A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that...

134
Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Scott Sinclair and Jim Grieshaber-Otto A guide to the GATS debate NEW WTO NEGOTIATIONS A guide to the GATS debate

Transcript of A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that...

Page 1: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

C a n a d i a n C e n t r e f o r P o l i c y A l t e r n a t i v e s

Scott Sinclair andJim Grieshaber-Otto

A guide to the GATS debate

N E W W T O N E G O T I A T I O N S

A guide to the GATS debate

Page 2: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

A guide to the GATS debate

Scott Sinclair andJim Grieshaber-Otto

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives2002

Page 3: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Copyright © 2002 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives andthe authors.

All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced ortransmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechani-cal, including photocopying, or by any information storage orretrieval system, without permission in writing from the pub-lisher or the author.

CAW 567OTTAWA

Printed and bound in Canada

Published by

Canadian Centre for Policy AlternativesSuite 410, 75 Albert StreetOttawa, ON K1P 5E7Tel 613-563-1341 Fax 613-233-1458http://[email protected]

National Library of Canada Cataloguing in Publication Data

Sinclair, ScottFacing the facts : a guide to the GATS debate

Includes bibliographical references.ISBN 0-88627-278-5

1. General Agreement on Trade in Services (1994) 2. Serviceindustries—Government policy. 3. World Trade Organization.4. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.I. Grieshaber-Otto, Jim II. Canadian Centre for Policy Alterna-tives. III. Title.

HF1379.S557 2002 382'.45 C2002-900954-5

Page 4: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Contents

Acknowledgements ...................................................................... i

Summary: The growing GATS debate ................................... iiiThe scope of the GATS is immense .............................................................. ivDoes the GATS cover public services? ......................................................... vJust how flexible is the GATS? ....................................................................... viThe policy implications of GATS rules ...................................................... viiiConclusion ........................................................................................................... xii

Chapter 1: The growing GATS debate .................................... 1

Chapter 2: GATS scope and coverage .................................... 9The breadth and diversity of services ....................................................... 10The “top-down” features of the GATS ......................................................... 12The “bottom-up” features of the GATS ...................................................... 25The GATS general exceptions ....................................................................... 35

Chapter 3: GATS policy implications .................................. 41The right to regulate in the GATS preamble ........................................... 41Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment (Article II) .......................................... 44National Treatment (Article XVII) ................................................................. 48Market Access (Article XVI) ............................................................................ 52Monopolies and exclusive service suppliers (Article VIII) ................... 58Domestic Regulation (Article VI) ................................................................. 63

Chapter 4: Conclusions ............................................................ 71

Endnotes ....................................................................................... 81

Appendix 1: List of acronyms ............................................... 105

Appendix 2: Glossary of key GATS terms ......................... 107

Page 5: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.
Page 6: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts i

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank Patricia Arnold, BruceCampbell, Tony Clarke, John Dillon, Murray Dobbin, EdFinn, Kerri-Anne Finn, Ellen Gould, Paul Mably, KarenPhilp, David Price, Mathew Sanger, Noel Schacter, StevenShrybman, Michelle Swenarchuk, Ken Traynor, ElisabethTuerk and members of the CCPA Trade and InvestmentResearch Project, who have provided suggestions, com-ments and other invaluable support. Any errors or omis-sions that remain are the sole responsibility of the authors.We are also very grateful to the many organizations thatmade this book possible by providing financial assistanceto the Trade and Investment Research Project. The inspi-rational efforts on GATS issues of a growing number ofresearchers, organizations and citizens around the worldare also gratefully acknowledged. Finally, we thank ourfamilies for their unstinting support, steadfast encourage-ment and deep generosity.

Page 7: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

ii Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Page 8: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts iii

Summary:The growing GATS debate

Shrouded in obscurity when the last round of World Trade Or-ganization (WTO) negotiations were concluded in 1994, theGeneral Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) is only nowbeginning to receive the public scrutiny that it deserves. Asnon-governmental organizations have examined this ex-ceptionally broad treaty, they have expressed growingconcern about its potentially far-reaching impacts. In re-sponse, GATS proponents recently issued two officialworks contesting GATS critics: “GATS: Fact and Fiction”by the WTO Services Secretariat and “Open Services Mar-kets Matter” by the Trade Policy Committee of the Or-ganization for Economic Cooperation and Development(OECD). Both tracts challenge critics’ arguments, theformer characterizing them as “scare stories.”

A challenge for those in the public, media and politicstrying to sort out the GATS debate is that the differentsides sometimes seem to be saying directly contradictorythings about the same agreement. At other times, one sidegives the impression of disagreeing sharply with the otherwhile seeming to say much the same thing in a slightlydifferent way. This analysis seeks to tease apart some ofthe most important GATS issues and to dispel the confu-sion that often exists even for the most discerning observ-ers.

This analysis provides a detailed critique of official WTOand OECD rebuttals, documenting numerous instances wherethey provide simplistic or misleading assurances. It examinesthe growing controversies over GATS coverage of publicservices, GATS flexibility, governments’ right to regulate,

Page 9: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

iv Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

and the policy impact of the most important GATS rulesIt also examines the key concerns of critics—that the GATSthreatens public services systems and public interest regula-tion—and concludes that these concerns are, in fact, well-founded. For these reasons, the GATS, together with thenegotiations now underway to expand the treaty, is slated tobecome a lightning rod for growing debate and controversy.

Agreeing on the point of departure:The scope of the GATS is immense

Both proponents and critics agree that the scope of theGATS is very broad. Its extraordinary breadth derivesfrom the incredible diversity of services, the architectureof the agreement, and the expansive way the GATS de-fines key terms.

