AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

download AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

of 8

Transcript of AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    1/8

    If you are puzzled by the debate over the future of oil and, like most of us, have no access

    to primary data to form an independent opinion based on physical facts, there is still help

    available to see through the fog of information and disinformation. Consider thefollowing:

    Conservative estimates published by U.S. Government sources indicate that the world isfast approaching the point where half of its oil endowment will be gone; consumption

    outpaces new discoveries of conventionally accessible reserves by a wide margin; loud

    and clear market signals for increased supplies during the past decade remainedunanswered; and the current flow of capital into expanding production to levels

    commensurate with the planets economic ambitions is wholly inadequate.

    These four seemingly unrelated observations in toto lead to the conclusion that themaximum rate of global oil output cannot be far. If we could complete the graph of

    historical production with 20 more annual entries, and calculated a 10-year moving

    average for the century of 1930-2030, a smooth, Hubbert-like curve rising, peaking, and

    descending without recourse would appear on the screen.

    Contrast the apparent, cost-dictated difficulties a sustained increase of oil productionfaces with forecasts of further growth in the worlds already precarious dependence on

    this paleo-biological substance, and the picture becomes even clearer: The peak is not a

    knife edge-like turning point. It is a time zone, a temporal force field. Its effects are felt

    long before and after it shows up as a statistic. We are already living cheek by jowl withits consequences, but the perplexingly contradictory expert opinion on reserves, tainted

    with brazen claims of superabundance, and resistance against parting with routine

    economic and political motivations prevent their recognition.

    While it is generally acknowledged that the world economy needs to reconfigure itsenergy base so as to rely primarily on renewable sources, it is rarely admitted that therequisite process of transition cannot be smooth. Putting it as succinctly as possible, here

    is the reason why.

    There is conflict between economic growth objectives and the structural

    transformation of the energy base.

    Our techno-economic civilizations dependence on fossil sources is so overwhelming thatthe expansion of the renewable energy sector is inconceivable without heavy reliance on

    them. An economist might say that the coefficient of renewable-energy supply elasticity

    for fossil-fuel demand is a positive number (hopefully less than 1.0).

    Even if a solar panel and cell manufacturing plant is able to produce the energy it needs,

    its total material (metals and minerals), off-plant energy demands involved inwarehousing, marketing, transportation (personnel and goods), and administration are

    built into the economys input-output grid. Renewable energy generation is entangled in

    the flow of inputs into the sectors and the transaction of outputs among them. A drastic

    change in the scheme implies an epochal development in technology as well as in the

    1

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    2/8

    ways value added is generated and distributed; that is, income and employment, living

    standards and socioeconomic institutions are maintained.

    John Donnes No man is an island . . . applies to every heroic effort aimed at carving

    out a local sanctuary of green energy.

    Fumbling on the margin of transition is possible without transforming the economic

    structure; which, given the past threescore years advances in trade liberalization, has

    acquired a distinctly transnational character. However, prohibitive obstacles wouldemerge before the scale and tempo of the process could reach its tipping point.

    Transitions unsolved problems

    A tradeoff exists between using resources (including energy and material inputs of fossil

    origin) to feed the growth of material production (industry and agriculture) and to support

    the economys structural transformation.

    Hearing this, conventional economics comes out swinging with the old one-two:

    Economic growth is not confined to such a zero-sum game (resources constantly expand);and the desired transformation has always been envisaged as gradual. Then the knock-out

    blow: Knowledge, efficiency, and organization have reduced the human economys

    dependence on natural resources.

    To show how ineffectual and off target this entire argumentation is, let us begin with the

    intended knock-out. It is true that material resources and energy carriers together

    account for less than ten percent of the GDP in developed economies, but so does theweight of blood supply in the average human body. Restricting that small percentage in

    either case spells calamity. Vulgar (un-ecological) economics has turned the economy-

    natural resource relationship on its head and tries to keep it that way.

    The old one-two also misses the target for reasons that are at once physical and

    systemic.

    The scale of a primarily renewable-energy-based world economy may be smaller than the

    one already in existence; a circumstance that long-term official growth targets, certainly

    justified by the abject poverty of at least one billion people and the legitimate aspirationof billions of others to raise their levels of living to developed country standards,

    completely ignore.

