruvian processors/exporters. In chapter 6, the relationships

between the actors are assessed based on the constraints and margins discussed in each stage.

This made us conduct a qualitative as well as a quantitative analysis in which we evaluate the

power of the different stages in the value chain of quinoa. Finally, insights and possibilities for

upgrading the current value chain are given.

50

Chapter 4

Socio-Economic Context

4.1 Introduction

A broad explanation of the socio-economic situation of Peru and Bolivia in recent years is given

in appendix F. This is representative for the case study being discussed in the following sections

because the main farmers, processors and exporters presented in this case study are located

near Ayacucho, the capital city of the Huamanga Province which lies in the Ayacucho Region

and Puno, the capital city of the Puno Region and Puno Province. Both cities have similar char-

acteristics: They are situated more than 2500 meters above sea level and around 150.000 people

are living in the cities. These regions in Peru are known for their high poverty rate, especially

Ayacucho, which has one of the highest in the whole country. Since it is comparable to the sit-

uation in Bolivia, Bolivia is included in this part of the case study as a means of reference. The

capital of Peru, Lima, scores slightly better in terms of poverty and development. Lima offers

a lot more possibilities for trade and export. This explains why most processors and storage

holders are located in Lima. This is also the case for the processors and storage holders in our

case study. To give an idea of the current poverty and socio-economic situation in Ayacucho as

well as Puno, the position of Ayacucho and Lima compared to each other and the rest of Peru

is discussed below by means of several tables. Note that this data is from 2007 and that some

changes have occurred since then.

51

CHAPTER 4. SOCIO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT 52

4.2 Population and Education

Table 4.5 shows absolute numbers of the population in Peru in general, in the Ayacucho region

and the region of Lima. The table makes a distinction between people living in rural areas

and people living in urban areas. The education part of the table shows that there still is a

huge difference between men and women in the society and also makes a distinction between

the urban and the rural population. Since 42% of the people in the region of Ayacucho live

in rural areas compared to 24% in the rest of Peru, we can state that agriculture is one of the

most important sources of income for the people in this region. When looking at the illiteracy

of the population of Peru, it seems that a lot more women are illiterate compared to men. This

illustrates the huge gap that still exists between the two genders, especially in the region of

Ayacucho. The percentage of illiterate, uneducated people in the region of Ayacucho is 10%

higher than in the rest of Peru. Both show the severe poverty that is present in this region.

4.3 Participation in Economic Activity

The second table (Table 4.5) entails the participation to economic activities by people of age

14 and older. The poverty of the Ayacucho region is again illustrated by its lower percentage

of population that is economically active compared to the rest of Peru (49,4% versus 54,1%).

The percentage of economically active population is the highest in Lima (58%). A lot of the

population in Ayacucho that is economically active (29%) is employed in agriculture and fishing

activities while this is only 12,9% for Peru in total. As was shown in the previous table, most

of the economically active people are men, not only in Ayacucho. Another notable measure

shows that relatively the double of the population in Ayacucho works in hunting and forestry

compared to the rest of Peru (46% versus 23%). This is only 3,8% in Lima, where more people

work in manufacturing industries (13,2%). In Ayacucho, this only amounts to 3,8%. Other facets

that indicate the severe poverty in the region of Ayacucho relatively to the rest of Peru are the

limited availability of electricity, television, computers, use of gas, primitive use of materials for

building houses and extensive use of firewood.

CHAPTER 4. SOCIO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT 53

4.4 Social Impact by Outsiders

The severe poverty present in some regions in Peru (especially the region of Ayacucho) was

one of the main reasons why organizations such as Solid Food International (Elaborated and

explained in the following sections) want to work with small farmers. They feel that having a

social impact nowadays is very important, not only for its own relationships and profits but

also to create a better world in general. By focussing on small farmers living in poor conditions,

such organizations want to help them out of the severe poverty. Several ways of doing so are

enumerated below and provide an indication for the construction of the value chain:

1. Linking farmers from poor regions with processors and storage holders in Lima.

2. Making sure farmers get a sufficient return on their sales.

3. Optimizing the cultivation process for the farmers and the processing steps for the pro-

cessors.

4.5 Prospects for the Future

It seems obvious that consumption as a food will remain the most important source of demand

for quinoa in years to come. However, niche markets such as the cosmetics, medicinal and

pharmaceutics industry in which quinoa’s nutritional values are used will also thrive demand

and contribute to the expansion of quinoa cultivation in Peru and Bolivia.

Since the demand of quinoa is still increasing and more and more exceeding borders world-

wide, the production as well as the cultivated area of quinoa in Peru will continue to increase,

certainly in Ayacucho and Puno, where quinoa is the major source of income for the poor farm-

ers. According to (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014), Peruvian authorities and the Min-

istry of Agriculture and Foreign Trade have stated that the goal is to expand the cultivated area

to 100 000 hectares in the next years. Furthermore, the authorities are looking to encourage

the local production and consumption of quinoa to stimulate the combined demand because

more than 75% of the production is exported. If we are to believe the predictions of the authori-

ties, cultivation and production of quinoa will continue to flourish which will lead to significant

benefits for the local population in Peru, despite the recent drop in prices and new plantations

of quinoa starting up overseas.

CHAPTER 4. SOCIO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT 54

Tab

le4.

1:Po

pu

lati

on

and

edu

cati

on

inPe

ru:R

egio

no

fAya

cuch

oan

dLi

ma.

Co

pie

dfr

om

(Cen

sos

nac

ion

ales

de

po

bla

ció

ny

de

vivi

end

a,20

08).

Per

uA

yacu

cho

Reg

ion

Lim

aR

egio

n

Var

iabl

e/In

dic

ator

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Po

pu

lati

on

Po

pu

lati

on

per

area

ofr

esid

ence

2741

215

710

061

248

910

08

445

211

100

Urb

an20

810

288

75,9

355

384

588

275

823

98

Ru

ral

660

186

924

,125

710

542

169

388

2

Ed

uca

tio

n

Illi

tera

tep

op

ula

tio

n(A

ge15

and

old

er)

135

955

87,

169

922

17,9

132

148

2,1

Men

336

270

3,6

1610

48,

425

763

0,8

Wo

men

102

328

810

,653

818

26,9

106

385

3,3

Urb

an54

879

03,

727

325

11,7

123

165

2

Ru

ral

810

768

19,7

4259

727

,28

983

7,5

CHAPTER 4. SOCIO-ECONOMIC CONTEXT 55

Tab

le4.

2:Pa

rtic

ipat

ion

inE

con

om

icA

ctiv

ity.

Co

pie

dfr

om

(Cen

sos

nac

ion

ales

de

po

bla

ció

ny

de

vivi

end

a,20

08).

Per

uA

yacu

cho

Reg

ion

Lim

aR

egio

n

Var

iabl

e/In

dic

ator

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Abs

.nu

mbe

rs%

Par

tici

pat

ion

inE

con

om

icA

ctiv

ity

(14

and

old

er)

Eco

no

mic

ally

Act

ive

Po

pu

lati

on

(EA

P)

1063

788

020

016

73

744

947

EPA

acti

vity

rate

54,1

49,4

58

Men

71,2

66,9

71,8

Wo

men

37,7

32,6

45,2

EPA

acco

rdin

gto

mai

no

ccu

pat

ion

1016

361

410

019

117

310

03

611

300

100

Agr

icu

ltu

ralA

ctiv

itie

s

and

Fis

hin

g1

311

748

12,9

5503

328

,860

080

1,7

No

n-q

ual

ified

wo

rk,s

ervi

ces,

paw

n,

(str

eet)

ven

do

rs,a

nd

rela

ted

259

043

025

,551

950

27,2

732

414

20,3

EPA

acco

rdin

gto

eco

no

mic

acti

vity

1016

361

410

019

117

310

03

611

300

100

Agr

icu

ltu

re,l

ives

tock

,

hu

nti

ng

and

fore

stry

234

249

323

8798

646

137

829

3,8

Man

ufa

ctu

rin

gin

du

stri

es94

395

49,

37

342

3,8

477

799

13,2

Chapter 5

Characteristics of the Value Chain of Quinoa

5.1 Introduction

As mentioned before and again confirmed by (Salcedo et al., 2013) in their paper about the

international trade of quinoa, peasant producers aka small farmers are the ones who are re-

sponsible for most of the production of quinoa. This makes the supply of quinoa very much

spread out over the different producing countries. (Salcedo et al., 2013) estimate that there are

70 000 small farmers in Bolivia and 100 000 in Peru, which results in an average growth of 1

hectare per farmer. He assumes this is very important data to better understand the market

channels that are installed to bring quinoa to the numerous local, regional and export markets.

Although the structure of the several kinds of quinoa is identical and adjusted to the relatively

small volumes that are produced by each farmer, not only its quality and physical characteris-

tics can be very different but also the channels responsible for the quinoa flow may somewhat

differ provided the final destination of the product. The main components of the value chain of

quinoa are shown in table 5.1. A simple representation of the different stages of the value chain,

incorporating these components, is depicted in figure 5.1. Each stage is outlined below in more

detail.

Since quinoa is not consumed immediately after harvest, (Salcedo et al., 2013) state that mar-

keting and distribution also comprise several actors of the value chain of quinoa: These are so-

called processors, people involved in drying, dehulling and saponin removal of the grain, which

can be described as preliminary processes before being consumed or transported. Due to the

increase in demand, particularly from international markets, quinoa adopted higher standards

57

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 58

regarding its quality and identical grain structure. These led to being able to cut back in trans-

action costs and assure a better quality and safety.

Until now, there is no information accessible regarding the distribution of resources between

the actors in the value chain. However, as (Salcedo et al., 2013) mention, most of the income

is supposedly retained by food industry traders and processors, which is also the fact in value

chains other than that of quinoa. (Salcedo et al., 2013) give the example of the retail prices in

United States supermarkets in July 2013. The prices were $14-25/kg for pearl quinoa, while the

export price free on board is $3/kg. This illustrates the fact that producers actually get a lot

less money than supermarkets overseas are asking. In what follows, the value chain stages and

actors are discussed. We mainly based the division of the different stages on the description of

(Salcedo et al., 2013) and (Hatch et al., 2015).

Table 5.1: Main components of the value chain of quinoa. Reprinted from (Salcedo et al., 2013)

based on data from (IDEPRO, 2012)(as cited by (Salcedo et al., 2013)).

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 59

Figure 5.1: Simple Representation of the Value Chain of Quinoa in Peru. Based on the Value

Chain as depicted by (Salcedo et al., 2013).

Figure 5.2: Simple Structure of the Value Chain of Quinoa based on (Hatch et al., 2015) and

(Salcedo et al., 2013).

5.2 Stages of the Value Chain

The value chain of quinoa in Peru consists of multiple actors who have different standards

and unequal power relative to each other. Since every actor wants to optimize his/her own

value, they seek other methodologies, technologies and advantages in linkages with other ac-

tors, keeping in mind the realization of their own objectives. The simplest structure of the

quinoa value chain is depicted in figure 5.2. Note that this representation is slightly different

than the one outlined before by (Salcedo et al., 2013). The difference lies in the fact that the

value chain of (Salcedo et al., 2013) is made based on linkages and global activities that are per-

formed in the chain while the value chain of (Hatch et al., 2015) makes a distinction between the

stages based on the actors that perform the activities. Therefore, some parts of the value chains

overlap, while other parts cover multiple stages in the other value chain. An overview of the dif-

ferent stages from both perspectives, together with their activities, constraints and respective

margins is given in figure 5.3. An explanation of each stage and its corresponding actors related

to the figure is given below.

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 60

5.2.1 Provision of Inputs

Farmers or producers, processors and storage holders of quinoa all have to be provided with

several different utilities and raw materials before being able to successfully conduct their ac-

tivities. The provision of inputs sets out the preliminary step in the value chain as can be seen

in figure 5.3. However, it can be taken together with the primary production step because pro-

ducers have to make sure they have the necessary inputs available.

The first thing the small farmers need is a piece of land. This can be rented from larger farm-

ers/landowners or associations or can be of their own. In Peru, it is often the case that large

farmers/landowners divide their land in small parts so as to provide small farmers with land

which they can use to grow whatever kind of crop they want. In return, the small farmers pay

a monthly or annual fee to the landowners. Sometimes, the small farmers are associated to the

landowners, which facilitates the process for later stage actors (e.g. processors). Secondly, many

quinoa seeds and fertilizers are necessary to cultivate quinoa on a large scale. These seeds can

be provided by seeders (directly or indirectly through external organizations) or by producers

themselves from previous harvests. In Puno, the main source of seeds is from own production

of a previous harvest (around 90%), while the remaining 10% is acquired from seeders (Hatch

et al., 2015). Fertilizers can be chemical or natural. In the lowlands, a lot of chemical fertilizers

are used to boost the production, while in the highlands and especially Puno, only natural fer-

tilizers are applied on the grains. Thirdly, equipment to sow and fertilize the seeds and harvest

the crops as well as warehouses to store raw materials and harvested quinoa are fundamental

for the producers, the processors and the storage holders. Most large farmers, processors and

storage holders have their own equipment available, some partly use other equipment for spe-

cific processes and some have to borrow all the equipment. According to (Hatch et al., 2015), in

the case of Puno, all the machines of the producers are rented. Sometimes, producers receive

financing from the local municipality for the rent of machinery and equipment. Furthermore,

since innovation is very important in this sector, research for new opportunities need to be con-

ducted. This occurs indirectly through universities and investigation and development funds

established by the government. The information is most likely provided to independent agri-

cultural development organizations which transfer the information towards the farmers and

producers. The information generated by innovation techniques can also be used to foresee

training and technical assistance for the farmers. Technical assistance and training go hand in

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 61

hand with each other in order to provide appropriate and sufficient skills to the different actors

such that the processes can be performed as good as possible. In this respect, certifications play

an important role because they seek meeting the requirements and guarantee quality products

for domestic and foreign markets. This requires a thorough knowledge of the market they want

to address. In Puno, around 30% of the producers seek technical assistance and look for train-

ing to improve their production (Hatch et al., 2015).