The subject matter of the GATS—services—is almost un-imaginably broad. Services range from birth (midwifery)to death (burial); the trivial (shoe-shining) to the critical(heart surgery); the personal (haircutting) to the social(primary education); low-tech (household help) to high-tech (satellite communications); and from our wants (re-tail sales of toys) to our needs (water distribution). TheGATS applies to all measures affecting “trade in services,”broadly defined. It covers measures taken by all levels of gov-ernment, including central, regional, and local governments.It also applies to professional associations, standards-set-ting bodies, and boards of hospitals, schools and univer-sities, where these bodies exercise authority conferredupon them by any level of government. In other words,no government action, whatever its purpose—protecting theenvironment, safeguarding consumers, enforcing labour stand-

Page 10: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts v

ards, promoting fair competition, ensuring universal service orany other end—is, in principle, beyond GATS scrutiny andpotential challenge.

As a former director general of the WTO has correctlynoted, the GATS extends “into areas never before recog-nized as trade policy.” Not limited to cross-border trade,it extends to every possible means of providing a serviceinternationally, including investment. While this broadapplication does not mean all services-related measuresviolate the treaty, it does mean that any regulatory or leg-islative initiative in any WTO-member country must nowbe vetted for GATS consistency or risk possible challenge.

The treaty covers “any service in any sector” with onlylimited exceptions; no service sector is excluded a priori.This all-inclusive framework binds member governmentsto certain GATS rules that already apply across all sec-tors—even those where no specific commitments havebeen made. It also means that all service sectors are on thetable in ongoing, continuous negotiations.

Does the GATS cover public services?

Nowhere are GATS proponents on shakier ground thanwhen they claim that the GATS fully protects public serv-ices through its so-called governmental authority exclu-sion. For example, WTO Director General Michael Moorehas asserted that “GATS explicitly excludes services sup-plied by governments”—a bald statement that is clearlyuntrue. This controversial exclusion only applies to thosegovernmental services which are provided neither on acommercial nor a competitive basis. These critical termsare left undefined. The GATS governmental authority exclu-sion—which proponents claim protects public services — is, at

Page 11: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

vi Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

best, unclear and subject to conflicting interpretations. At worst,if narrowly interpreted by dispute panels, the exclusion is oflittle or no practical effect.

Just how flexible is the GATS?

The flexibility of the GATS, and its limits, is another im-portant area of controversy. GATS proponents indicatethat the treaty provides governments “remarkable flex-ibility,” to open their services markets at their own pace,according to an “a la carte approach to liberalization.” Butthis is an oversimplification. Certain GATS obligations, mostnotably the most-favoured nation rule, apply unconditionallyacross all service sectors; governments now have little choicein this matter. Moreover, while it is true that the most forcefulGATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

In practical terms, a significant amount of this flex-ibility no longer exists since most governments alreadymade substantial commitments when the agreement wasadopted, and all limitations to these commitments had tobe scheduled then. Also, member governments are andwill remain under intense pressure to cede more flexibil-ity by liberalizing further under the treaty. The treaty spe-cifically mandates successive rounds of negotiation aimedat achieving “a progressively higher level of liberaliza-tion.” As well, developed country governments activelypromote negotiation and classification devices designedto force governments into making broader and deeperGATS commitments than they otherwise might. More-over, there are enormous practical difficulties in protect-ing government policies or measures through country-specific exceptions. Any protective exceptions: must be

Page 12: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts vii

drafted extremely carefully; will be interpreted narrowly;usually protect existing measures, not future policy flex-ibility; become targets in ongoing negotiations; and areof uncertain effectiveness until tested in dispute settle-ment.

Significantly, the GATS does provide a means for gov-ernments to withdraw previously made commitments,but only so long as they are prepared to compensate othergovernments whose service suppliers are allegedly ad-versely affected.

Finally, there is an insidious bias against permanentlyinsulating public policies from GATS rules. Whereverthere is domestic multipartisan consensus, it is conceiv-able that country-specific exceptions will endure. Butwherever there are serious ideological divisions on con-tentious issues, country-specific limitations that protectpolicy flexibility are likely to endure only until a singlegovernment committed to a market-oriented approacheliminates them, binding all future governments. In thisway, the GATS interferes with the normal ebb and flow ofpolicy-making in a democratic society.

The GATS contains just two general exceptions towhich governments can turn to try to save otherwise non-conforming measures. The more important of these, GATSArticle XIV, has not yet been invoked in any WTO dis-pute, but there is little reason to be optimistic that it willprotect public interest measures from successful GATSchallenge. Despite the far broader scope and political sen-sitivity of the GATS, the treaty’s general exception iscrafted even more narrowly than the weak GATT ArticleXX provisions, which have been interpreted very restric-tively in over 50 years of GATT and WTO jurisprudence.

Page 13: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

viii Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

The only reliable GATS exception is Article XIVbis for na-tional security measures.

The policy implications of GATS rules

Controversy over governments’ right to regulateA common refrain in every official rejoinder to GATS

critics is that the GATS specifically recognizes govern-ments’ right to regulate. Regrettably, it is terribly mislead-ing to suggest that the mere affirmation of the right toregulate, contained in the treaty preamble, fully protectsthe right to regulate. It does not. While the preamble doescontain a clause that “recognizes the right of Members toregulate,” this language has strictly limited legal effect. Itwould have some interpretive value in a dispute, butshould not be construed as providing legal cover for regu-lations that would otherwise be inconsistent with the sub-stantive provisions of the treaty. In short, governments re-tain their freedom to regulate only to the extent that the regula-tions they adopt are compatible with the GATS.

The MFN rule: More powerful than generally acknowledgedDespite its acknowledged importance, the GATS Most-

Favoured Nation Treatment (MFN) rule is discussed onlybriefly in the WTO and OECD tracts. MFN has proven tobe a surprisingly powerful obligation in two recent GATS-related disputes. The rule is better understood as a most-favoured-foreign company rule, as it requires that any regu-latory or funding advantage gained by a single foreigncommercial provider must be extended, immediately andunconditionally, to all. The MFN obligation has the practicaleffect of consolidating commercialization wherever it occurs.While not legally precluding a new policy direction, this

Page 14: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts ix

rule makes it far more difficult for governments to reversefailed privatization and commercialization.

The National Treatment and Market Access rulesThe hard core of the GATS is comprised of restrictions

that apply only to the sectors, or sub-sectors, where gov-ernments have made specific commitments. These com-mitments, together with any country-specific limitations,are listed in each government’s GATS schedule.