    As the substitution of renewable for nonrenewable (primarily fossil) energy continues,

    nature exerts resistance at some point; the scale limit begins to bind. Either economic

    growth or transition must halt. Both alternatives lead to severe disequilibrium. The firstbecause increased pauperization and the apparent irreducibility of income differentials

    would endanger social peace. Also, since an economic order built on competition among

    private firms cannot exist without expansion, the free enterprise system would flounder.

    2

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    3/8

    The second alternative is equally untenable because the depletion of nonrenewable

    resources, proceeding along a rising marginal cost curve or, equivalently, along a

    descending Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROI) schedule, increases productioncosts across the entire spectrum of activities. Supply curves shift upwards.

    The problem that substitution tries avoid -- running out of affordable nonrenewableresources -- becomes more acute as time passes.

    The prevalent incentive system, which is naturally aligned with traditional consumercapitalism, rejects a large-scale substitution of nonrenewable resources. It does not jibe

    with its endless long-term growth perspective and it reflexively repels the requisite

    transformation in the short run.

    This is the mechanism through which the systems complex defense network

    unconsciously immunizes poisonous greening: When energy prices are low, energy

    carriers flow into expanding the production of consumer goods. But when as a result of

    the systems inability to maintain the abundance of cheap energy, the exchange value ofcarriers begins to increase faster than the general price level, aggregate demand receives a

    shock. The resultant threat of recession closes the door on private incentives. Theeconomys currently unchangeable dependence on oil seals it.

    The obvious requirement for substituting away from oil is that its price should exceed the

    price of the substitute by a significant margin. However, given the importance of oil inevery single cell of the body economic, the price of solar and wind energy, for example,

    would tend to rise with the barrel.

    The incentive that worked (and still works) in substituting consumer and manmade

    capital goods for one another will not lead to a sustainable energy base.

    The currently experienced will-o-the-wisp reprieve from the oil constraint only

    reinforces this ever more obvious conclusion. Goldilockean, not too low and not too

    high oil prices neither spur the private sector to green the worlds energy base nor is itmore than a strictly temporary phenomenon. It is tied to persistent unemployment in the

    United States, the worlds largest consumer and importer of crude. Once demand begins

    to press against supply as a result of India and China, the price of oil will go up to

    disruptive levels once again with or without resumption of U.S. growth.

    The micro-foundations of the mixed economy are such that the elasticity of substitution

    between nonrenewable and renewable energy sources is too low in the desired direction.Even when the price of oil rises above its renewable-source substitutes -- sluggishly for

    the reasons cited; the global input ratio, quantity of nonexhaustible substitutes for oil

    consumed per a given period divided by the quantity of oil consumed during the sameperiod will not increase to an extent that would be needed to accomplish transition to a

    significantly more sustainable world economy.

    3

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    4/8

    To summarize, the physical constraint facing the global economy invalidates the

    expansion of resources argument, and the one that claims that transition will be

    accomplished with gradual smoothness falters on the systems micro-level resistance.There is trouble also with the macro-foundations.

    Public authority in the mixed economy is insufficient to clear the logjam.

    Apetit tourof recent macrohistory in support of this proposition follows.

    The Great Depression turned the United States of the 1930s into an experimental

    laboratory in which democratic institutions and traditions allowed society to seek a new

    equilibrium between labor and capital and develop modalities appropriate for guiding the

    growth of mass production and consumption. The resultant mixed economy (solidifiedlegally, ideologically, and psychologically by the Employment Act of 1946) was cloned

    with incredible speed and matter-of-fact naturalness by the rest of the industrialized

    world immediately after the war.

    Based on the principle of multilateralism, the United Nations, with its panoply of

    chartered organizations, provided the framework of international cooperation. Sincesupranational institutions remained subordinate to nation states; i.e., they cannot be

    regarded as a World Government, the current global system may best be described asmixed economy/weak multilateralism. (Until the end of the Cold War, it seemed that there

    were two competing global systems vying for domination. In retrospect, this view isincorrect. During its peak years, the Soviet Bloc represented less than five percent of

    world trade and, to avoid ruinous isolation la Kim Jong-ils North Korea, countries

    under communist control had to conduct their international relations within the industrial-democracy-dominated UN framework.)