We can derive from all of the above that lack of information, equipment, raw materials, training

etc. (i.e. the constraints) can occur throughout the whole value chain. The specific constraints

for each stage are also discussed in the following sections and can be categorized as external or

internal to the value chain stage. Internal constraints are those constraints imposed directly on

the actors by limitations of the actor’s own activities. Examples are lack of seeds available, lack

of storage and equipment etc. External constraints are those constraints that are imposed by

external actors or by the market and cannot be controlled. Examples are the lack of information,

research and technical assistance, shortage of land use, lack of capital etc. In the ’provision of

inputs’ stage, lack of land providers, too expensive land, unavailability of seeds or fertilizers,

lack of equipment and facilities, no research, training and technical assistance are the main

constraints. A margin is not discussed in this phase because it is supposed that the primary

production phase has full responsibility of the provision of inputs and production. Therefore,

the margin will be discussed in the next section.

5.2.2 Primary Production

The second step in the value chain, after the provision of inputs, is the production step. This

step involves the cultivation of quinoa. The activities performed in this step include preparation

of land and equipment, sowing the quinoa seeds, application of fertilizers and phytosanitary

work to protect the plants against pests and diseases, and harvesting. According to (Salcedo

et al., 2013), this part of the value chain consists merely of the small individual producers of

quinoa. (Salcedo et al., 2013) consider the small farmers as the weakest link in the value chain

and those with the least bargaining power because they don’t have infrastructure to store, dry

and thresh products. On top of this, their income is very low. Sometimes, the small farmers are

associated with larger landowners or they are united with other small farmers in associations

so as to strengthen their position in the value chain. In Puno, 20% of the producers are said to

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 62

be part of an association. (Hatch et al., 2015) states that 2% of the production of the farmers in

Puno is used as seeds in the next years, own consumption ranges from 5% to 22%, around 30% is

stored for later sale and half of the production is sold immediately after harvest, depending on

the farmers’ intentions. Figure 5.3 includes a light blue double arrow going from the producers

to the framework with organizations that include processors and exporters because these or-

ganizations perform the activities normally performed by processors as well as exporters. This

indicates the interrelationships both groups and is further explained in section 5.3 ’Multi-stage

actors’. The dark blue arrow coming from the framework of intermediaries expresses the re-

lationships that intermediaries in foreign countries build with primary producers in order to

have an economic and a social impact on the small farmers. Obviously, they also have con-

tracts with processors and exporters but by establishing a relationship with the farmers, they

try to help the farmers to defend their rights and create social awareness among the people not

only in Peru, but also in Europe and other continents, depending on the resident country of the

organization. Therefore, a specific reference from the intermediaries to the primary producers

was made on the figure. These intermediaries can be regarded as the importers of quinoa in

foreign countries. An example of such a company is Solid Food Europe, which is described later

in section 5.3.7.

Constraints primary producers have to cope with include the shortage of land use due to lots

being too expensive to buy or rent or too many lots already taken, lack of training, technical as-

sistance, information exchange, research and innovation, lack of storage and equipment, lack

of certifications to assure quality, inability to sell at fair prices, transportation difficulties. These

are external constraints. The internal constraints for primary producers comprise the unavail-

ability of seeds, pests or diseases of seeds or plants and bad fertilization of seeds. The area har-

vested by farmers in the region of Puno amounted to 32 261 ha in 2014, while the production for

that year was 36 158 ton. This resulted in a yield of 1 121 kg/ha. This is slightly less than the yield

generated in Ayacucho in 2014 (1 341 kg/ha), where harvested area (7 696 ha) and production

(10 323 ton) are a lot lower. The region of Puno can be regarded as the most important region

of production of quinoa in Peru with a total of 61 425 production units in 2014. This adds up

to 82% of the total production units in Peru (Hatch et al., 2015). Based on the previous figures

and the fact that 5% of the total production units are located in Ayacucho, the absolute number

of production units in Ayacucho is 3 745. An overview of the harvested area, the production

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 63

and the yield are given in table 5.1 for the years 2001, 2013 and 2014 to show the enormous

evolution the respective regions have witnessed. Lima is included because in recent years they

also started to grow quinoa in that region as well as more up north to the coast. The circum-

stances, think not only about the height and the weather but also better infrastructure etc., here

are a lot better, which results in very high yields compared to the regions of Ayacucho and Puno.

Table 5.2: Harvested area, production and yield for different regions in Peru. Reprinted from

(Cenagro, 2012)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)).

Harvested Area (ha) Production (ton) Yield (kg/ha)

2001 2013 2014 2001 2013 2014 2001 2013 2014

Ayacucho 1 374 4 653 7 696 1 144 4 925 10 323 833 1 058 1 341

Puno 18 717 29 886 32 261 15 484 29 331 36 158 827 981 1 121

Lima 62 637 202 1 718 3 258 2 702

Total Peru 25 600 44 788 68 037 22 269 52 092 114 343 870 1151 1681

(Fallis, 2013) states that the producer or farmer price is the price farmers receive at the place

of production, before the product is transferred to the next stage of the value chain. From the

90s until 2007, this price remained more or less stable in Peru at a rate of S/.1,63/kg 1, which

corresponded to $0,39/kg at that time. This evolved over the years, amounting to S/.7,99/kg or

$2,81/kg (the average national quinoa farm price) in 2014, but decreasing again. A distinction

can be made for the farm prices in Puno and Ayacucho, where the farm price amounted to

S/.9,58/kg and S/.7,73/kg respectively, which indicates that farmers in Puno were able to get

more profits than those in Ayacucho. The evolution from 2007-2015 of the average national

farm price is given in table 6.1 in the next chapter. This price is used to calculate marketing

margins and share of the total price in the next sections, while also considering that the cost

farmers incur for the cultivation of quinoa lies around 50% of the farm price. Therefore, the

income of the farmers really depends on the wealth of the industry and export opportunities.

1’S/.’ being the currency of Peru: Peruvian nuevo sol (S/.1 = $0,308)

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 64

5.2.3 Storage and Basic Processing

In this stage, the quinoa grain is collected and goes through processes such as cleaning, dry-

ing, separating the edible part of the grain from the chaff around it (i.e. threshing), selection

and storage. These activities can be done by the farmers that executed the primary produc-

tion phase but according to (Salcedo et al., 2013), this stage often comprises small companies

(farmers/processors) that are united in cooperatives and associations. These are the ones that

form so-called joined forces. As depicted on figure 5.3, there is some kind of overlap between

the two kinds of representations, indicating that the storage and basic processing phase can in-

clude primary producers as well as processors. Small-scale facilities are formed to enhance the

processes of cleaning, drying and threshing. The places where the quinoa is stored are mostly

close to the field of production. Once the product is finished, it is ready to be transported for

further processing or export to regional and international markets. In the case of Puno, quinoa

is collected by a specific type of collectors and brought to processors that are located in the clos-

est city. This can also be done by the processor himself. In some very rare cases, retailers and

wholesalers from nearby cities act as the collectors and the processors from where the quinoa

is further distributed for domestic export and consumption.

External constraints with which actors in this stage of the value chain have to cope include

asymmetries in price and information with farmers as well as with further processors, exporters

or intermediaries, infrastructure problems (e.g. bad roads on which quinoa needs to be trans-

ported from farmer to processor), lack of storage facilities and equipment, lack of certifications

to assure quality standards, limited technical assistance and training, inefficiencies in linkages

with farmers or exporters and limited availability of capital. Internal constraints for the storage

holders and processors are lack of storage space, outdated equipment, limited technology and

too few improvement and innovation possibilities available at the plant.

5.2.4 Industrialization

The next stage is the industrialization stage as indicated by (Salcedo et al., 2013). This stage

overlaps with the processing and exporting phases that were distinguished by (Hatch et al.,

2015) (Figure 5.3). The main activities performed in this stage are the collection, extraction

and preparation of organic or conventional quinoa for the market. Quite often, this phase is

covered by the same company as the previous phase and therefore can be considered together

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 65

(see section 5.3 ’Multi-stage actors’). According to (Hatch et al., 2015), 85%-90% of the quinoa

that is commercialized is sold as bulk, the remainder is sold as pearls, flakes, flour and pop-

corn. Exceptionally, it can be used in biscuits, bread, cakes, juices, energy bars and delicacies.

The product is then sold to either regional or international markets. The most important actors

in this stage are small and medium-sized enterprises, including some cooperatives and asso-

ciations. In the region of Puno, there are 11 exporting companies that distribute to either the

domestic market or the international market. The average export prices for the period 2007-

2016 in Peru are given in column 4 of table 6.1.

Constraints in this stage of the value chain are very similar to those described in the previ-

ous stage since this stage may include multi-stage covering actors. However, exporters also

may have to deal with a lack of diversification markets to export quinoa to, transportation dif-

ficulties, lack of certifications to be allowed to export to several countries, implications by the

government, limitations of importing countries etc. which are all external constraints.

5.2.5 Marketing

The marketing phase in the value chain as described by (Salcedo et al., 2013) involves exporters,

intermediaries (cfr. importers) and wholesalers or retailers who buy organic or conventional

quinoa from the processors. This is illustrated on figure 5.3, where it is clear that the ’Market-

ing’ stage partly overlaps ’exporters’ and totally overlaps ’intermediaries’, ’wholesalers/retailers’

and ’final consumption’. In most cases, as well in the case of the multi-stage actors described

below, the quinoa is distributed either domestically or internationally. In our case study, we fo-

cus on marketing for the foreign market, as we want to analyse the chain from introduction in

Peru to consumption in Belgium/Europe. Constraints that can occur in this stage of the value

chain comprise mostly external constraints: The absence or shortage of a market, the enormous

transportation costs that may have to be incurred when quinoa has to be transported overseas,

lack of capital, lack of competition may lead to oligopolies or monopolies, asymmetries in price

and information, several kinds of fees, inability to meet quality standards and certifications that

assure the standards, licenses that allow to sell the quinoa, wholesalers or retailers that are dif-

ficult to get to, distribution systems that are incomplete etc. Internal constraints can be the lack

of storage space or insufficient facilities.

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 66

Marketing for the Domestic Market

The domestic market consists merely of local markets in neighbouring villages of the small pro-

ducers. They go there on a weekly basis and sell their products to most often rural populations

who live in the small villages. Wholesalers that have close relationships with processors and

storage holders provide quinoa for regional, bigger markets and stores in or close to urban cen-

tres. (Salcedo et al., 2013) state that when the processing facilities are also located in an urban

centre, grain brokers can directly address processors to buy quinoa from them. Column 3 in

table 6.1 contains the Peruvian consumer price in $/kg for the period 2007-2016. This is the

average price people pay for average quinoa. The data until 2014 is obtained from (Hatch et al.,

2015) while for 2015 and 2016, an estimation was made based on the current consumer price in

Peru.

Marketing for the Foreign Market

According to (Salcedo et al., 2013), higher standards, not only of the way quinoa is presented,

but also regarding its uniformity and safety, must be met when quinoa is intended to be ex-

ported to markets outside of Peru. Therefore, organic quinoa is the type of quinoa that is most

used for export because it is certified and easily goes through specialized marketing channels

which have direct linkages with importers at the final destination. The exporters of Peru put

the quinoa in containers at the harbour in Lima, from where it is shipped towards Europe. Ex-

porters have an appropriate administrative structure and sufficient financial support available

to satisfy the relatively high standards implied by international trade agencies. Besides these,

some cooperatives of farmers and several associations also export to foreign markets. They

may be assisted by public institutions or NGO’s in order to guide them in the process of selling

quinoa to foreign markets. On the other end of the freight transport overseas are the (Euro-

pean) importers. These are normally medium or large companies located in the country or a

neighbouring country of the destination market. Examples of such companies responsible for

the import of quinoa from Peru and Bolivia and acting as intermediaries are Solid Food (an

organization working together with local farmers (see further) looking to import quinoa from

Peru, while also helping the local population, and selling to wholesalers/retailers in Europe),

DO-IT (Dutch Organic International Trade; can be regarded as a real trader of the quinoa prod-

uct) and Markal, a French company importing, packaging and distributing quinoa and other

foods. They make sure the quinoa gets transported from the importing quay to the wholesalers

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 67

and retailers, ready to be sold for final consumption. Solid Food, for example, delivers quinoa

to Bio-Planet where it is sold for €10-13/kg. Bio-Planet acts, just like other stores and super-

markets, as wholesaler/retailer in the value chain, purchasing the quinoa from the importers

and selling it to customers, who are the final consumers. Figure 5.3 on the one hand mentions

DO-IT, Markal and Solid Food as intermediaries, with the dark blue arrow indicating that they

also try to have an impact on the local population by establishing close relationships with lo-

cal farmers and processors. On the other hand, the figure describes Bio-Planet, Delhaize, Lidl,

Oxfam and Aldi as wholesalers and retailers being the next stage in the value chain and the last

step towards the final consumers. For the intermediary prices in the fifth column of table 6.1,

(Bio-Planet, nd) provided us with figures for a mediocre type of quinoa. Unfortunately, since

no data was available for the intermediary price before 2009, we made an estimation of these

prices and found that it lied between $3/kg and $4/kg. Therefore, we can state that margins that

will be calculated based on this price are an estimation of the reality and are mainly used to be

able to have an idea of the prevailing relationships and ratios.