The GATS national treatment rule requires govern-ments to extend the best treatment given to domestic serv-ices (or service providers) to like foreign services (or serv-ice providers). In the GATS, this rule is quite intrusive, asit explicitly requires government measures to pass a verytough test of de facto non-discrimination. That is, meas-ures that on their face are impartial can still be found in-consistent if they modify the conditions of competition in fa-vour of domestic services or service providers. This givesdispute panels wide latitude to find measures GATS-ille-gal even when they are, on their face, non-discriminatoryor when such measures alter the conditions of competi-tion merely as an unintended consequence in the legiti-mate pursuit of other vital policy goals. The GATS’ stiffnational treatment requirement thus opens the doors for non-discriminatory public policy to be frustrated for reasons thatare unrelated to international trade.

The GATS Market Access rule in one of the treaty’s mostnovel, and troublesome, provisions. While the WTO andOECD documents play down its significance, there isnothing quite like this rule in other international commer-cial treaties. Framed in absolute rather than relative terms,it precludes certain types of policies whether they are dis-criminatory or not. A government intent on maintaining

Page 15: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

x Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

otherwise inconsistent measures is forced to inscribe themin its country schedule when it makes its specific com-mitments. This rule prohibits governments from placingrestrictions on: the number of service suppliers or opera-tions; the value of service transactions; the number ofpersons that may be employed in a sector; and, signifi-cantly, the types of legal entities through which suppliersmay supply a service. This prohibition calls into question,for example, the GATS-consistency of limits imposed toconserve resources or protect the environment. Also, manygovernments restrict the private delivery of certain socialservices such as childcare to non-profit agencies. Manyalso confine certain basic services such as rail transporta-tion, water distribution, or energy transmission to private,not-for-profit providers. Such public policies certainlyrestrict the market access of commercial providers,whether domestic or foreign. But they have never beforebeen subject to binding international treaty obligations.Now, whether this was intended or not, these policies areexposed to GATS challenge.

Other important GATS obligations: Restrictions on monopo-lies and regulation

The WTO and OECD tracts contain little discussionof the policy implications of the GATS restrictions on mo-nopolies and exclusive service suppliers. Neither piecefully acknowledges that the GATS imposes new burdens onmonopolies and exclusive service supplier arrangements. In fact,monopolies and exclusive service suppliers are GATS-in-consistent and must be listed as country-specific excep-tions in committed sectors. Any government wishing todesignate a new monopoly in a listed sector is required to

Page 16: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts xi

negotiate compensation with other member governmentsor face retaliation.

Monopolies, while not so prevalent as they once were,are still relied upon to provide basic services in manycountries. Postal services, the distribution and sale of al-coholic beverages, electrical generation and transmission,rail transportation, health insurance, water distribution,and waste disposal are just some of the more widespreadexamples. Exclusive supplier arrangements are common-place in post-secondary education, health care and othersocial services. The consequences of these GATS rules,which so far have gone largely unexamined, are likely tobe significant in all of these important areas.

If new restrictions on domestic regulation, now being ne-gotiated in Geneva, were ever agreed to, they would constitutean extraordinary intrusion into democratic policy-making. Atissue is the development of “disciplines” on membercountry’s domestic regulation—explicitly non-discrimina-tory regulations that treat local and foreign services andservice providers evenhandedly. The subject matter ofthese proposed restrictions is very broad, covering meas-ures relating to qualification requirements and procedures,technical standards and licensing procedures — a wideswath of vital government regulatory measures.

Critically, these proposed restrictions are intended toapply some form of “necessity test,” that is, that regula-tions must not be more trade restrictive than necessaryand that measures must be necessary to achieve a speci-fied legitimate objective. Perversely, the proposed GATSrestrictions would turn the logic of the long-establishedGATT necessity test on its head. It would transform it froma shield to save clearly discriminatory measures from chal-lenge into a sword to attack clearly non-discriminatory meas-

Page 17: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

xii Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

ures. Finally, since the GATS architecture does not permitit, no exceptions are contemplated to these sweeping pro-posed restrictions on domestic regulation. The proposedGATS restrictions on domestic regulation are a recipe for regu-latory chill; they are among the most excessive restrictions evercontemplated in a binding international commercial treaty. Thisexcess is concrete evidence of the hazards of leaving theambitions of commercial ministries—and the corporatelobbyists driving them on—unchecked by broader pub-lic scrutiny and debate.

Conclusion

When the Uruguay Round was concluded in 1994, theGATS was little known outside a small circle of negotia-tors and corporate lobbyists. Early insider analyses of theGATS then frankly conceded, even celebrated, the nov-elty of the treaty and its sweeping scope and ambition.By contrast, as the GATS has attracted more public atten-tion, proponents now strive to imply that the GATS is soflexible that it leaves governments almost completely freeto govern as they choose. But the GATS is a deservedly con-troversial agreement. It is, by design, a formidable instru-ment to encourage and to entrench the commercializa-tion of services, including public services. Its broadlyworded provisions give too much weight to commercial inter-ests, constraining essential public services, legitimate publicinterest regulation, and democratic decision-making.

GATS proponents would prefer to keep its dangersout of the public eye. They adhere to what has been calledthe bicycle theory of international trade negotiations, in-sisting that the WTO’s momentum into new sectors andfields of regulation must not be allowed to falter—out of

Page 18: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts xiii

fear that if the bicycle slows down it will fall over. Oneprominent GATS architect has even suggested that paus-ing to understand “the overwhelming uncertainty” aboutits provisions amounts to “frustrating progress.” Indeed,in the power bargaining and pressure tactics employedat the recent WTO ministerial meeting in Doha, the callfor assessment of the GATS by non-governmental organi-zations and a number of key southern governments wasbrushed aside. Instead, negotiations to broaden and deepenGATS coverage will be one of the centerpieces of the new DohaRound of WTO negotiations. Firm timelines for the servicesnegotiations were agreed to as part of the Doha package,with initial requests for specific commitments due by June30, 2002, initial offers by March 31, 2003, and a finalizedrenegotiation by the ambitious deadline of January 1, 2005.In short, the bicycle theorists appear to be in firm controland setting a furious pace.