    Multilateral institutions -- especially the WTO/GATT, the IMF, and The World

    Bank -- are the guardians of the world orders mixed economy character.

    Only pariah regimes remain outside these agencies, but once inside, they arecontractually obligated to abide by the fundamental principle of the mixed economy:

    Laissez fair, with governments role restricted to using mainly indirect tools of

    governance; i.e., fiscal and monetary measures.

    The system tolerates state-led industrial policies within limits, particularly when it comes

    to developing countries. But the pressure against the idea and practice of government

    support extended to specific economic sectors or industries is relentless. Using itsvirtually apostolic authority, neoclassical academe has come close to turning the claim

    that government interference does more harm than good into an edict. It has injected into

    public policy analysis mathematical models that treat tax and tariff reductions asautomatically growth-spurring, job-creating achievements of enlightened societies.

    The substantial public role in Asias economic progress over the past decades has been

    smeared and rubbed to innocuousness through definitions and by imparting more clout to

    4

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    5/8

    econometric work in support than in opposition to the principle that privatization and

    liberalization is the quickest, surest, and least-expensive way to high living standards.

    Time relentlessly tests the appropriateness of economic organization for its ability to

    fulfill social objectives.

    No matter how successful the system ofmixed economy/weak multilateralism has been in

    increasing and spreading prosperity over half a century, it is no exception. If it becomes

    widely recognized that it cannot harmonize the planets activities with its physicallimitations, it will have to go too. This may indeed be the case.

    The curve depicting the marginal social cost of oil production faces an abrupt acclivity,

    the introduction of substitutes is mired in demanding oil as a complement, and the entireprocess seems helpless without enlarging the role of the state beyond the mixed

    economys legal-institutional parameters.

    This new reality, which differs so profoundly from what postwar generations came toregard as permanent, does not announce itself clearly. But nor is it hidden beyond any

    hope of grasping it. A little unorthodox eyeballing suffices to show that, given the rolethat oil now plays in global welfare, the system is out of whack; the stasis built around it

    has been punctuated. Specifically, one of the mixed economys canonical principles, the

    independence of the market rate of interest from any given industry, no longer applies.

    Checking out from Hotelling

    The Hotelling Rule, dating to 1931, retains a considerable influence on the wayeconomists think about nonrenewable resources. It has been stated in many different

    ways, but the bottom line is simple enough: The market rate of interest (i), characterizing

    general economic conditions, plays a key role in deciding how fast to draw downreserves.

    If owners of a scarce resource expect return on investments they could make in the rest ofthe economy to exceed the appreciation of their reserves, increasing extraction makes

    good sense. The appreciation of reserves is measured by dividing next years expected

    rent (profits to be obtained exclusively as a result of possessing the scarce resource) --

    denoted as (t + 1) -- by this years rent, (t ). When (t + 1) / (t) is smaller thanoverall return in the economy -- (i +1) -- there will be more of the scarce resource on the

    market since (1 + i) > (t + 1) / (t) makes it rational for the owners to step up the

    liquidation of reserves and invest the proceeds elsewhere in the economy.

    When the inequality sign points in the opposite direction, i.e., interest rates are relatively

    low, the incentive goes into reverse: Scale back and wait until the opportunity cost ofsitting on the reserves -- (1 + i) -- rises.

    The Hotelling Rule proposes that competition among the owners of nonrenewable

    resources will tend to equate the opportunity cost of production now and production later

    5

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    6/8

    via the market rate of interest. That is, the condition (1 + i) = (t + 1) / (t) will pave the

    optimal path to emptying reservoirs.

    To appreciate this theory, it is important to note that economists like to equate high real

    (inflation adjusted) interest rates with prosperous times. Productive capacity and

    purchasing power are growing. The world produces and earns more; capital continues toflow into new machinery, equipment, buildings, infrastructure, and intangible productive

    assets. Growth calculus even equates a summary, symbolic rate of real interest with the

    steady state tempo of global expansion, determined by the combined increase ofpopulation and productivity.

    Beautiful minds conceived all this, but after the insatiable Leviathan has gone through a

    trillion barrels of oil and, in close relationship with this devastating throughput, anunsalvageable international monetary-credit system begot astronomic quantities of

    worthless payment obligations, winds blow differently.

    Peak Oil renders Hotelling obsolete.