5.2.6 Final Consumption

The final consumer is the one who buys the quinoa in supermarkets, in small shops, on the lo-

cal, provincial or regional markets, from exporters or on fairs. The price paid by the consumers

in countries like Belgium nowadays ranges from €8/kg for Aldi’s own label quinoa to €13/kg for

organic fair trade quinoa (Quitho by Solid: €12,90/kg for red quinoa) while the price consumers

in Peru pay ranges from $3-8/kg. This difference is mainly due to the extra transportation costs

incurred and the margin that intermediaries in importing countries are taking on quinoa. The

third column of table 6.1 includes the Peruvian consumer price of quinoa. Note that this differs

largely from region to region and from store to store. Therefore, for the years 2015 and 2016,

the average is calculated based on information from different stores in different regions. For

the years 2007-2014, we were able to gather this information from (Vinculos Agricolas, nd). The

last column in table 6.1 contains the data for the European consumer price in $/kg for the pe-

riod 2013-2016. These prices were provided by (Bio-Planet, nd). Although their database did

not allow to provide consumer prices before 2013, we estimated the consumer prices before

2013 and found that it fluctuated between $5/kg in 2007 and $7/kg in 2012.

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 68

5.3 Multi-Stage Actors

Most of the multi-stage actors have established contracts with small farmers in the region that

supply quinoa to them. The multi-stage actor then stores and processes the quinoa. These

multi-stage actors also have contracts with local or regional wholesalers and retailers, when

the quinoa is intended for domestic consumption or they have contracts with intermediaries

overseas when the quinoa is intended for international consumption. We were able to contact

several of the largest quinoa processors and exporters in Peru: Vinculos Agricolas, Alisur, De

Guste, Avendaño Trading Company and COOPAIN. This enabled us to gather information on

the amount of export of quinoa and the corresponding price for every described multi-stage

actor, which is summarized in table 5.3. The decrease in the export price is clearly visible in

2015 and 2016, indicating the current ’quinoa crisis’ that is going on in Peru. Although the

export volume held on to its normal level, or even increased little in 2015, most companies’

export volume decreased in 2016, not as much relatively to the price but it is clear that this is

due to the increase of production facilities in Peru as well as the start-up of plantations overseas.

Most large companies like Alisur, Vinculos Agricolas and De Guste were able to keep a large

production, mainly thanks to also starting production facilities in the lowlands in the north of

Peru, where yields are also much higher.

Table 5.3: The Net Export Volume (kg) and Price per kg ($/kg) for five exporters of quinoa in

Peru.

Year 2014 2015 2016

Net Export

Volume (kg)

Price

($/kg)

Net Export

Volume (kg)

Price

($/kg)

Net Export

Volume (kg)

Price

($/kg)

Alisur 3 914 257 4,78 5 232 233 2,86 5 636 799 2,15

Avendaño 607 257 5,28 1 046 725 3,66 470 590 2,80

COOPAIN 179 228 5,99 184 357 4,89 158 190 3,35

De Guste 1 197 861 6,33 730 469 5,25 668 699 3,32

Vinculos 3 702 150 5,66 6 106 108 3,76 4 565 172 2,63

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 69

5.3.1 COOPAIN

An example of a multi-stage actor given by (Hatch et al., 2015) is the COOPAIN (Cooperativa

Agroindustrial Cabana Ltda). COOPAIN is located in Puno and has very close relationships

with small farmers in the region of Puno. Its network consists of more than 500 members who

grow an average of 1.7 ha of quinoa with an average yield of 3.5 ton/year. The producers sell

72% of their production to COOPAIN, use 25% for self-consumption and 3% is used as seed

the next year. 60% of what COOPAIN buys from producers is destined for direct exports, 30%

goes to companies in Lima for further processing and only 10% stays in the Cusco region or

goes to restaurants. We can state that COOPAIN mainly covers the processing phases as well as

the exporting phase. Thereby, it offers training, technical assistance and equipment to primary

producers. Important note with respect to exporting is that the cooperative possesses several

certifications that allow to export organic and Fair Trade quinoa to the United States, France,

Germany and the Netherlands. COOPAIN can be regarded as a small company, but compared to

other companies, the impact of the drop in prices is only slightly reflected in its export volume.

5.3.2 Vinculos Agricolas

As part of a larger company, Gandules, initially a pepper producer located in the north of Peru

which now collects and processes all kinds of crops, Vinculos Agricolas was able to get some

piece of land from Gandules to cultivate quinoa in the lowlands back in 2013. Vinculos Agri-

colas has also built a network with farmers but different from COOPAIN, Vinculos has con-

tracts with large landowners (thanks to the good relationships of Gandules with the landown-

ers). These landowners most likely have around 1 000 acres at their disposal and divide it in

many small lots of 20 acres that the small farmers can use to cultivate whatever they want.

Vinculos has contracts with these landowners to buy quinoa, which some of the small farmers

cultivate, from them. Vinculos currently has 1 500 ha of land available for the production of

quinoa in the north of Peru (Vinculos Agricolas, nd). Together with well-developed equipment,

a plant that is equipped with technology and a good-working relationship with landowners and

associations of small farmers, organic and conventional quinoa is made according to the high-

est global quality standards (Vinculos Agricolas is a BRC-certified plant). After processing, the

quinoa is then stored in its warehouse in Chiclayo, more than 700km away from Lima. Since

prices of quinoa were very high in 2013, the fact that it needed to be transported to Lima for

distribution afterwards did not pose any limits to the benefits of the company. When prices

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 70

started to decrease 2 years ago, the logistic and transportation costs were getting too high to be

able to still be profitable. By consequence, Vinculos is looking to move their plant to Lima in

order to reduce logistic and transportation costs and regain benefits, despite the lower price of

quinoa. After the quinoa is transported to Lima, it is exported to the domestic market or the

foreign market. In case of export to the foreign market, it ends up at intermediaries. These are

the ones who actually have the strongest impact on the price and therefore capture a significant

proportion of benefits away. From these intermediaries, it is then sold to wholesalers such as

Costco and retailers such as Lidl. Vinculos was het largest exporter of quinoa in 2015, but due to

the ’crisis’, it lost a significant part of its share to Alisur. However, Vinculos remained the second

largest exporter of quinoa in 2016.

5.3.3 De Guste Group SAC

De Guste Group acts as a processor and exporter located in Juliaca, a city in the region of Puno.

The quinoa is collected from the farmers in the highlands in Puno and brought to the city of Ju-

liaca to be processed. Being the owner of their own land and plant enables De Guste to manage

every element of their supply chain from seeding through harvesting, storage and processing

until the export (De Guste Group, nd). Each step in the process is said to be under strict control

to assure the quality standards for exporting to foreign markets. Compared to 2014, De Guste

had to deal with a decline of almost 50% in the export volume, despite staying one of the com-

panies with the highest selling price per kg, as can be seen in table 5.3. This illustrates the high

quality grain they provide, although it was at the expense of its export volume.

5.3.4 Avendaño Trading Company SAC

Avendaño Trading Company is another company that covers the processing and exporting stages.

By having plants both in Puno and Lima, it is well-suited to fulfil these activities cost-effectively.

Different from the above mentioned companies, Avendaño is said to be exporting mostly to

Southern American countries. This can be declared by the fact that Avendaño is still a young

and dynamic company and it might be difficult to already get all the certifications for exporting

towards the United States or Europe. 2015 was a very good year for Avendaño, which saw their

export almost double, but the general bad trend in the export of quinoa was also translated in

their figures in 2016.

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 71

5.3.5 Alisur SAC

Alisur is also a company whose main activities are the production and processing of vegetables

and grains for domestic and international markets (Alisur, nd). Indicated by itself, Alisur acts

as growers, wholesalers, distributors, importers and exporters in the value chain. To be able to

perform all these activities, Alisur has four facilities spread over the country: One in the north,

one in Lima, one in Ayacucho and one in Cusco. The proximity of the plants to the fields of

production allows Alisur to significantly reduce transportation and logistic costs. Their mission

is to become the most important exporter of quinoa, which they achieved in 2016. They get

a low price for the large volumes they export, especially with the recent drop of the price, as

indicated in table 5.3. When they are able to come up with some innovations and keep up the

current excellent work, they will continue to remain the largest and most important exporter of

quinoa in the future.

5.3.6 The Government

Although the government plays an important role for some organizations because it enables

them to get a significant amount of financing and more bargaining power towards other links in

the value chain, most processors and exporters have a direct connection with large landowners

and small farmers. Therefore, the government does not play any direct role in our case study.

Since the government influences actors by means of indirect actions, rules and regulations, it

can be classified under the indirect actors in the value chain of quinoa.

5.3.7 Solid International - Solid Food Peru/Europe

Solid International is a development organization created in 2000, with the purpose of transfer-

ring business knowledge and know-how to underprivileged people worldwide in order to help

improve their living conditions in a sustainable way (Solid Food, nd). They state that they make

use of a hybrid model where profits from commercial activities are used to finance local non-

profit and social projects. The objective is to achieve long-term financial autonomy, which is

why Solid has started multiple small- and large-scale projects. In 2004, Solid decided to focus

its efforts on Ayacucho, one of the poorest regions in Peru. In 2006, Solid Food Peru was estab-

lished there to accommodate the various local organizations, one of which became Solid Food

Peru. In collaboration with Solid Food Europe, Solid Food Peru sells organic Peruvian quinoa

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 72

on the European market under brand names from retailers, but also under their own label. With

the proceeds from this, Solid Food Peru provides training on agricultural and commercial issues

to many farmers and their families while at the same time, new investments can be made.

Solid Peru and Solid Europe can together be regarded as a multi-stage actor as well. On the one

hand, Solid Peru acts in Peru and performs multi-stage activities from interacting with farmers

to processing and export to foreign markets. Therefore, it is included as processors/exporters

in the producing country in figure 5.3. Solid Europe on the other hand, is responsible for all the

activities related to sales, i.e. it actually acts as a trader like DO-IT, except from the fact that it

buys from Solid Food Peru and not from other exporters in Peru. Solid Food Europe is depicted

on figure 5.3 as intermediary in the consuming country and their collaboration with Solid Food

Peru is shown by means of the double arrow that connects both. Solid Food Europe then im-

ports the quinoa into Europe and sells it in bulk or packaged to traders, catering- and food ser-

vices, wholesalers and retailers (e.g. Bio-Planet, Colruyt, Delhaize etc.). As mentioned before,

the overall goal of Solid is to help the population who is living in poor conditions in Ayacucho

(Peru). In this regard, it wants to have an impact on a socio-economic level and make sure the

local population can rely on their own income. The dark blue arrow on figure 5.3 illustrates the

impact Solid wants to have on local farmers. By providing assistance and guiding them in their

production process, Solid wants to help the local population as well as boost the production of

quinoa in that specific region. In this respect, it has close contacts and collaborates with small

local farmers and processors in the region of Ayacucho. One fourth of the profits generated by

Solid are used to build social projects for the population. Until last year, Solid bought quinoa

from the farmers to sell it to processors in Peru like Vinculos Agricolas and De Guste. How-

ever, Solid discovered it would benefit themselves and farmers more if they could immediately

export to Europe and sell to wholesalers and retailers there. This allows them to skip a stage

in the value chain and provide quinoa to wholesalers and retailers in Belgium/Europe at more

affordable prices while at the same time also generating more profits for the farmers and them-

selves. (Solid Food, nd) describes its own operations as follows: "Through a reliable and sound

local organization from the fields in Peru to the supermarkets in Europe, Solid is able to install

a durable, intensive and long-term collaboration with the small farmers.". We can conclude

that Solid thrives on their vertical integration, durable trade and traceability that allow them to

execute their activities in the best possible way (Solid Food, nd).

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 73

5.4 Indirect Actors

Indirect actors can be of different kinds, depending on the stage in the value chain they sup-

ply and the kind of service/product they provide. Those regarded as suppliers of inputs for

the production stage are the ones that deliver seeds, fertilizers, technical assistance and train-

ing, machinery for sowing and harvesting, climate information, financing for expanding their

production etc. Supplies for the processing and exporting phase mainly involve research and

technology, certification provisions and proposals, equipment and machinery for the different

processing steps, financing for extending the market potential and the facilities used for pro-

cessing. Another indirect actor already mentioned in a previous section is the government.

They all influence the value chain and its actors in an indirect manner by offering one or more

services throughout the whole chain. Since the list of such organizations is very long, they are

not included in our case study, nor in the value chain depicted in figure 5.3.