As the prominent author Susan George remarked re-cently, however, it would be far wiser to get off the bicy-cle, put our feet on the ground, and have a look around tosee where we are. If there is one lesson proponents shouldhave learned from the Seattle debacle and the failed Mul-tilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI), it is that nomatter how emphatic or strident their voices, they cannotshut down or control the debate. The GATS is such a broadly-worded, sweeping agreement, and the negotiations nowunderway to expand it raise such serious threats to democraticgovernance, that it will almost certainly stimulate greater pub-lic interest. In this circumstance, the WTO’s Fact and Fic-tion and the OECD’s Open Services Markets Matter are sofilled with misleading assurances that they could provecounterproductive—provoking citizens to greater efforts.After all, with modest effort, non-governmental organi-

Page 19: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

xiv Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

zations, elected officials, and ordinary citizens are morethan capable of understanding the critical issues, of sepa-rating GATS fact from fiction. And when they do, theyare likely to react with shocked disapproval at how far,and in what direction, the proverbial bicycle has beendriven. They will then demonstrate just how quickly theycan mobilize, and how effectively they can bring their con-siderable influence to bear on their respective govern-ments, both to change the nature of GATS negotiationsnow underway in Geneva and to chart a more balancedfuture.

Page 20: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 1

Chapter 1:The growing debate about the GATS

The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) isonly now beginning to receive the public scrutiny anddebate that it deserves. The treaty has leapfrogged, fromthe near obscurity it enjoyed when the World Trade Or-ganization (WTO) negotiations were concluded in 1994,to close to the forefront of the current debate about WTOrules. Faced with growing concerns, criticism and oppo-sition voiced by increasingly well-informed non-govern-mental organizations, GATS proponents recently re-sponded with a coordinated counterattack. The purposeof this analysis is to respond to this counterattack and torebut the main arguments employed in this official back-lash against non-governmental critics of the GATS.

Does the GATS threaten public services? Does it re-strict public interest regulation? Or, as proponents claim,are public services and public interest regulation explic-itly safeguarded? Are suggestions to the contrary merelyill-informed and hostile criticism?

A challenge for those in the public, media and politicstrying to sort out the GATS debate is that the differentsides sometimes seem to be saying diametrically opposedthings about the same agreement. At other times, one sidegives the impression of disagreeing sharply with the otherwhile seeming to say much the same thing in a slightlydifferent way. This analysis seeks to tease apart some ofthe most important GATS issues and to dispel the confu-sion that often exists even for the most discerning observ-ers.

This analysis will focus on the two principal officialworks contesting GATS critics: GATS: Fact and Fiction1, by

Page 21: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

2 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

the World Trade Organization (WTO) Services Secretariat,and Open Services Markets Matter2, by the Trade PolicyCommittee of the Organization for Economic Coopera-tion and Development (OECD).3 Fact and Fiction was pub-licly released in March 2001 just before a group of inter-national non-governmental organizations (NGOs) held aGeneva media conference to air GATS concerns. MarketsMatter, completed by the OECD in September 2001, is aself-described “advocacy piece” that “against the back-drop of increasing public scrutiny and criticism of theGATS and services trade and investment liberalization”…seeks to “demonstrate the tangible benefits associatedwith the progressive liberalization of services trade andinvestment and address concerns over the operation ofthe GATS.”4

The principal champions of the GATS in this debatehave been officials working either in the trade ministriesof the Quad countries5 or international institutions suchas the WTO and the OECD. But there is little doubt thatthis counterattack has been devised and coordinated inclose alliance with corporate lobby groups representingmultinational service industries, including the GlobalServices Network (GSN) the European Services Forum(ESF), the US Coalition of Service Industries (CSI) and theInternational Financial Services London (IFSL).6

In one sense, it is gratifying for non-governmental or-ganizations that the WTO and the OECD have felt com-pelled to respond directly to their critiques of the GATS.This reaction underscores that this is a new era when citi-zen activism and broader public debate can influence oth-erwise secretive, behind-closed-doors negotiations. In theaftermath of the WTO’s failed Seattle Ministerial and theOECD’s abortive Multilateral Agreement on Investment

Page 22: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 3

(MAI), even the trade policy elites recognize that they canno longer safely ignore these outside concerns.

But, not unexpectedly, the tone and substance of thesetwo official documents is generally far from flattering.These are polemics. This suggests that the lesson drawnby some élites from the Seattle and MAI debacles is thatcritics must be neutralized by attacking their credibilityor artfully sidestepping the issues they raise, rather thanby addressing the substance of their criticism.

The tone of these documents, especially Fact and Fic-tion, is frequently aggressive.7 For example, in its intro-duction to Fact and Fiction, the WTO complains that:

“… the negotiations and the GATS itself have be-come the subject of ill-informed and hostile criti-cism. Scare stories are invented and unquestion-ingly repeated, however implausible. It is claimed,for example, that the right to maintain public serv-ices and the power to enforce health and safetystandards are under threat, though both are ex-plicitly safeguarded under the GATS.”8

Despite this dismissive tone, more open public debateabout this important, but previously little-known treaty,is welcome and to be encouraged.

To get right to the crux of the disagreement betweenthe WTO and its critics: claims that the GATS threatenspublic services and public interest regulation are neitherscare stories nor implausible. This analysis argues thatthe critics’ concerns, accurately represented,9 are, well-founded.10

Technically speaking, GATS proponents are correct inclaiming that the GATS itself does not force individualgovernments to privatize public services. But this narrow,

Page 23: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

4 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

technical assertion is only part of the truth. Through con-tinuous rounds of repeated negotiations that are man-dated in the treaty, the GATS exerts constant pressure toopen up public services to foreign commercial providers—in other words, to privatize or commercialize them.11 Asthe book will discuss more fully later, the GATS not onlymakes it more difficult for governments to maintain pub-lic service systems intact, it especially threatens govern-ments’ ability to restore public services where they havebeen privatized, revitalize them where they haveshrunken from neglect, and to expand them in future tomeet new or changing public desires and needs.