    Since both theories predict a decline in the rate of oil output over the long run, they seemto be compatible. But this is mere appearance.

    The Hotelling Rule has practical relevance only if the low and diminishing supply of

    the nonrenewable resource in question does not constrain economic growth and if strongcompetition prevails among suppliers. Short of allowing oneself to remain hypnotized be

    the internal consistency of neoclassic algebra -- along with sound-bites attesting to the

    titanic lore of markets and mans unlimited engineering genius -- one can see that theseconditions are absent from the contemporary economic scene.

    The actual and prospective supply of oil does act as a growth constraint and the pastdecade has revealed that OPEC can act more in a concerted fashion than previously

    believed.

    The absence of conditions required for the Hotelling Rule has shrunk the mixed

    economys policy space. Keynes, the systems philosophical sire, considered the rate of

    interest an independent variable in the hands of central banks. But if the state of the

    economy can worsen as a result of reduced flows of oil, central banks have no choice butto reduce interest rates through increasing the money supply in order to stimulate

    recovery. There goes the independence of the independent variable and the

    meaningfulness of the real rate of interest as a long-term growth indicator. High real ratesare as likely to imply expansion as contraction, good news or bad news.

    To repeat, the mixed economy and the global system based on it presume that firm- orindustry-level investment decisions do not alter general economic conditions. All

    particular judgments about investing in real capital (machinery, equipment, etc.) are

    guided by what the same amount of money would expect to yield if it were invested

    elsewhere, including the financial sector. That is, economic agents depend on

    6

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    7/8

    comparative (present value) calculations in which the prevailing or expected market rate

    of interest is independent from their actions.

    Things have become very different in our brave new, post-Hotelling, post-Keynesian

    world. Decisions made in the boardrooms of OPEC forcefully affect both the global

    economys critical resource and the market rate of interest, nominal and real.

    Oil is king but, as Hemingway mused, how happy are kings?

    Monopoly power means an ability to influence the price. But in the sunset phase of the

    petroleum age this simple one-step has turned into a roundelay. The price will have an

    impact on the rate of interest that will loop back to the price. In theory, major oil

    producing nations could control this interwoven dance, but in practice they cannot. Evenif monopoly power can be preserved as oil depletion proceeds, the chain of causalities

    along the price-interest rate-price circle is too uncertain both in terms of time and

    effect.

    Prices set too high could catalyze post-peak-characteristic structural transformation in

    the worlds energy base, devaluing reserves. And while sovereignty over how high theceiling can go has been reduced, the floor is rising. The inevitable increase in the

    marginal cost of production tends either to reduce the rent (price minus marginal cost)

    or lead to the error of setting prices cripplingly high.

    To recap the same dilemma in an alternative way, if the oil monopoly over-boosts the

    rent it destroys opportunities to invest profitably in the rest of the world. If it wants to

    feed global prosperity in order to maintain and expand opportunities for investing exportrevenues, it would hasten the end of the bonanza, reducing the time budget available for

    transiting to an economic structure no longer dependent on oil export revenues.

    In this all-around dangerous Odyssey, the monopoly tries to navigate the whirlpool

    between the Scylla of overcharging (and harming itself indirectly through damage caused

    to the global economic environment) and the Charybdis of undercharging (sufferingdirect harm through forgone revenues). The thickening fog of uncertainty may require

    modifying the tactic daily, but the overall strategy has constant components. Exhaust

    natures one-time gift as slowly as possible and forestall net oil importers momentum

    toward greening their energy base.

    Consequently, the oil monopoly must lull the rest of us into believing that the Earth, in

    general, and itself, in particular, have enormous riches of untapped reserves -- much morethan claimed to be the case by independent (i.e. not oil money supported) expertise.

    Such self-regarding course of action is logical and judicious from the monopolysstandpoint. Yet it defies imagination how widespread, unfounded expectations for

    affordable long-run oil supplies will not lead to an all-engulfing catharsis, a Wagnerian

    finale to our reckless materialistic disposition and correspondingly deficient economic

    and social structures.

    7

  • 8/9/2019 AGE OF PETROLEUM ENDS IN SYSTEMIC IMBROGLIO

    8/8

    The specter of segmented rationality haunts the world just when it needs collective vision

    more than ever.

    8