CHAPTER 5. CHARACTERISTICS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 74

Provision of Inputs

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•P

rovi

din

g se

ed

s,

equ

ipm

ent,

fac

iliti

es,

info

rmat

ion

, tr

ain

ing,

te

chn

ical

ass

ista

nce

, te

chn

olo

gy

•C

on

stra

ints

• L

ack

of

lan

d p

rovi

der

s

•To

o e

xpen

sive

lan

d

ren

t

•U

nav

aila

bili

ty o

f se

ed

s/fe

rtili

zers

•La

ck o

f eq

uip

men

t an

d

faci

litie

s

•N

o r

esea

rch

, tra

inin

g an

d t

ech

nic

al

assi

stan

ce

Primary Producers

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•So

win

g, f

erti

lizat

ion

, p

hyt

osa

nit

ary

wo

rk,

har

vest

•C

on

stra

ints

:

•Sh

ort

age

of

lan

d u

se

(lo

ts t

oo

exp

ensi

ve t

o

bu

y/re

nt)

•La

ck o

f tr

ain

ing,

te

chn

ical

ass

ista

nce

, in

form

atio

n e

xch

ange

, re

sear

ch a

nd

in

no

vati

on

•La

ck o

f st

ora

ge a

nd

eq

uip

men

t

•La

ck o

f q

ual

ity

cert

ific

atio

ns

•Tr

ansp

ort

atio

n

•In

abili

ty t

o s

ell a

t fa

ir

pri

ces

•U

nav

ailib

ility

of

see

ds

•P

est

or

dis

ease

s; b

ad

fert

iliza

tio

n

•M

argi

n:

5-1

5%

Processors

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•C

lean

ing,

dry

ing,

th

resh

ing,

sel

ecti

on

, st

ora

ge

•C

on

stra

ints

:

•P

rice

an

d in

form

atio

n

asym

met

ries

•In

fras

tru

ctu

re

pro

ble

ms

•La

ck o

f st

ora

ge

faci

litie

s an

d

equ

ipm

ent

•La

ck o

f q

ual

ity

cert

ific

atio

ns

•Li

mit

ed t

ech

nic

al

assi

stan

ce a

nd

tra

inin

g

•In

effi

cien

cies

in

linka

ges

wit

h f

arm

ers

or

exp

ort

ers

•Li

mit

ed c

apit

al a

nd

te

chn

olo

gy

•M

argi

n:

see

exp

ort

ers

Exporters

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•St

ora

ge,

selli

ng

to

do

mes

tic

or

inte

rnat

ion

al m

arke

t

•C

on

stra

ints

:

•C

fr. c

on

stra

ints

fo

r p

roce

sso

rs

•La

ck o

f d

iver

sifi

cati

on

m

arke

ts f

or

exp

ort

•Tr

ansp

ort

atio

n

dif

ficu

ltie

s

•Ex

po

rt c

erti

fica

tio

ns

•Im

plic

atio

ns

by

the

gove

rnm

ent

•Li

mit

atio

ns

in

imp

ort

ing

cou

ntr

ies

•M

argi

n:

20-3

0%

Intermediaries

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•Im

po

rtin

g, d

istr

ibu

tin

g

•C

on

stra

ints

:

•A

bse

nce

/sh

ort

age

of

a m

arke

t

•Tr

ansp

ort

atio

n

dif

ficu

ltie

s

•La

ck o

f ca

pit

al

•La

ck o

f co

mp

etit

ion

/to

o m

uch

co

mp

etit

ion

•P

rice

an

d in

form

atio

n

asym

met

ries

•La

ck o

f q

ual

ity

cert

ific

atio

ns,

lice

nse

s

•In

com

ple

te

dis

trib

uti

on

sys

tem

s

•La

ck o

f st

ora

ge s

pac

e o

r in

suff

icie

nt

faci

litie

s

•Ta

xes

and

oth

er f

ees

•M

argi

n:

20-3

5%

Wholesalers/Retailers

•A

ctiv

itie

s

•Se

llin

g to

fin

al

con

sum

ers

•C

on

stra

ints

:

•C

fr. c

on

stra

ints

fo

r in

term

edia

ries

•R

etai

lers

dif

ficu

lt t

o

reac

h

•U

nav

aila

bili

ty o

f w

ork

ing

cap

ital

•M

argi

n:

30

-40

%

Pro

visi

on

of

Inp

uts

P

rim

ary

Pro

du

cers

P

roce

sso

rs

Exp

ort

ers

Inte

rmed

iari

es

Wh

ole

sale

rs/R

etai

lers

Fi

nal

Co

nsu

mp

tio

n

*No

te: T

he

con

sum

ing

cou

ntr

y ca

n b

e th

e sa

me

as t

he

pro

du

cin

g co

un

try

CO

OP

AIN

Vin

culo

s A

gric

ola

s

De

Gu

ste

Gro

up

SA

C

Ave

nd

año

Tra

din

g C

om

pan

y SA

C

Alis

ur

SAC

Solid

Fo

od

Per

u

E.g.

Bio

-Pla

net

,

Del

hai

ze, L

idl,

Oxf

am, A

ldi

E.g.

DO

-IT,

Mar

kal,

Solid

Fo

od

Eu

rop

e

Pri

mar

y P

rod

uct

ion

Sto

rage

an

d B

asic

Pro

cess

ing

Ind

ust

rial

izat

ion

M

arke

tin

g

Fig

ure

5.3:

Th

eva

lue

chai

no

fqu

ino

aas

con

sid

ered

ino

ur

case

stu

dy.

Chapter 6

Analysis of the Value Chain of Quinoa

6.1 Assessing the Value

6.1.1 Introduction

Since we did not have enough respondents to be able to fully assess the influence of each actor

in the value chain on the other actors, a qualitative assessment of the different stages was made

based on the activities performed and the corresponding constraints present in each stage. In

addition, a quantitative analysis of the different prices per stage was made to determine the

relationships and the power of the actors relative to each other in monetary terms based on the

marketing margin and the percentage of the total value created. As mentioned before, this is

mainly an estimation because it is based on averages and approximations.

6.1.2 Qualitative Analysis

Based on the activities performed by each stage and the constraints related to executing these

activities, a qualitative analysis can be carried out. This is similar to a SWOT-analysis where all

the strengths, weaknesses, opportunities and threats of the whole value chain are described.

The opportunities and threats for the future are also discussed later in section 6.2 ’Upgrading

the Value Chain of Quinoa’ as challenges and future possibilities. The main activities and con-

straints present in every step of the value chain are described in the bottom half of figure 5.3

and constitute the foundation and most important elements of the analysis.

75

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 76

Strengths and Opportunities

Before addressing its weaknesses and threats, the strengths and opportunities of the quinoa

value chain are quickly mentioned:

1. Strengths related to the primary producers encompass the following:

(a) Obviously, the most prevalent strengths of the first stages of the value chain of quinoa

are, as described by (Hatch et al., 2015), its nutritional value and its suitability to dif-

ferent types of (even more or less infertile) soils and climates for harvest. On the

one hand, this is very advantageous for people from all parts of the world because in

principle, everybody can grow quinoa, no matter where and no matter in which cli-

mate they live. However, the yield will differ. On the other hand, this may cause the

producers, processors and exporters in Peru to lose their markets abroad and hav-

ing to cope with overproduction. The fact that they are momentarily even expanding

their plantations and production facilities confirms that they believe that quinoa ex-

port to foreign countries will continue to grow. The negative effect of losing markets

and overproduction, if it ever occurs, may then be even bigger.

(b) Quinoa’s multidimensionality (nutritional as well as medicinal and cosmetic pur-

pose), genetic variety and organic or ecological production are factors that boosted

the consumer perception over the years (Hatch et al., 2015).

(c) Furthermore, production costs for farmers are said to be around 50% of the average

national farm price, which is assumed to be quite low relative to other products’

production costs. This means that farmers can retain the other 50% as pure profits

for food and other basic needs.

According to (Hatch et al., 2015), these comprise the most important strengths of the pro-

ductive chain.

2. When considering the organizations that act as processors and exporters, we can state

that the remuneration these companies get is more or less pro rata their efforts to the

contribution of the created value of the final quinoa product. In this respect, exporters

can use their knowledge of the international market to adapt margins between the na-

tional and international prices in their own favour. According to (Fallis, 2013), this is the

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 77

link in the value chain with the most possibilities and resources for adaptations and en-

hancements.

3. Finally, the intermediaries can be seen as the most powerful link in the value chain. As im-

porters, they have an enormous impact on the final consumption price of quinoa. Since

there are only a few companies importing and providing quinoa in the destination coun-

tries, they exercise an oligopoly and are able to ask very high prices.

When looking, as outsiders, at the linkages in the value chain, the value chain looks like a

smooth flow of products and services downstream and remunerations upstream. However, this

is not always the case. Therefore, the weaknesses and threats present in the value chain, as

opposed to the strengths and opportunities, are discussed below.

Weaknesses and Threats

There are a lot of weaknesses and deficiencies present in the current chain that badly influence

either the productivity and efficiency of the actors or the value that is delivered to the cus-

tomers. In general, deficiencies can be with regard to the price settings of the different actors,

the way actors fulfil their role, the structure of the value chain and the different activities and

operations performed in the value chain (i.e. harvesting, processing, export, distribution). The

main weaknesses present in the producer’s stage of the value chain are outlined below:

1. When investigating the producers, it is immediately clear that they may have to deal with

a lack of quality seeds to cultivate high quality crops that are conform the high export

standards. The lack of quality standards and certifications with respect to the seeds il-

lustrates that there is a shortage of bonding between actors of the same stage. Lonely

farmers are not able to arrange higher standards and certifications because they simply

do not have the power to do so. Grouping together would enable the organizations to

negotiate better quality standards and more certifications which would eliminate the low

yield production currently present in most of the regions of Peru.

2. To be able to increase quality and reach the standards and certifications, producers of

course need to be supported by a sufficient amount of technology and knowledge. How-

ever, most of the producers do not have the technology and the knowledge available to

boost their cultivation process.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 78

3. Another factor that thrives the deficiency in the chain is the fact that it rains quite often in

the highlands of Peru, fields are sometimes overrun with water and no irrigation systems

are present. An irrigation system that drains the redundant amount of water would be

very helpful. The large amounts of rain and sometimes very rough weather conditions

in the highlands cause the farmers to have a very low yield, obviously depending on how

generous the weathering was during the harvesting season.

4. On top of this, a lot of farmers do not legally possess or use land on which they are allowed

to cultivate quinoa. A cooperation with other farmers would bolster each farmer’s own

development and that of the industry, but until now, most farmers are not confident that

it will really benefit them.

5. Moreover, there is a lack of training and technical assistance which serves as guidance

for the producers and processors towards more efficient and effective production and

processing.

Taking the drawbacks into account, as described before, it is a very good thing for farmers to

unite in organizations such that their bargaining power increases towards other linkages in the

value chain. The farmers would be able to stimulate and help each other to set and reach higher

goals. Thereby, the government is willing to support such cooperation in order to promote and

brisk up the quinoa industry. However, the encouragement of the government and other orga-

nizations to cooperate and associate did not manage to convince the farmers and the ones that

already exist show only little commitment.

The lack of quality, certifications, technology, knowledge, training and technical assistance is

said to be due to the inability to generate finances, which is an indirect consequence of the un-

favourable socio-economic conditions producers still have to cope with on the one hand and

the heterogeneity of the actors in the value chain on the other hand. We would like to refer to ap-

pendix F for a broad description of the socio-economic circumstances of Peru relative to Bolivia

and Belgium. Although Peru’s socio-economic conditions have evolved positively over time,

there still are some misconceptions and limitations in the quinoa industry and value chain.

Furthermore, the heterogeneity of producers is portrayed by their different levels of resources,

access to markets, technological development, infrastructure etc. relative to each other. This

clearly influences the competitiveness and the power the producers are able to generate. Obvi-

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 79

ously, it is related to the limited amount of time and money that is invested in research, devel-

opment and innovation. Again, these are aspects that could and can be achieved more easily

when producers and processors are associated and in a close relationship with each other. The

availability of much more resources thanks to the combination of several actors would raise the

ability to accomplish more investments in respective domains. All the factors described indi-

cate that most primary producers still have to cope with primitiveness with regard to technical

assistance, training, facilities, equipment, research, technology and knowledge on the one hand

and that they are reluctant towards cooperation and association on the other hand. This causes

farmers to remain in their existing position, given the fact that quinoa is actually a complemen-

tary product of their income (Fallis, 2013). They constitute that link in the chain that undergoes

the power and the will of other stage actors of the value chain: The bargaining power of the

primary producers is very small relatively to the other stages.

In addition to the limited bargaining power of the producers, price and information exchange

between actors and stages largely differs from region to region and from actor to actor. In-

sufficient technology, large distance between actors, bad infrastructure and poverty all restrict

actors to communicate with each other in an efficient manner. This can cause actors to lack

necessary information regarding their production and prices of quinoa. As a result, the insecu-

rity and negative unexpected circumstances come into play in this case. Predetermined prices

or quantities may differ at the moment of trade due to the above mentioned factors, leading

to dissatisfaction among the involved actors. Also, this may lead to exploitation of actors who

do not possess the technology, who are located in remote areas, who do not have sufficient

communication services etc. Often, large landowners, organizations that cover the processing

and exporting stage, and especially intermediaries in foreign countries are regarded as those

being able to exploit such a situation. They generally possess the necessary technology, have

the resources available for further development, are situated in metropolitan centres etc. Those

are all factors that contribute to their strong position in the value chain, at the expense of the

weakest link in the chain, namely the producers. We can state that the price and information

asymmetries between different stage actors in the value chain (cfr. described as constraints in

earlier sections) make the relationships in the value chain more fragile and difficult to maintain.

Concerning the subdivision of the consumer price, our investigation learned that exporters and

importers are the ones who increase the prices the most significantly and therefore reap the

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 80

largest share of the total consumer price away compared to producers who only get a small

share of the final consumer price. This is further illustrated in section 6.1.3 ’Quantitative Anal-

ysis’.

We can conclude from the above that there are two very important weaknesses in the value

chain: The low bargaining power of the farmers on the one hand, which is related to the lack of

association between producers and the lack of financing opportunities present, and the large

share of the price that is taken away by the intermediaries in foreign countries relative to the

proportion of work and added value they put into the value chain of quinoa. Although it is

difficult to really assess the value and the relationships between the stage actors in monetary

terms, we tried to do so in the section below.

6.1.3 Quantitative Analysis

To be able to conduct a quantitative analysis that allows us to assess the impact the actors of

each stage have based on the share from the total consumer price the actor receives, we firstly

collected the prices of each stage and calculated the margins every stage was able to generate

over the years as well as the share of the total each stage receives. By considering the prices of

the different stages relative to each other, each actor’s function and impact in the whole value

chain can be distinguished more easily.

An important measure that we used for quantitatively assessing the impact is the marketing

margin, also called farm-retail price by (Agriculture and Consumer Protection, nd). A market-

ing margin as used in our case study can be defined as the difference between the buying cost

and the selling price in each stage, which is the actual gross marketing margin. Marketing costs

are not taken into account because we were not able to obtain these from different stage actors.