The GATS creates legally enforceable rights that for-eign governments can invoke on behalf of their commer-cial service providers. This threat can reasonably be ex-pected to steadily erode the public, not-for-profit provi-sion of essential services such as health, education, andwater. The biggest threat to public services in the existingGATS is that it legally entrenches their commercializa-tion wherever foreign, for-profit providers get a foothold.While these incursions are not irreversible, governmentsmust pay a price to do so, making the reversal of publicservice commercialization—even when critical to the pub-lic interest—far less likely and more difficult.

GATS proponents are also technically correct, thoughmisleading, when they claim that the GATS does not doaway with governments’ right to regulate. As will be dis-cussed further, WTO member governments retain theright to regulate, provided the regulation is consistent withthe GATS. Only in this narrow and peculiar sense doesthe GATS not affect the “right to regulate.”12

There are compelling reasons to be concerned that theexisting GATS—and especially proposals to expand re-

Page 24: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 5

strictions on “domestic regulation” in ongoing negotia-tions under GATS Article VI.4—threaten vital public in-terest regulations. The range of affected regulations is farwider than just the “health and safety standards” referredto by the WTO; it also includes environmental, consumerand other protective standards.

There is, of course, much room for debate about theprecise nature of these threats, their seriousness and whatshould be done to remedy them. On these matters, thereis far greater diversity of views and respectful debateamong the critics than among the Quad trade ministries,WTO and OECD officials and other insiders who haveclosed ranks to defend the GATS against outside criticism.But for the WTO to contemptuously label these concernsas implausible is both inaccurate and regrettable. Belit-tling serious concerns stifles genuine public debate, aninappropriate role for international public servants.

Although one would hardly know it from reading theWTO and OECD’s pieces, GATS’ critics are well awarethat the agreement provides certain flexibility for govern-ments when they make liberalization commitments, andthat it also includes certain provisions that purport to safe-guard public services and the right to regulate. Since Factand Fiction was first released, many NGOs have producedthoughtful and effective rejoinders.13 These demonstratetheir knowledge of the agreement, the basis of their con-tinuing concerns about it, and good reasons why the pub-lic should be skeptical of the WTO’s assurances.

While critical of the GATS, this analysis is informedby the view that it is important for healthy public debateto try to find more common ground between GATS pro-ponents and critics about the meaning and legal charac-ter of the agreement. Finding recognizable common

Page 25: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

6 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

ground does not preclude strong disagreement about theagreement’s likely impacts, its desirability14 or even con-flicting technical interpretations of GATS provisions. Butthe point of articulating shared understandings, as wellas differing views, is to better enable those now on thesidelines to come to their own informed judgments aboutthis important agreement and its likely impacts.

In fact, while they should be read critically, some ofthe most lucid explanations of the legal character of theGATS have been provided by the WTO Secretariat.15 Butthese mostly date from an earlier era when the GATS wasan obscure agreement almost unknown outside tradepolicy circles. The recent polemics out of Geneva and Parisare the products of a new, more politically charged envi-ronment.16

Occasionally stooping to diatribe, Fact and Fiction mayscore points with the casual or already decided reader,but it is riddled with oversimplification and shallow as-surances. In fact, the WTO Secretariat adopts the sensa-tionalist style it—in many cases falsely—attributes to itscritics. Such ferocity may please some of the GATS stoutestsupporters,17 but it contributes to a deteriorating qualityof public debate and, in time, may deservedly underminethe Secretariat’s own credibility with the public.

The tone of the OECD’s critique, Markets Matter, ismore civil and less confrontational than Fact and Fiction.It acknowledges, for example, that many of the GATS crit-ics’ concerns are “genuine” and “can be seen as warningsto national governments that the terms of the domesticsocial contract should be negotiated at the national—andnot supranational—level.”18 But Markets Matter is also aself-described “advocacy piece,” and condescendinglyattributes most of the critics’ concerns to various “mis-

Page 26: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 7

conceptions” that it sets out, like an impatient schoolmas-ter, to correct.

The GATS is a broadly worded and complex agree-ment. While there have already been several importantGATS-related cases, many of its provisions remain un-tested. Because the agreement itself lacks clarity, how theserules will be applied in any future dispute is, at least tosome extent, a matter of interpretation. But, to GATS crit-ics, this uncertainty is part of the problem: vesting wide-ranging discretion in a remote institution designed pri-marily to benefit foreign commercial interests is one ofthe GATS most serious flaws. On the other hand, thosevested with the power to shape and interpret this broadlyworded treaty are, as one might expect, quite comfort-able wielding it. Its chief beneficiaries, global servicescorporations, can be expected to exploit and defend theadvantages the GATS affords them. Those who are lesslikely to experience direct benefits—but who must nev-ertheless live with the policy consequences of negotiators’and dispute panelists’ decisions—cannot afford to be sosanguine and self-satisfied.

Finally, and critically, in rebutting the WTO’s Secre-tariat’s and the OECD’s critiques, this book will argue thatthe GATS purported protections for public services andgovernments’ ability to regulate in the public interest areunacceptably weak and inadequate.

This book is divided into two sections.• The first section considers the debate over the scope

and coverage of the GATS—that is, what is covered,what is not, and under what conditions?

• The second section deals with the controversy overthe substance of GATS provisions—that is, what is the

Page 27: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

8 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

content and force of GATS provisions and what aretheir policy implications?

The book then concludes by returning to theoverarching themes of the effects of the GATS on publicservices, public interest regulation and, more generally,on democratic governance.

Page 28: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 9

Chapter 2:GATS scope and coverage

One point on which both proponents and critics agree isthat the scope of the GATS is very broad. While the agree-ment’s impacts may be debatable, its breadth is not. Rela-tive to earlier GATT disciplines, which applied primarilyto border measures affecting internationally traded goods,the scope of the GATS is truly immense. This extraordi-nary breadth follows from several factors, including theincredible diversity of services themselves, the architec-ture of the agreement, and the expansive way the GATSdefines key terms such as “measures” and “trade in serv-ices.”

Even in partisan debate, GATS proponents acknowl-edge this breadth. Fact and Fiction, for example, notes “thevery broad scope” of the GATS.19 Where proponents andcritics diverge is that GATS supporters, while acknowl-edging the breadth of the agreement in principle, empha-size that, in practice, the agreement provides governmentswith “remarkable flexibility which allows governments,to a very great extent, to determine the level of obliga-tions they will assume.”20 This flexibility, and its limits,will be discussed in the final part of this section.

First, this section considers the breadth and diversityof services themselves. Then it turns to three of the im-portant “top-down” features of the GATS:• the GATS applies to all government measures;• the GATS covers all means of supplying a service in-

ternationally; and• no services are excluded a priori.

Page 29: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

10 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Next, the book examines the highly controversial ex-clusion for services provided “in the exercise of govern-mental authority” which GATS proponents often—mis-leadingly—suggest provides a blanket exclusion for pub-lic services. Finally, the book will consider the flexibilitythat is provided by the so-called “bottom-up” features ofthe GATS and the significant limits to this flexibility.

The breadth and diversity of services

It is difficult to grasp the full range of services that existin any complex society.21 Delving into one of the compre-hensive classification systems developed under the aus-pices of the United Nations provides invaluable insightinto the myriad of human activities classified as services.22

These range from birth (midwifery) to death (burial), themundane (dry cleaning services) to the sublime (theatreand music), the trivial (shoe-shining) to the critical (heartsurgery), the personal (haircutting) to the social (primaryeducation), low-tech (household help) to high-tech (sat-ellite telecommunications), and from our wants (retailsales of games and toys) to our needs (water distribution).

The subject matter of the GATS—services them-selves—is therefore almost unimaginably broad. As Mar-kets Matter aptly observes, “Services encompass a vast anddisparate array of economic activity, and imply a simi-larly wide scope of issues, institutions and interests.”23

Surprisingly, for a legal document, the GATS does notdefine services.24 Elsewhere, services are often defined notonly by what they are, but by what they are not. Broadlydefined, a service is a product of human activity aimed tosatisfy a human need, which does not constitute a tangi-

Page 30: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 11

ble commodity.25 Or, as some wag put it, a service is anyproduct that “you can’t drop on your foot.”

Even these broad definitions are oversimplifications.In practice, it is very difficult to draw a clear line betweenthe production of goods and services. Services are em-bodied in tangible products, e.g. advertising in a maga-zine, which can be dropped on your foot. This is not apurely theological matter. It means that the WTO ruleson trade in goods and services overlap and that govern-ment measures must conform to both. As the WTO panelthat ruled against Canadian cultural policies designed tosupport indigenous magazines observed: “Overlaps be-tween the subject-matter of disciplines in the GATT 1994and in GATS are inevitable, and will further increase withthe progress of technology and the globalization of eco-nomic activities.”26

To a casual observer, the widely assumed intangibil-ity of services may also suggest an absence of environ-mental or resource impacts. It should not. For example,producing primary commodities such as wood, miner-als, or agricultural products involves many environmen-tally sensitive services. These include silviculture, road-building, drilling, applying pesticides, transportation, andmore. The same holds true of manufacturing, for whichwastes must be disposed of and goods transported tomarkets. Even services such as tourism and retailing must,of course, be carefully managed and planned to minimizeadverse environmental impacts. In short, safeguarding theability to conserve natural resources and to protect theenvironment is as critical in services rule-making as forany other sphere of economic activity.27

Markets Matter attributes the current wave of GATScriticism to the idea that some services are “simply too

Page 31: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

12 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

important to bring within the scope of international traderules.28 There is something to this. Many services are ar-guably too important to submit to rules designed chieflyto expand international commerce and to benefit commer-cial interests. Societies have deliberately insulated manyimportant services from the full brunt of private marketforces. Even after two decades of widespread neo-liberalreform, services such as water, health, and education arestill, in many countries, either heavily regulated or pub-licly provided to ensure greater equity and access—re-gardless of the ability to pay. Many GATS critics regardthe encroachment of international trade treaty restrictionsinto services as part of a broader trend to appropriate theseremaining “global commons” for private profit-making.

The “top-down” features of the GATS

To follow the twists and turns of the GATS debate, it helpsto understand some trade policy jargon. A “bottom-up”agreement refers to one that applies only to those specificgovernment measures and sectors that individual gov-ernments explicitly agree to cover. So, for example, Ja-maica’s tourism sector would only be covered if a Jamai-can government agreed. This is also called a “positive list-ing” approach.

By contrast, “top-down” treaties automatically applyto all measures and sectors unless governments explic-itly exclude them by negotiating them off the table. In thiscase, for example, the French health care sector would becovered unless France successfully negotiated a country-specific exemption to exclude it. This is also known as a“negative listing” or, more graphically, as a “list it or loseit” approach.

Page 32: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 13

The GATS is frequently referred to as a “bottom-up”agreement.29 This characterization is only partly true. Infact, the GATS is a hybrid agreement that combines bothbottom-up and top-down features.

The most significant top-down features of the GATSinclude:• the GATS applies to all government measures;• the GATS covers all means of supplying a service in-

ternationally; and• no services, except those supplied in the exercise of

governmental authority, are excluded a priori.

Each of these is now considered in turn.

The GATS applies to all government measures affecting tradein services.

The GATS scope and coverage is determined by Arti-cle I which states that the “GATS...applies to measures byMembers affecting trade in services (Article I:1).”30 Suchmeasures, or government actions, can take any form in-cluding laws, regulations, administrative decisions, oreven unwritten practices.31 WTO panels and the Appel-late Body have clearly established that “no measures area priori excluded from the scope of application of theGATS.”32

The GATS also applies to measures taken by any levelof government. While negotiated exclusively by nationalgovernments, its restrictions cover measures by “central,regional, or local governments and authorities (GATSArticle I:3.a.i).” This includes provincial, state, municipal,Aboriginal, and all other governments. The GATS alsoapplies to “non-governmental bodies in the exercise ofpowers” delegated by any level of government (GATS

Page 33: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

14 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Article I:3.a.ii). This catches, for example, professionalassociations, standards-setting bodies, and boards of hos-pitals, schools or universities where they exercise author-ity conferred upon them by any level of government.