The gross marketing margin is equivalent to the difference between the selling price of stage y

and the selling price of stage y-1 because the selling price of the previous stage is the same as the

buying cost of the current stage. The gross marketing margin for the farmers for example is the

difference between the price at which they can sell the quinoa to the processors and the price

they have to pay for seeds, rent of equipment and land etc., relative to the final consumption

price. (Agriculture and Consumer Protection, nd) state that the longer the chain gets, the higher

the marketing costs will be and the lower the net marketing margin for each stage. Calculating

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 81

the gross marketing margin for each stage will show the added value in terms of money, which

is actually a misrepresentation of the real value that is added but a good representation of the

unfairness present in the value chain due to the large margins taken by later-stage actors.

We obtained the farm prices, Peruvian consumer prices and export prices from an aggregation

of data from (Fallis, 2013), (Vinculos Agricolas, nd) and (Hatch et al., 2015) and the intermedi-

ary and European consumer prices from (Bio-Planet, nd) for the period 2007-2016. A list of the

prices is given in table 6.1. We can immediately observe from table 6.1 that the farm price has

always remained very low relatively to the consumer and export price. We assumed that pro-

cessing and exporting are performed by one and the same company. Therefore, both stages are

considered together and have one selling price, which is the export price. The corresponding

gross marketing margins are calculated based on this export price. As mentioned in the respec-

tive sections, price estimations were made for the intermediary price before 2009 and for the

European consumer price before 2013. Furthermore, since we were not able to get the specific

marketing costs of the farmers, we assumed the costs for the farmers to be 50% on average, as

mentioned before. The expectations about the margins are that when the quinoa is exported

to foreign countries, later stage actors like intermediaries and wholesalers/retailers will be the

ones with the highest margins. An appropriate and fair compensation for every stage actor

would be something around 20% when the chain consists of 5 stages. Note that everything is

expressed in $/kg because this is the standard used by Peruvian companies. Besides this, we

also have to take into account that the discussed data is based on averages and estimations.

Therefore, the margins are approximations used to illustrate the current relationships in the

value chain and get a global view of the bottlenecks in the chain. We can define the formula for

the margin and its parameters as follows:

GM My = (Py −Py−1)/Pc

GM My Gross Marketing Margin stage y ($/kg)

Py Price stage y ($/kg)

Py−1 Price stage y-1 ($/kg)

Pc Final Consumer Price ($/kg)

This formula and the prices in table 6.1 allow to calculate the gross marketing margins, which

are given in table 6.2. Figure 6.1 depicts the margins for the different stages but only considers

the data from 2013 until 2016 because this is the most representative for the current relation-

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 82

ships. Table 6.2 and figure 6.1 clearly show that the farmers get the smallest percentage of the

total consumer price. The margin for the farmers over the past years lies between 5% and 15%

in the worst case scenario and the best case scenario respectively. We can see that their margin

was higher when the production of quinoa was really booming on foreign markets, i.e. from

2011-2014. The sharp drop in the farm and export prices in 2015 resulted in very small margins

for the farmers, causing those who are really dependent on quinoa to get into a precarious sit-

uation. This is conform our expectations. In addition, processors and exporters seem to have a

remuneration pro rata their added value to the product. Their margin ranges between 20% and

30% with some outliers like the 10% in 2016. This outlier shows the loss of a significant amount

of profits to the intermediaries in 2016, which is mainly due to the steep drop of the export price

during that year. The main cause of the decline of those prices in 2016 is the overproduction

and the fact that a lot of projects to cultivate quinoa are starting up in foreign countries, which

leads to consumers in foreign countries preferring to buy the local ’cheaper’ quinoa above the

imported ’more expensive’ organic or Fair Trade quinoa from Peru. It causes Peru to lose mar-

kets and forces it to lower its prices which in turn results in the loss of income for exporters,

processors and farmers. This can also be regarded as one of the biggest threats for the future of

the quinoa industry in Peru.

The largest part seems to be taken away by wholesalers and retailers, although intermediaries’

percentage is again increasing in the last couple of years, approaching the percentage of the

wholesalers and retailers. The margin for the intermediaries generally lies between 20% and

30% but increased to above 30% in 2015 and 2016. This indicates the large proportion interme-

diaries are realizing on the final price. Table 6.2 displays the range of the wholesalers/retailers,

which is even larger than that of the intermediaries and amounts to 30% to 40% and even 43%

in 2016. When looking at the Peruvian consumer price and comparing it with the export price,

we can observe that both prices fluctuate around each other. Most of the time, the average

Peruvian consumer price was the highest. Given the fact that the export price may be a refer-

ence for companies to set their price and the fact that the export price may also refer to export

to other regions in Peru, it is obvious that the Peruvian consumer price is slightly higher than

the export price. However, especially in 2013, the export price was higher than the Peruvian

consumer price, mainly due to the enormous demand from foreign markets which caused the

export price to increase. This led to Peruvians being encouraged to export and use their income

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 83

to buy other, less nutritional products.

An important take-away from this short quantitative analysis is the fact that intermediaries and

wholesalers/retailers benefit most from the sale of quinoa, although adding the least value to

the final product. Important to note is also the increase in their margins for 2015 and 2016. The

intermediary and European consumer prices seem to remain relatively stable compared to the

enormous decrease in export and farm prices. This allows the later stages in the chain to derive

more profits at the expense of farmers and hence also have a higher margin. When we add up

the margins of the intermediaries and wholesalers/retailers, their combined margin amounts

to more or less 80% of the final consumer price, which is a ridiculous number when taking the

amount of work the farmers and processors put into the realization of the product into account.

Table 6.1: The price for producers (Farm Price), for Peruvian consumers, for export, for interme-

diaries and for European consumers in $/kg for the period 2007-2016. Based on an aggregation

of data from (Vinculos Agricolas, nd), (Fallis, 2013), (Hatch et al., 2015) and (Bio-Planet, nd).

Year

Average national

farm price

($/kg)

Peruvian

consumer price

($/kg)

Export price

($/kg)

Intermediary

price ($/kg)

European

consumer price

($/kg)

2007 0,39 1,31 1,31 3,20 5,12

2008 0,55 2,24 2,45 3,85 5,62

2009 1,12 3,23 2,69 4,00 6,16

2010 1,19 3,36 2,76 4,56 6,70

2011 1,33 3,42 3,17 4,44 6,65

2012 1,47 3,57 2,91 4,50 7,05

2013 2,33 4,18 4,26 5,00 8,08

2014 2,81 6,62 5,38 8,08 12,38

2015 1,21 5,54 3,84 8,02 12,84

2016 1,17 3,92 2,34 6,56 11,60

Note: The figures are partly based on estimations and prices are converted from Peruvian

Soles to US Dollars such that deviations may occur.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 84

Table 6.2: Margins for farmers, processors/exporters, intermediaries and wholesalers/retailers

in % for the period 2007-2016.

Year

Gross Marketing

Margin farmers

(%)

Gross Marketing

Margin processors/

exporters (%)

Gross Marketing

Margin

intermediaries (%)

Gross Marketing

Margin wholesalers/

retailers (%)

2007 3,81 17,97 36,91 37,50

2008 4,89 33,81 24,91 31,49

2009 9,09 25,49 21,27 35,06

2010 8,88 23,43 26,87 31,94

2011 10,00 27,67 19,10 33,23

2012 10,43 20,43 22,55 36,17

2013 14,42 23,89 9,16 38,12

2014 11,35 20,76 21,81 34,73

2015 4,71 20,48 32,55 37,54

2016 5,04 10,09 36,38 43,45

Figure 6.1: Gross Marketing Margins (in %) for the different stages in the value chain for the

period 2013-2016.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 85

6.2 Upgrading the Value Chain of Quinoa

6.2.1 Introduction

Since more and more projects for cultivating quinoa are starting up in importing countries (Eu-

rope, USA, Canada), the external demand (from outside Peru) is diminishing. This leads to an

overproduction which in turn leads to a decrease in the price which negatively influences the

whole value chain but mainly the farmers, since their share of the final consumption price is

then even lower. Anyway, people are convinced that quinoa will again live up to its full potential

in the coming years as demand will continue to grow, maybe having new regions to export to.

Prices are expected to remain quite low, like they are right now. To fulfil this growing expected

demand, the current cultivation and production methods of quinoa and thus the productivity

(yield per hectare) will need to be revamped. When they will be able to upgrade and improve

the installed processes, small farmers will also get to experience the benefits of more efficient

processes and their margins and corresponding profits will increase. Another possibility for

farmers to increase their profits may lie in the association of the farmers into one larger organi-

zation. The unification of farmers into one large association would guarantee a larger influence

of the stage of the primary producers on the other stages which would see their margins and

thus their profits rise. Therefore, in this section we focus on upgrading the value chain in terms

of an enhanced distribution of the final consumer price to whom it belongs.

6.2.2 Improvement Guidelines

An enumeration of guidelines for improving the current situation of the stages involving pro-

cessors and exporters, based on recommendations by (Salcedo et al., 2013), is outlined below:

1. Support from public institutions and the government is essential for the formation of co-

operatives and associations to become more attractive for local farmers. By providing

assistance, associations can get really involved in the primary production and storage

and basic processing steps in the value chain that are needed before the industrialization

step. This would enhance the position of the small farmers in the value chain.

2. A second option is to introduce programs that focus on productivity and improving the

farmers’ position towards the processors such that they can exert more influence on the

processors and increase their own benefits.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 86

3. Thirdly, programs implemented by the government that can help increasing the domestic

consumption of quinoa should be closely related to certain mechanisms of direct public

purchase from cooperatives and associations. In this regard, several steps in the value

chain are skipped and the length of the marketing part of the chain is reduced.

4. Furthermore, research has to be done on quinoa cultivation projects that are starting up

in other parts of the world. This will allow Peru and Bolivia to have a better image of

the worldwide production such that they can respond by looking for new production ap-

proaches or adopt the (better) techniques present in other countries.

5. Last but not least, further investigation with respect to the value chain and the optimiza-

tion of harvesting and other activities is required to be able to address the institutional

and governmental requirements and the implementation of standards etc. that are nec-

essary for export to Europe and the US.

If actors are able to execute the guidelines effectively and continuously look for innovations to

improve the situation that is prevailing at that moment, the quinoa industry in Peru will be able

to thrive for much more years. In this respect, there are several challenges that are in line with

these guidelines and which the value chain may entail, as described in what follows.

6.2.3 Challenges

If the goal really is to target small farmers and enhance their position in the value chain as well

as reduce the enormous margins of the later-stage actors, specific and convenient standards

and arrangements will be necessary in order to unite the farmers and re-boost the demand for

quinoa. According to our insights derived from investigating the value chain and research done

by (Salcedo et al., 2013), several challenges or possible gateways can be identified:

1. Productivity enhancement and incorporation of innovations in quality and management

of the product. This also involves encouraging actors to make use of technical assistance,

training and technological transfer programs (Salcedo et al., 2013).

2. Higher levels of standardization and uniformity should be admired. This can be done by

ameliorating research systems and allowing the government to settle more certifications.

Very important in this respect is that the value of the product may not decrease.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 87

3. Stimulating farmers to unite in associations in order to induce scale effects of operations

covering the whole value chain of quinoa. By uniting themselves in associations, their

power relatively towards other actors in the chain will increase and will enable them to

generate a larger net margin. (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014) confirms this by

stating that "it is advisable for producers to perform associative activities because it helps

to reduce the number of processors present in the value chain which in turn causes a

decrease in transaction costs and enables access to a greater proportion of the value that

is generated along the chain".

4. Minimizing losses in the basic processing and storage step of the chain by enhancing the

facilities (drying, threshing, saponin removal). If associations of farmers also covered the

storage and processing step, they would be able to exert greater bargaining power in their

relationship with the other links in the value chain (Salcedo et al., 2013). This may result

in significant advantages for small farmers that are part of such an association.

5. Looking for innovations with regard to the use of quinoa in order to be able to increase

supply without the risk of overproduction. This also involves research for entering new

markets and responding appropriately to fulfil new types of market demand.

6. Strengthen the awareness and knowledge of the product on new international markets

besides the ones where export is already directed to by advertising and putting the em-

phasis on nutritional characteristics and ethical and cultural values.

7. Aligning supply and demand with respect to the price by monitoring domestic and inter-

national markets.

8. Reassuring the in recent years declined domestic consumption of quinoa by installing

and maintaining public procedures and social programs (e.g. incorporating quinoa in

catering services of companies, schools, hospitals, municipalities etc.).

9. By promoting quinoa in other southern American countries where it has not yet been

developed or in other new regions that are capable of developing the crop, the demand

for quinoa can be stimulated enormously. For this, cooperation and coordination mech-

anisms will be necessary between Peru and the involved countries of the newly tapped

regions. In this regard, (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014) states that synergies

and associations that enhance this process may be established.

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 88

(Salcedo et al., 2013) state that an implementation of such policies and procedures would cer-

tainly require participation of and interaction between the various actors in the value chain.

Furthermore, a profitable and ethically efficient quinoa production is dependent on consis-

tency over time in order to be of any influence. Lastly, it is important that researchers and

participators of the value chain are aware whether their are deficiencies and weaknesses and

where they are situated in the chain such that they can prevent worse cases and take action to

strengthen the chain when necessary.