Moreover, in the EC Bananas case, the panel elabo-rated that in Article I:1, which defines the GATS’ scope:“we note that the ordinary meaning of the term ‘affect-ing,’ in Article I:1 of GATS, does not convey any notion oflimiting the scope of the GATS to certain types of meas-ures or to a certain regulatory domain. On the contrary,Article I:1 refers to measures in terms of their effect, whichmeans that they could be of any type or relate to any domain ofregulation (emphasis added).”33 In other words, no gov-ernment action, whatever its purpose—protecting theenvironment, safeguarding consumers, enforcing labourstandards, promoting fair competition, ensuring univer-sal service, or any other end—is, in principle, beyondGATS scrutiny and potential challenge. Because of thisstunning breadth alone, it is not only legitimate, but vital,for citizens, NGOs, and elected representatives at all lev-els of government to critically examine potential GATSimpacts on an almost unlimited range of public interestmeasures.

The GATS covers all possible means of supplying a serviceinternationally.

A second top-down feature of the GATS is that it ap-plies to every possible means of providing a service in-ternationally. As noted, the GATS “applies to measuresby Members affecting trade in services (Article I:1).” Ifthe GATS applies to any measure that has an effect on“trade in services,” what then does “trade in services”mean?

Page 34: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 15

The GATS defines “trade in services” quite unconven-tionally to include not just cross-border trade—where asupplier located in one country provides a service to aconsumer located in another—but also every possiblemeans of supplying services internationally. The fourGATS “modes of supply” are:• cross-border services trade (mode 1). This mode is

closest to the conventional meaning of internationaltrade, and includes, for example, a consultant locatedin one country giving advice to a client located in an-other country by mail, phone or Internet.

• consumption abroad (mode 2). Examples of this modeinclude tourism or a student travelling abroad to at-tend university.

• commercial presence (mode 3). This mode includesall forms of foreign direct investment; for example, ahealth care company setting up a private clinic, a fast-food chain establishing a franchise, or a bank settingup a branch in another country.

• natural persons (mode 4). This mode covers personstravelling internationally to provide services; for ex-ample, a technician or management personnel physi-cally travelling to another country to provide serv-ices.

Significantly, the GATS covers investment—servicesprovided through commercial presence (mode 3). This factalone greatly expands its coverage relative to previousGATT rules. As the WTO Secretariat observed in a lessguarded era, “This [i.e., mode 3] is probably the mostimportant mode of supply of services, at least in terms offuture development, and also raises the most difficult is-sues for host governments and for GATS negotiations.”34

Page 35: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

16 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Foreign direct investment is present in all nationaleconomies. Indeed, in a globalized economy it is difficultto conceive of a government measure that would not insome way affect some foreign investor providing serv-ices in the host country. As the WTO Secretariat com-mented in 1999, “rules governing commercial presenceare very different from the tariffs and other border meas-ures that principally affect trade in goods. GATT has onlygradually become involved in some sensitive domesticpolicy issues such as subsidies and technical standards.Right from the beginning, however, the GATS has beenforced to grapple with internal policy issues such as rightsof establishment that are inherent in the commercial pres-ence of foreign interests.”35 Because foreign investment ispervasive, almost any government action could fall intothe category of measures affecting “trade in services” asbroadly defined by the GATS.

To avoid any misunderstanding, it should be stressedthat simply because a measure falls within the scope ofthe GATS does not make it GATS-inconsistent—that is,contrary to GATS rules. But, conversely, it is also true thatany regulatory or legislative initiative in any WTO-mem-ber country—including many that have never before beenconsidered trade-related—must now be vetted for GATSconsistency or risk possible challenge.

In fact, the GATS defines “trade in services” so broadlyand unconventionally that it restricts any governmentmeasure that might, even unintentionally, adversely af-fect competitive conditions relating to the supply of a serv-ice through any mode.36 In the WTO Appellate Body’s au-thoritative opinion, “the use of the term ‘affecting’ reflectsthe intent of the drafters to give a broad reach to the GATS.

Page 36: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 17

The ordinary meaning of the word ‘affecting’ implies ameasure that has ‘an effect on,’ which indicates a broadscope of application.”37 This effect of a regulatory or othermeasure on “trade in services” need not be large. In fact,panels have ruled that, if a measure’s adverse effect onthe conditions of competition is minimal or even hypo-thetical, it may nevertheless be found GATS-inconsistent.38

This excessive reach further validates rising globalconcern among non-governmental organizations and oth-ers about the impact of GATS restrictions on a huge rangeof public interest measures and regulation. As a formerdirector-general of the WTO frankly conceded, the GATSis no ordinary trade agreement; it extends “into areasnever before recognized as trade policy.”39

No service sector is excluded a priori:The governmental authority exclusion

A third top-down feature of the GATS is that it covers“any service in any sector except services supplied in theexercise of governmental authority (GATS Article I:3.b).”As Fact and Fiction acknowledges, “the GATS covers allservices with two exceptions—i.e., services provided inthe exercise of governmental authority, and [certain serv-ices] in the air transport sector.”40 Similarly, Markets Mat-ter observes that “the GATS covers in principle interna-tional trade in all services except those supplied in theexercise of governmental authority and [certain aspectsof] the air transport sector.”41

This universal sectoral coverage is critical to the GATS’intended development. This all-inclusive frameworkbinds member governments to certain rules that alreadyapply across all sectors—even those where no specificcommitments have been made. Critically, the GATS uni-

Page 37: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

18 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

versal coverage also means that all sectors are on the ta-ble in ongoing negotiations. Such negotiations to achieveprogressively higher levels of liberalization, mandated inArticle XIX, are part of the agreement’s so-called built-inagenda. The current phase began in February 2000 inGeneva and is now part of the broader WTO round thatwas launched in Doha, Qatar in November 2001. As theguidelines for the current phase of GATS negotiationsstipulate, “There shall be no a priori exclusion of any serv-ice sector or mode of supply.”42

The exclusion for “services provided in the exerciseof governmental authority” is arguably the only signifi-cant carve-out from the GATS’ universal scope. No GATSprovision has been more controversial, at least outsidethe walls of the WTO complex in Geneva. Article I:3, if ithad left governments to define for themselves the serv-ices they provided in their exercise of governmental au-thority, might have been a broad exclusion that preservedgovernments’ flexibility to protect public services fromthe commercializing pressures of the GATS. But, presum-ably anticipating this, negotiators strictly circumscribedit.