6.2.4 Future Possibilities

Since the growth in regional quinoa production in Peru and Bolivia was mainly a consequence

of the growing external demand from Europe, the United States and Canada, the new projects

being developed not only pose a barrier because less quinoa will be exported at lower prices,

they are also an opportunity for current farmers, processors and exporters in Peru to optimize

their processes in order to increase productivity and efficiency. By increasing their productivity

and efficiency by means of seed quality, product management, training, technical assistance

and technology, actors will manage to decrease the costs for producing and processing quinoa,

again leading to higher benefits. According to (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014), the

product has passed its phase of international market penetration and is now in a more mature

stage where demand is mitigated. This could be the perfect moment to try quinoa for different

purposes on different markets. Research that investigates the multiple possible new markets

in depth is necessary in this regard. First of all, quinoa has enormous opportunities with re-

gard to its nutritional value because it can be used for multiple diets and other preparation-

and consumption-related activities. (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014) elaborate that

quinoa can not only be used for nutritional purposes, but also for medicinal, chemical and

pharmaceutical and cosmetic purposes. In the medicinal and pharmaceutical industry, it can

be of significant influence for people suffering from diabetes thanks to a high fiber content and

easily digestible carbohydrates and it can also be of influence for people suffering from dis-

orders due to celiac disease mainly thanks to its high amount of vitamin content, mineral salts

and magnesium (Thompson, 2011) and (Zeballos et al., 2012)(as cited by (Documento conjunto

ALADI - FAO, 2014)). According to (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014), the establish-

ment on international markets and the expansion of the quinoa production caused its multi-

functionality to catch the eye of researchers. It is now a matter of time to expand the research

CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS OF THE VALUE CHAIN OF QUINOA 89

on its multi-functionalities and come up with innovations that will help the quinoa production

and price relive to its full potential. If people are able to do so, a large prospective new market

will come to life. From the moment it will get more integrated in these sectors, the probability

that demand will grow yet again is considerable. Thereby, as mentioned in the previous section

in point 3, uniting in associations can be very beneficial for producers and this will only benefit

the whole value chain. In this regard, (Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO, 2014) adds that "sup-

port policies are required to aid producers’ organizations to have better processing facilities and

equipment. By consequence, their trading conditions would be enhanced with the other stages

in the value chain", allowing them to exert more bargaining power. These support policies are

mainly public policies with norms, strategies and institutional actions such as investments that

are expected and required to exert a significant impact on the quinoa industry by contributing

to its development.

Another possibility for future development includes the strategy that was introduced by Solid

Food and also partly by COOPAIN. As mentioned in section 5.3.7 and 5.3.1, they did a take-over

of multiple activities (i.e. processing and exporting in the producing country and importing

into the consuming country in the case of Solid and the activities performed in the produc-

ing country in the case of COOPAIN) and established close relationships with local farmers in

order to provide them guidance and management for their production (e.g. organic and Fair

Trade). Furthermore, they stimulate farmers to unite in associations, provide technical assis-

tance, training and certifications for producers and they invest in research, knowledge and fu-

ture projects on a regular basis. Investment in research and knowledge, by means of involving

educational institutions etc., is something that they need to keep doing and improve in order to

remain successful and really have an influence on the long-term. By taking over the processing

and exporting steps in the value chain, they act as intermediate station between the farmers

and the wholesalers/retailers in the destination markets. It allowed both companies to increase

their own profits while at the same time increasing the benefits for local farmers, both socially

and economically, with whom they have contracts. This shows that the function that Solid and

COOPAIN fulfil in the value chain really has a twofold impact and should stimulate other people

and companies to follow their footsteps: Improving their own operations while simultaneously

improving those of others who live in uncertain conditions, resulting in more benefits for all the

parties involved.

Chapter 7

Conclusion

First of all, the available literature on the quinoa industry together with our investigation al-

lowed us to observe trends in the prosperity of Peru, its quinoa production and prices and its

ability to depend on quinoa as driving force for their future development. Although the grow-

ing demand on international markets was considered to be the main factor driving the devel-

opment of quinoa production until 2014 according to (Salcedo et al., 2013), the industry had to

cope with noticeable setbacks in price as well as in production. The quinoa price and produc-

tion quantity have witnessed enormous peaks in the last decade, followed by the recent drop in

price and a significant amount of overproduction. The boom of the quinoa industry has been

the basis of the income of most of the farmers in Peru. In this respect, we can say that the recent

’crisis’ caused farmers to lose a large part of their income, both in absolute values and relative

to actors of other stages.

Secondly, our research resulted in the identification of the different stages and corresponding

actors of the value chain of quinoa. When researching the value chain and looking for deficien-

cies and weaknesses, it became clear that primary producers can be seen as the weakest link in

the value chain. The fact that the margins intermediaries in foreign export countries are getting

have increased relatively while the prices have dropped, allows to assert that they are taking the

benefits away from the farmers. Our qualitative analysis further examined this aspect in detail

and came to the conclusion that the two biggest issues the value chain has to cope with include

the low bargaining power of the farmers, related to the lack of association between the farmers

and the lack of financing available, on the one hand and the large share of the price that is taken

away by later-stage actors in the foreign destination markets on the other hand. This has been

91

CHAPTER 7. CONCLUSION 92

confirmed in our illustrative quantitative analysis.

Furthermore, we can declare that the quinoa peak is over now and that prices are expected to

remain quite stable in the coming years. If producers are able to enhance their power in the

value chain by means of organizing in associations and producing for other than only nutri-

tional purposes, we believe that the production will be able to remain stable or can even grow

again. Since it is known that quinoa is a multi-functional product of which the real potential is

still to be discovered, significant research, knowledge, training and assistance on the following

aspects will be fundamental for future success: New nutritional and health aspirations, quinoa

in the medicinal, chemical and pharmaceutical industry, cosmetic properties of quinoa and the

introduction of quinoa in new diets, catering services of schools, hospitals etc. but also the abil-

ity to obtain certifications and quality standards will be key if Peru will want to keep thriving on

the quinoa industry for many more years.

Finally, to be able to carry out research and innovation for further development of the quinoa

industry, support from public policies and international organizations will be necessary. They

should focus on enhancing the bargaining power of small producers by encouraging them to as-

sociate, provide them with sufficient facilities, equipment, technology and other infrastructure

such that they are able to protect themselves against poverty. Otherwise, there is the risk that

the economic prosperity and benefits of high quinoa prices may never reimburse small produc-

ers appropriately. On top of this, they should also aim to stimulate demand by promoting the

multi-functionality of quinoa in other parts of the world. All the above mentioned aspects will

also help to reduce the large margins taken away by later-stage actors and thus result in a more

stable value chain. Based on all our investigations, we are convinced that the quinoa industry

still has a bright future ahead and will continue to be the basis of prosperity for Peru for many

more years.

Bibliography

Agrawal, R. C. and Heady, E. O. (1968). Applications of Game Theory Models in Agriculture.

Agriculture and Consumer Protection (n.d.). Agricultural and food marketing management. Re-

trieved April 20, 2017, from http://www.fao.org/docrep/004/W3240E/W3240E12.htm.

Alisur (n.d.). Alisur. Retrieved April 15, 2017, from http://www.alisur.net/index.php.

Bacon, C. M., Méndez, V. E., and Fox, J. A. (2008). Cultivating sustainable coffee: persistent para-

doxes. Confronting the Coffee Crisis: Fair Trade, Sustainable Livelihoods and Ecosystems in

Mexico and Central America. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pages 337–372.

Barraclough, S. and Utting, P. (1987). Food Security Trends and Prospects in Latin America.

10(August).

Barrientos, S., Gereffi, G., and Rossi, A. (2011). Economic and social upgrading in global pro-

duction networks: A new paradigm for a changing world. International Labour Review,

150(3-4):319–340.

Bio-Planet (n.d.). Bio-Planet.

Bioversity International (2007). Annual Report 2006.

Birbuet, J. C. and Machicado, C. G. (2008). Technologycal Progress in the Quinoa Sector.

(November):1–24.

Bosque, H. (2008). Diagnotico en tierras altas de bolivia, el marco de la temática de la “recu-

peración de suelos y sistemas tradicionales de producción” en tierras comunitarieas de

origen. Viceministerio de Tierras, La Paz.

Buenrostro, E., Stezano, F., Casalet, M., Oliver, R., Abelanda, L., et al. (2011). Evolución y com-

plejidad en el desarrollo de encadenamientos productivos en méxico: los desafíos de la

93

BIBLIOGRAPHY 94

construcción del cluster aeroespacial en querétaro. Technical report, Naciones Unidas

Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL).

CBI - Centre for the Promotion of Imports from developing countries (n.d.). Exporting Quinoa

to Europe. Retrieved April 10, 2017, from https://www.cbi.eu/market-information/

grains-pulses/quinoa-grains/europe/.

Cenagro, T. (2012). Censo Nacional Agropecuario. Boletín02, MINAGRI.

Censos nacionales de población y de vivienda (2008). Sociodemográfico del Perú, Perfil.

Chopra, S. and Meindl, P. (2016). Supply Chain Management: Strategy, Planning and Operation.

Composition, W. and James, L. E. A. (2009). Chapter 1 - Quinoa (Chenopodium quinoa Willd.):

Composition, Chemistry, Nutritional, and Functional Properties, volume 58. Elsevier Inc.,

1 edition.

Daviron, B. and Ponte, S. (2005). The coffee paradox: Global markets, commodity trade and the

elusive promise of development. Zed books.

De Guste Group (n.d.). De guste: The company. Retrieved April 14, 2017, from http:

//deguste.com.pe/en/our-company/about-us/.

Dixit, D. (2014). Agricultural Value Chains and Food Security. Journal of World Trade, 48(5):967–

81.

Documento conjunto ALADI - FAO (2014). Tendencias y Perspectivas del Comercio Internacional

de Quinua. Santiago.

Donovan, J., Franzel, S., Cunha, M., Gyau, A., and Mithöfer, D. (2015). Guides for value chain

development: A comparative review. Journal of Agribusiness in Developing and Emerging

Economies, 5(1):2–23.

Dreibus, T. (2016). Quinoa Rides the ’Superfoods’ Wave. Re-

trieved March 16, 2016, from http://www.wsj.com/articles/

quinoa-rides-the-superfoods-gluten-free-waves-1404926555.

European Commission (n.d.). Market access database. Retrieved April 10, 2017, from http:

//madb.europa.eu/madb/statistical_form.htm.

BIBLIOGRAPHY 95

Fallis, A. (2013). Anális de la Cadena de Valor en el Sector de la Quinua en Perú, volume 53.

Journal of Chemical Information and Modeling.

FAO, I., IMF, O., and UNCTAD, W. (2011). the world bank, the wto, ifpri and the un hltf (2011).

Price Volatility in Food and Agricultural Markets: Policy Responses. Rome, FAO.

Fernandez-Stark, K., Bamber, P., and Gereffi, G. (2012). Upgrading in global value chains: Ad-

dressing the skills challenge in developing countries. Background Paper. Paris: OECD.

Frederick, S. E. (2010). Development and application of a value chain research approach to

understand and evaluate internal and external factors and relationships affecting economic

competitiveness in the textile value chain. North Carolina State University.

Gereffi, G. et al. (1999). A commodity chains framework for analyzing global industries. Institute

of Development Studies, 8(12):1–9.

Gereffi, G. and Fernandez-Stark, K. (2016). Global value chain analysis: a primer.

Gereffi, G., Fernandez-Stark, K., and Psilos, P. (2011). Skills for upgrading: Workforce develop-

ment and global value chains in developing countries. Duke University: Center on Global-

ization, Governance and Competitiveness (Duke CGGC), RTI International.

Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M. (1994). Commodity chains and global capitalism. Number 149.

ABC-CLIO.

Gilbert, C. L. (2008). Value chain analysis and market power in commodity processing with

application to the cocoa and coffee sectors. Commodity market review, 2007:5.

Giuliani, E., Pietrobelli, C., and Rabellotti, R. (2005). Upgrading in global value chains: lessons

from latin american clusters. World development, 33(4):549–573.

Hatch, D. N., M Vila, F., Núñez, M., Vila, F., Risi, J. R., W Pacheco, M., Rojas, W., Pacheco, M.,

Anzola, E., Buainain, A., et al. (2015). El mercado y la producción de quinua en el perú.

Technical report, IICA, Lima (Perú).

Hawkes, C. and Ruel, M. T. (2012). Reshaping Agriculture for Nutrition and Health.

Hernandez, R. A., Martinez-Piva, J. M., and Mulder, N. (2013). Global Value Chains and World

Trade: Prospects and challenges for Latin America, volume 1.

BIBLIOGRAPHY 96

Humphrey, J. and Navas-Alemán, L. (2010). Value chains, donor interventions and poverty re-

duction: A review of donor practice. IDS Research Reports, 2010(63):1–106.

IDEPRO (2012). Vision, mision y valores. Retrieved November 20, 2016 from http://www.

idepro.org/vision.asp.

Jacobsen, S.-E. (2003). The worldwide potential for quinoa (chenopodium quinoa willd.). Food

reviews international, 19(1-2):167–177.

Jacobsen, S. E. (2011). The Situation for Quinoa and Its Production in Southern Bolivia: From

Economic Success to Environmental Disaster. Journal of Agronomy and Crop Science,

197(5):390–399.

Janvry, A. D. and Sadoulet, E. (2000). Rural poverty in Latin America Determinants and exit

paths. 25:389–409.

Kaplinsky, R. and Morris, M. (2002). A Handbook for Value Chain Research. (September).

Kilian, B., Jones, C., Pratt, L., and Villalobos, A. (2006). Is sustainable agriculture a viable strategy

to improve farm income in central america? a case study on coffee. Journal of Business

Research, 59(3):322–330.

Mazur, R., Musoke, H. K., Nakimbugwe, D., and Ugen, M. (2011). Enhancing nutritional value

and marketability of beans through research and strengthening key value-chain. 2020 con-

ference note 1.

McCalla, A. F. (2009). World food prices: Causes and consequences. Canadian Journal of Agri-

cultural Economics/Revue canadienne d’agroeconomie, 57(1):23–34.

Mendoza, R. and Bastiaensen, J. (2003). Fair trade and the coffee crisis in the nicaraguan

segovias. Small Enterprise Development, 14(2):36–46.

Meyer-Stamer, J. and Waltring, F. (2006). Value chain analysis and ‘making markets work for the

poor’(m4p): Poverty reduction through value chain promotion. Eschborn, German Agency

for Technical Cooperation (GTZ).

Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego (2014).

BIBLIOGRAPHY 97

Parker-gibson, N. (2016). Quinoa : Catalyst or Catastrophe ? Commodity of the Quarter.

6505(February).

Ponte, S. and Gibbon, P. (2005). Quality standards, conventions and the governance of global

value chains. Economy and society, 34(1):1–31.

Ruiz, K. B., Biondi, S., Oses, R., Acuna-Rodriguez, I. S., Antognoni, F., Martinez-Mosqueira, E. A.,

Coulibaly, A., Canahua-Murillo, A., Pinto, M., Zurita-Silva, A., Bazile, D., Jacobsen, S., and

Molina-Montenegro, M. A. (2014). Quinoa biodiversity and sustainability for food security

under climate change: A review. Agronomy for Sustainable Development, 34(2):349–359.

Salcedo, S., Furche, C., Ekaterina, K., Rabczuk, P., Jara, B., Fernández, D., and Correa, F. (2013).

International Quinoa Trade. pages 316–329.

Sexton, R. J. et al. (1994). A survey of noncooperative game theory with reference to agricultural

markets: Part 2. potential applications in agriculture. Review of Marketing and Agricultural

Economics, 62(2):183–200.

Solid Food (n.d.). Solid Food. Retrieved March 25, 2017, from http://www.solidfood.eu/.

Spielman, D. J., Ekboir, J., and Davis, K. (2009). Technology in Society The art and science of

innovation systems inquiry : Applications to Sub-Saharan African agriculture. Technology

in Society, 31(4):399–405.

Stiegert, K. W. (2008). Imperfect competition, agriculture and development. Commodity market

review, 2007:35.

Sutton, J. (1991). Sunk costs and market structure: Price competition, advertising, and the evo-

lution of concentration. MIT press.

Talbot, J. M. (1997). Where does your coffee dollar go?: The division of income and surplus along

the coffee commodity chain. Studies in comparative international development, 32(1):56–

91.

Thompson, T. (2011). Case problem: questions regarding the acceptability of buckwheat, ama-

ranth, quinoa, and oats from a patient with celiac disease. Journal of the Academy of Nu-

trition and Dietetics, 101(5):586–587.

BIBLIOGRAPHY 98

Turocy, T. L., Stengel, B. V., and von Stengel, B. (2003). Game Theory. Encyclopedia of Informa-

tion Systems, pages 403 – 420.

Valkila, J. (2009). Fair trade organic coffee production in nicaragua—sustainable development

or a poverty trap? Ecological Economics, 68(12):3018–3025.

Valkila, J., Haaparanta, P., and Niemi, N. (2010). Empowering coffee traders? the coffee value

chain from nicaraguan fair trade farmers to finnish consumers. Journal of Business Ethics,

97(2):257–270.

Vinculos Agricolas (n.d.). Vinculos agricolas. Retrieved April 14, 2017, from http://www.

vinculosagricolas.com/index-eng.html.

Zeballos, V. F., Ellis, H. J., Šuligoj, T., Herencia, L. I., and Ciclitira, P. J. (2012). Variable activation

of immune response by quinoa (chenopodium quinoa willd.) prolamins in celiac disease.

The American journal of clinical nutrition, 96(2):337–344.

Zehner, D. C. (2002). An economic assessment of ‘fair trade’in coffee. Chazen Web Journal of

International Business, 21.

Appendices

99

Appendix A

Worldwide Production and Distribution of

Quinoa

The figure below shows the global distribution of quinoa production for 2013. Bolivia and Peru

are the main producers, followed by Ecuador, USA, and Canada. Chile, Argentina, Colombia,

and Mexico produce mostly for local consumption. The other countries are currently develop-

ing quinoa projects (field trials). Bar plot on the left shows productive varieties developed by

genetic improvement in countries within the original distributional range (FAO et al., 2011)(as

cited by (?)).

Figure A.1: Overview of the worldwide production and distribution of quinoa. Reprinted from

(FAO et al., 2011)(as cited by (Ruiz et al., 2014)).

100

Appendix B

Distribution and Production in Peru

The figures outlined in this section show the distribution of the cultivated surface and the

amount of quinoa production in Peru for the years 2013 and 2014. An increase in both pro-

duction volume and cultivated area can be noticed, especially along the coast and in lowlands.

Figure B.1: Volume of quinoa production in metric tons for Peru in 2013 and 2014. Reprinted

from (Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego, 2014)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)).

101

APPENDIX B. DISTRIBUTION AND PRODUCTION IN PERU 102

Figure B.2: Cultivated surface used for quinoa production in Peru in 2013 and 2014. Reprinted

from (Ministerio de Agricultura y Riego, 2014)(as cited by (Hatch et al., 2015)).

Appendix C

Export of Quinoa from Peru to Europe:

Value and Quantity

Exports of quinoa out of Peru towards Europe only started in 2012. The figure gives an indica-

tion of the value and quantity of quinoa that was imported in Europe since that time. We notice

increases in almost all countries for every year. This data was retrieved from the website of the

European Commission.

103

APPENDIX C. EXPORT OF QUINOA FROM PERU TO EUROPE: VALUE AND QUANTITY 104

Table C.1: The Import Value and Quantity of Quinoa from Peru to Different European Countries

for the period 2012 - 2016. Retrieved from (European Commission, nd).

Appendix D

Example of a Value Chain: The Furniture

Industry

Figure D.1 depicts the value chain of the furniture industry. It starts with the supply of seed

inputs, chemicals, machinery, water and extension services (e.g. Information and knowledge)

for the forestry sector. Logs pass to the sawmill sector to be sawn into smaller pieces. This sector

is very dependent on machinery, which is its primary input. After this step, sawn timber moves

to the furniture manufacturers who are also very dependent on machinery. They obtain other

inputs from adhesives, upholstery and paint industries and also draw on design and branding

skills from the service sector. Depending on which market is served, the furniture then passes

through various intermediary stages until it reaches the final consumer. The final consumers

entrust the furniture for recycling. This simple example is a start to understanding that there

is value created in every step of the value chain. As the product moves through the chain, its

value is enhanced until it reaches the customer. Additionally, intermediary actors such as the

forestry sector, the sawmill sector and the furniture sector may unfold in many more different

value chains (e.g. from the forestry to the mining or pulp and paper sector; from the sawmill

sector to domestic/foreign stockholders or to the building and construction industry).

105

APPENDIX D. EXAMPLE OF A VALUE CHAIN: THE FURNITURE INDUSTRY 106

Figure D.1: The forestry, timber and furniture value chain. Reprinted from (Kaplinsky and Mor-

ris, 2002).

Appendix E

Participation of Nicaragua in Global Value

Chains

(Hernandez et al., 2013) provide an example of the production of apparel in Nicaragua to show

that Latin American countries play a significant and valuable role in the global network. Al-

though a lot of countries are involved in the agricultural sector, companies in Latin American

countries have not only entered global value chains in agriculture, but some are also present

in the aerospace sector and offshore business services (Fernandez-Stark et al., 2012); (Giuliani

et al., 2005); (Buenrostro et al., 2011) (as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)). Furthermore, an

example of a country that plays an important role in the global apparel manufacturing value

chain is Nicaragua. The value chain is depicted on figure E.1, on which we can clearly distin-

guish the following phases: R&D; Design; Purchasing; Production cut-make-trim; Distribution;

Marketing; Services.

Nicaragua is mainly involved in the so-called "low-value cut-make-trim stage of the apparel

value chain" (Hernandez et al., 2013). Although Nicaragua can still be regarded as a regional

supplier, its market share has increased firmly since 2004 and especially in certain segments

in the United States, one of its most important countries for export. According to (Hernandez

et al., 2013), foreign-owned firms are the ones most present in the apparel industry. A lot of

these companies are crucial actors in global value chains. By using and exploiting the close

relationships with the other actors in the value chain, companies in a global network are able to

supply complete deals to customers. Nicaragua’s focus lies on production services for apparel,

which is a difficult segment if you want to upgrade the value chain or want to climb the ladder in

107

APPENDIX E. PARTICIPATION OF NICARAGUA IN GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS 108

Figure E.1: Nicaragua: Curve of value added stages in the global apparel value chain. Reprinted

from (Frederick, 2010)(as cited by (Hernandez et al., 2013)).

a value chain. It is allowed to state that Nicaragua, given its dependency on the United States for

export transactions, is vulnerable with regard to economic upgrading (Hernandez et al., 2013).

Appendix F

The Position of Peru and Bolivia

This part illustrates the position of quinoa-producing countries Peru and Bolivia relatively to

each other and to an average European country: Belgium. The following tables show the de-

gree of development of a country by means of the Human Development Index (HDI) and its

components. The data was provided by (Solid Food, nd).

F.1 Human Development Index: Components and Trends

F.1.1 Definitions

Table F.1 depicts multiple facets that represent the development of countries:

- Human Development Index: A composite index that measures the average achievement in

three basic dimensions of human development: A long and healthy life, knowledge and a de-

cent standard of living.

- Life expectancy at birth: Number of years a newborn infant could expect to live if prevailing

patterns of age-specific mortality rates at the time of birth stay the same throughout the infant’s

life.

- Expected years of schooling: Numbers of years of schooling that a child of school entrance age

can expect to receive if prevailing patterns of age-specific enrollment rates persist throughout

the child’s life.

- Mean years of schooling: Average number of years of education received by people ages 25

and older, converted from education attainment levels using official durations of each level.

- Gross National Income (GNI) per capita: Aggregate income of an economy generated by its

production and its ownership of factors of production, less the incomes paid for the use of fac-

109

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 110

tors of production owned by the rest of the world, converted to international dollars using PPP

(Purchasing Power Parity) rates, divided by midyear population.

F.1.2 Interpretation

From table F.1, we can conclude that Belgium’s life expectancy, education, income and devel-

opment is significantly higher than that of Peru and Bolivia. Peru’s measures are mediocre but

still a lot higher than Bolivia. The life expectancy in Bolivia is 12 years lower than that of Bel-

gium, which is an indication of poor living conditions. The gross national income per capita

also shows huge differences between the countries: Belgium’s GNI is 4 times that of Peru and

8 times that of Bolivia. We can state that Belgium is a country with very high human develop-

ment, Peru is part of the countries with high development mainly due to the development of

multiple international markets in and around the capital Lima in recent years. Countries with

similar rankings are Algeria and Albania. Bolivia is a country with medium human develop-

ment, like Vietnam or Kyrgyzstan. Note that these are figures for 2014. The evolution of the HDI

for different years is depicted in table F.2, as well as the average growth of HDI over time. The

Average Annual HDI Growth is the smoothed annualized growth of the HDI in a given period,

calculated as the annual compound growth rate. It is clear that the HDI for Belgium is signifi-

cantly higher than that of Peru. The difference with Bolivia is even greater. Thereby, the increase

from 1990 to 2000 is the biggest for every country. The increase for Peru and Bolivia is bigger for

the period 2000-2010 compared to a very small increase for Belgium in that period. This indi-

cates the unrealized potential of Peru and Bolivia, while Belgium seems to have reached its full

potential. This is confirmed by the second part of this table. The average annual HDI growth

shows that the increase in Peru and Bolivia, although it isn’t that big as in the period 1990-2000,

is still significantly higher than the one of Belgium for the period 2000-2014.

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 111

F.2 Poverty in Bolivia and Peru

F.2.1 Introduction

When taking a deeper look into Bolivia and Peru, we can state that Bolivia is a lot poorer than

Peru. Table F.3 shows the population below the national poverty line: This is the percentage of

the population living below the national poverty line, which is the line deemed appropriate for

a country by its authorities. National estimates are based on population-weighted subgroup

estimates from household surveys. The second statistic shows the population in severe multi-

dimensional poverty: This is the percentage of the population that is poor regarding multiple

aspects (money, health, electricity, clean water, work, education) adjusted by the intensity of

the deprivations and having a high deprivation score. The changes of these figures in Peru over

the period 2008-2012 are displayed in table F.4. As can be seen from the table, the poverty has

been reduced in Peru in recent years, although there still is a significant amount of the popu-

lation that lives in poor conditions. The data is derived from HDRO calculations based on data

on household deprivations in education, health and living standards from various household

surveys.

F.2.2 Population Trends, Health Outcomes and Education Achievements

The poverty of Peru and especially Bolivia is also illustrated by table F.5, which depicts the pop-

ulation trends, mortality rates and educational achievements (e.g. Literacy rate and secondary

education rate) and table, which shows the national income and its composition of resources

(Gross domestic product (GDP), annual growth of expenditures for the general government and

the consumer price index). Table F.5 has included the following characteristics statistics:

- Total population: De facto population in a country, area or region as of July 1st.

- Population average annual growth: Average annual exponential growth rate for the specified

period.

- Median age: Age that divides the population distribution into two equal parts—that is, 50 per-

cent of the population is above that age and 50 percent is below it.

- Adult mortality rate: Probability that a 15-year-old will die before reaching the age of 60, ex-

pressed per 1,000 people.

- Adult literacy rate: Percentage of the population ages 15 and older who can, with understand-

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 112

ing, both read and write a short simple statement on their everyday life.

Table F.6 involves the following variables:

- Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita: This is the GDP in a particular period divided by

the total population for the same period.

- Gross domestic product (GDP): Sum of gross value added by all resident producers in the econ-

omy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products,

expressed in 2011 international dollars using purchasing power parity (PPP) rates.

- General government consumption expenditure: All government current expenditures for pur-

chases of goods and services (including compensation of employees and most expenditures on

national defence and security but excluding government military expenditures that are part of

government capital formation), expressed as a percentage of GDP.

- Consumer price index: Index that reflects changes in the cost to the average consumer of ac-

quiring a basket of goods and services that may be fixed or changed at specified intervals, such

as yearly.

F.2.3 Interpretation

From the tables, we can conclude that Peru is able to maintain the average annual growth in

the considered periods (2000-2005 and 2010-2015). Its population is also expected to keep in-

creasing. The relative increase of the population is a lot bigger in Peru and Bolivia compared to

Belgium. It is clear that the median age in Belgium is a lot higher than that in Peru and almost

twice as high as that in Bolivia. This is yet another indicator of the poor conditions in which

people of Peru and especially Bolivia have to live. Thereby, the adult mortality rates are higher

in Peru and extremely high in Bolivia. Not mentioned in the table is malnutrition: It does not

occur in Belgium but the numbers in Peru and Bolivia are pretty high: (18,4% and 27,2% respec-

tively). Malaria also causes a lot of deaths in these countries. Obviously, poverty goes together

with the restrictions in terms of education. As we can derive from the table, the literacy rate In

Peru and Bolivia is only slightly more than 90% in 2013. We have to note that the literacy rate

for the youth with ages 15-24 (not included in the table) is significantly higher (98,7% for Peru

and 99,2% for Bolivia), which indicates an improvement for the future.

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 113

F.3 National Income and Composition of Resources

The GDP per capita gives a better representation than the total GDP because it is taken rela-

tively to the population. Belgium has the highest GDP per capita, which is 4 times as big as that

of Peru and 8 times as big as that of Bolivia. This is again an indication of the poverty in Peru and

especially in Bolivia. The annual growth of expenditures assigned for the general government

consumption are a lot higher in Bolivia and Peru than in Belgium but its total is still a lot lower.

Figures that are not included in the table are tax income, credit to domestic customers and ex-

ternal debt stock. The tax incomes generated by the Belgian government are a lot higher than in

Peru and Bolivia. The credit given to various domestic sectors is much higher in Belgium. An-

other remarkable variable is the fact that Belgium doesn’t seem to have any external debt stock,

while Peru and Bolivia have quite a lot. This is the debt owed to non-residents repayable in

foreign currency, goods or services, expressed as a percentage of gross national income (GNI).

The consumer price index for all countries has increased relative to 2010, but remarkably the

cost for the average consumer of acquiring a basket of goods and services in Bolivia and Peru

has increased a lot. This also shows that there are sustainable developments going on in these

countries, which may be a positive sign for the future.

F.4 Employment Rates and Labour Productivity

F.4.1 Definitions

Table F.7 depicts the employment rates in agriculture, in services, the % of vulnerable em-

ployment, the unemployment rate and the labour productivity (output per worker and hours

worked per week). Figures included in the table are:

- Labour force participation rate: Percentage of a country’s working-age population that en-

gages actively in the labour market, either by working or looking for work. It provides an indi-

cation of the relative size of the supply of labour available to engage in the production of goods

and services.

- Employment in agriculture: Share of total employment that is employed in agriculture.

- Employment in services: Share of total employment that is employed in services.

- Vulnerable employment: Percentage of employed people engaged as unpaid family workers

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 114

and own-account workers.

- Unemployment rate: Percentage of the labour force population ages 15 and older that is not

in paid employment or self-employed but is available for work and has taken steps to seek paid

employment or self-employment.

- Youth unemployment rate: Percentage of the labour force population ages 15–24 that is not

in paid employment or self-employed but is available for work and has taken steps to seek paid

employment or self-employment.

- Output per worker: Output per unit of labour input, expressed as GDP per person engaged, in

2005 international dollars using purchasing power parity rates.

- Hours worked per week: The number of hours that employed people (wage and salaried work-

ers as well as self-employed workers) work per week.

F.4.2 Interpretation

A variable that is not given in the table is the employment to population ratio. This ratio for

2013 states that 73% of the population in Peru (older than 15) is employed, while in Belgium

this in only 49%. The labour force participation rate, the first in the table, gives the same con-

clusion: Relatively, a lot more people are employed in Peru and Bolivia compared to Belgium,

especially in agriculture. However, in Belgium, there is relatively more labour force with ter-

tiary education (not given in table): 41,3% compared to 15,7% in Peru and Bolivia. From 1990

to 2012, employment in services has increased in Belgium and agriculture has decreased. The

contrary happened in Peru and Bolivia: There is a lot more employment in agriculture in recent

years. The amount of vulnerable employment is also a lot higher in these countries. The unem-

ployment rate seems to be higher in Belgium than in Peru and Bolivia and seems to comprise

a lot of youth. When looking at the youth not in school or employment (not given in table), the

percentage is higher in Peru than in Belgium (16,5% compared to 12,7%). This indicates that a

lot of youth in Belgium has a higher education, while in Peru this isn’t the case. The last metric

is the labour productivity: This is a lot higher in Belgium (4 times higher than in Peru and 8

times higher than in Bolivia) although in Peru, they work a lot more hours per week.

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 115

F.5 International Integration

F.5.1 Definitions

The last metrics to determine the position of the Peru and Bolivia relative to Belgium are given

in table F.8 and can be explained as follows:

- Exports and imports: The sum of exports and imports of goods and services, expressed as a

percentage of gross domestic product (GDP). It is a basic indicator of openness to foreign trade

and economic integration and indicates the dependence of domestic producers on foreign de-

mand (exports) and of domestic consumers and producers on foreign supply (imports), relative

to the country’s economic size (GDP).

- Foreign direct investment, net inflows: Sum of equity capital, reinvestment of earnings, other

long-term capital and short-term capital, expressed as a percentage of GDP.

- Private capital flows: Net foreign direct investment and portfolio investment, expressed as a

percentage of GDP.

- Net migration rate: Ratio of the difference between the number of in-migrants and out-migrants

from a country to the average population, expressed per 1,000 people.

- Stock of immigrants: Ratio of the stock of immigrants into a country, expressed as a percentage

of the country’s population. The definition of immigrant varies across countries but generally

includes the stock of foreign-born people, the stock of foreign people (according to citizenship)

or a combination of the two.

- Internet users: People with access to the worldwide network.

F.5.2 Interpretation

We can derive from the table that the exports and imports of Belgium determine an enormous

part relative to the GDP of Belgium (164,2%). This is a lot more than Bolivia (81,4%) and Peru

(48,4%). The financial flows indicate that Belgium does not really invest much in foreign capital

since this percentage is negative. Bolivia and Peru do quite some foreign direct investments

but no private capital flows (Private capital flows are negative for all three countries). The net

migration rate and the stock of immigrants clearly illustrates that more people are migrating to

Belgium compared to people that are leaving Belgium, while this is not the case in Bolivia and

Peru. In Bolivia and Peru, more people are leaving the country than there are entering the coun-

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 116

try. This causes a bigger stock of immigrants in Belgium, as can be seen in the table. Last but

not least, the number of internet users back in 2014 was already significantly higher in Belgium

than in Peru or Bolivia. This is another indication of the difference in development between

the countries: Belgium can be categorized as a country with very high human development,

Peru can be categorized as a country with high human development and Bolivia is still seen

as a country with medium human development. To give an illustration, this investigation in-

cludes all countries in the world such as very poor African countries. Relative to these countries,

Bolivia and Peru are doing quite good. However, there is still a lot of potential for improvement.

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 117

Tab

leF.

1:H

um

anD

evel

op

men

tIn

dex

and

com

po

nen

tsfo

r20

14.

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Ind

ex(H

DI)

Life

exp

ecta

ncy

atb

irth

Exp

ecte

dye

ars

ofs

cho

oli

ng

Mea

nye

ars

ofs

cho

oli

ng

Gro

ssN

atio

nal

Inco

me

(GN

I)

per

cap

ita

Cou

ntr

yV

alu

e(y

ears

)(y

ears

)(y

ears

)(2

011

PP

P$)

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m0,

890

80,8

16,3

11,3

4118

7

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

0,73

474

,613

,19,

011

015

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a0,

662

68,3

13,2

8,2

576

0

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 118

Tab

leF.

2:H

um

anD

evel

op

men

tIn

dex

for

1990

-201

4an

dth

eav

erag

ean

nu

alH

DI

grow

thp

erco

un

try

for

this

per

iod

.

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

entI

nd

ex(H

DI)

Ave

rage

An

nu

alH

DI

grow

th

Cou

ntr

yV

alu

e(%

)

1990

2000

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

1990

-200

020

00-2

010

2010

-201

419

90-2

014

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m0,

806

0,87

40,

883

0,88

60,

889

0,88

80,

890

0,81

0,10

0,21

0,41

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

0,61

30,

677

0,71

80,

722

0,72

80,

732

0,73

41,

000,

580,

570,

75

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a0,

536

0,60

30,

641

0,64

70,

654

0,65

80,

662

1,19

0,61

0,79

0,88

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 119

Table F.3: Poverty indices for Bolivia and Peru in 2008 and 2012 respectively.

Population living

below national poverty

line (%)

Population in severe

multidimensional poverty (%)

Bolivia 45,0 7,8

Peru 23,9 2,1

Table F.4: Poverty indices for Peru from 2008 to 2012.

Year

Population in

multidimensional poverty

(%)

Population in severe

poverty (%)

2012 10,4 2,1

2011 12,2 2,8

2010 13,2 3,1

2008 16,1 3,9

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 120

Tab

leF.

5:Po

pu

lati

on

tren

ds,

mo

rtal

ity

rate

s,li

tera

cyra

tean

dse

con

dar

yed

uca

tio

nra

tefo

rB

elgi

um

,Per

uan

dB

oli

via.

Tota

lpo

pu

lati

on

Ave

rage

ann

ual

grow

thM

edia

nag

eA

du

ltm

ort

alit

yra

teLi

tera

cyra

te

Cou

ntr

yIn

mil

lion

s(%

)(y

ears

)(P

er1

000

peo

ple

:

fem

ale/

mal

e)(%

)

2014

2030

2000

-200

520

10-2

015

2015

2013

2013

2013

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m11

,111

,70,

50,

441

,957

9810

0%

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

30,8

36,5

1,3

1,3

27,1

9011

693

,8%

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a10

,813

,71,

91,

622

,817

224

794

,5%

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 121

Tab

leF.

6:N

atio

nal

inco

me

and

com

po

siti

on

ofr

eso

urc

es.

Gro

ssD

om

esti

c

Pro

du

ct(G

DP

)

Gen

eral

Gov

ern

men

t

con

sum

pti

on

exp

end

itu

re

Co

nsu

mer

pri

ce

ind

ex

Cou

ntr

yP

erca

pit

a

(201

1P

PP

$)

Tota

l

(%of

GD

P)

Ave

rage

ann

ual

grow

th(%

)(2

010

=10

0)

2013

2005

-201

320

05-2

013

2013

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m40

607

24,4

1,1

108

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

1139

611

,26,

711

0

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a5

934

13,9

9,3

121

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 122

Tab

leF.

7:E

mp

loym

entr

ates

and

lab

ou

rp

rod

uct

ivit

yin

Bel

giu

m,B

oli

via

and

Per

u.

Em

plo

ymen

tU

nem

plo

ymen

tLa

bo

ur

pro

du

ctiv

ity

Lab

ou

rfo

rce

par

tici

pat

ion

rate

Em

plo

ymen

tin

agri

cult

ure

Em

plo

ymen

t

inse

rvic

es

Vu

lner

able

emp

loym

ent

Tota

lYo

uth

Ou

tpu

tper

wo

rker

Ho

urs

wo

rked

per

wee

k

Cou

ntr

y(%

ages

15

and

old

er)

(%of

tota

l

emp

loym

ent)

(%of

labo

ur

forc

e)

(%of

you

th

labo

ur

forc

e)(2

011

PP

P$)

Per

emp

loye

d

per

son

)

2013

1990

2012

1990

2012

2008

-201

320

08-2

013

2008

-201

420

05-2

012

2003

-201

2

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m53

,33,

11,

265

,677

,110

,88,

423

,280

810

30,3

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

76,2

1,2

25,8

71,5

56,8

46,3

4,0

8,8

1819

140

,2

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a72

,51,

232

,173

,247

,954

,92,

76,

210

026

/

APPENDIX F. THE POSITION OF PERU AND BOLIVIA 123

Tab

leF.

8:In

tern

atio

nal

inte

grat

ion

ofB

elgi

um

,Per

uan

dB

oli

via.

Trad

eF

inan

cial

flow

sH

um

anm

ob

ilit

yC

om

mu

nic

atio

n

Exp

ort

san

d

imp

ort

s

Fore

ign

dir

ect

inve

stm

ent,

net

infl

ows

Pri

vate

cap

ital

flow

s

Net

mig

rati

on

rate

Sto

cko

f

imm

igra

nts

Inte

rnet

use

rs

Cou

ntr

y(%

ofG

DP

)(%

ofG

DP

)(%

ofG

DP

)(P

er1

000

peo

ple

)(%

ofp

opu

lati

on)

(%of

pop

ula

tion

)

2013

2013

2013

2015

2013

2014

Very

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Bel

giu

m16

4,2

-0,6

-10,

02,

710

,485

,0

Hig

hH

um

anD

evel

op

men

t

Peru

48,4

4,6

-7,1

-2,0

0,3

40,2

Med

ium

Hu

man

Dev

elo

pm

ent

Bo

livi

a81

,45,

7-4

,3-2

,41,

439

,0