The governmental authority exclusion is qualified bytwo criteria, both of which must be satisfied for the exclu-sion to apply. These criteria are that a service 1) must notbe supplied on a “commercial basis”, and 2) must not be“supplied...in competition with one or more service sup-pliers.”43 Neither of these critical criteria is further definedin the GATS text.

Markets Matter maintains that this “provision ‘carvesout’ a potentially wide category of services from the scopeof GATS rules.” It also grudgingly concedes that ArticleI:3 “does not precisely define the scope of this category,

Page 38: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 19

however, a lacuna that some anti-GATS analysts havedrawn attention to and interpreted as having ominousimplications.”44

The precise scope of this exclusion is certainly a criti-cal issue with significant—and quite possibly ominous—public policy implications. All services that do not fitwithin its scope are covered by the GATS. That is, all serv-ices that are supplied either on a commercial basis or incompetition with one or more service suppliers, regard-less of whether they are public or private, are subject toall of the GATS obligations that now apply across-the-board. Where member governments have made specificcommitments, GATS national treatment, monopolies andmarket access rules also apply to committed services—including public services—that are supplied either on acommercial basis or in competition with other servicesuppliers. In addition, these services will also be subjectto any new unconditional obligations, including the con-troversial new restrictions on non-discriminatory domes-tic regulation being negotiated under GATS Article VI.4,that may be adopted in future.

Prominent GATS supporters have confused mattersconsiderably by making categorical, but unsupported, as-surances about the GATS and public services. For exam-ple, in a widely published opinion piece, WTO Director-General Michael Moore baldly asserted that “GATS ex-plicitly excludes services supplied by governments.”45

This is clearly untrue; the statement is at odds with theGATS text. A 1994 analysis by the OECD also directly con-tradicts Moore’s assertion, stating, “A category of serv-ices which is excluded from the coverage of the GATS,are...services supplied in the exercise of government au-thority. This exception is, however, limited: where a Gov-

Page 39: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

20 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

ernment acts on a commercial basis and/or as competi-tor with other suppliers, its activities are treated like thoseof any private supplier.”46

Because the key terms “commercial” and “in compe-tition with” are not defined in the GATS, GATS disputepanels will turn, under applicable international law, tothe ordinary meanings of these words.47 As a recent gov-ernmental analysis points out, “the ordinary definitionsof these terms are broad, making the set of services thatthey describe very large, and the set of services that fallsoutside them—and hence outside the scope of the agree-ment—quite small.”48 Another recent analysis concludesthat a WTO Appellate Body “would be in conformity withinternational law if it adopted a narrow understanding”of the exclusion.49 Indeed, a similar exclusion in the Euro-pean Communities Treaty has been interpreted restric-tively and has failed to exclude the services in disputeevery time it has been tested.50 Moreover, the WTO’s ownCouncil for Trade in Services noted the need for the ex-clusion to be interpreted narrowly.51

In most WTO countries, “public services” are rarelydelivered exclusively by government. Instead, vital pub-lic services are delivered to the population through amixed system that is wholly or partly funded, and tightlyregulated, by governments at the central, regional, andlocal levels. Health, education, and other social servicesystems, for example, consist of a complex, continuallyshifting mix of governmental and private funding. Thesesystems also entail a mixing—or co-existence—in the samesector, of governmental, private, not-for-profit and pri-vate for-profit delivery. To be effective, a GATS exclusionfor these services needs to safeguard governments’ abil-ity to deliver public services through the mix that they

Page 40: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 21

deem appropriate, to shift this mix as required, and toclosely regulate all aspects of these mixed systems.

The GATS exclusion clearly falls well short of thisideal, although by how far remains uncertain. This de-pends on how restrictively it will be interpreted in futureGATS disputes. At best, it would appear that the exclu-sion is narrow and is likely to be interpreted restrictively.At worst, the exclusion may be so narrow as to be of littlepractical significance or, at the extreme, to provide no pro-tection at all.

It is, in fact, difficult to conceive of a “public service”that is unequivocally both non-commercial and not incompetition with any other service supplier. To date, de-spite the controversy surrounding this GATS provision,no one—including the WTO Secretariat and the OECDTrade Directorate—has yet provided a credible exampleof a service that would satisfy the terms of the GATS gov-ernmental authority exclusion.52 Moreover, no matter hownarrow the exclusion is at present, it seems beyond ques-tion that, because of increasing commercialization andcompetition in many countries, its scope is steadily di-minishing.

Unfortunately, far from allaying the critics’ main con-cerns, both Fact and Fiction and Markets Matter stick to thenow-familiar pattern of sidestepping difficult issues whileoffering inappropriate reassurances. Both of these docu-ments implicitly reinforce concerns about the limits of thiscontroversial exclusion. For example, Fact and Fiction ac-knowledges that “Those services which are provided ona commercial or competitive basis are covered by theGATS.”53

Markets Matter briefly considers the possible meaningof the two criteria underlying the governmental author-

Page 41: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

22 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

ity exclusion, although this discussion is not very enlight-ening. With respect to the “competition” criterion, it notes,as have many GATS critics, that “the co-existence of pub-lic and private providers is common to virtually all OECDcountries’ social services sectors, such as health and edu-cation, a condition that pertains also to numerous devel-oping countries.”54

But it goes on to assert that “such co-existence doesnot necessarily mean that they are ‘like services’ nor thatthey are in competition, and therefore does not bring pub-lic services into the purview of the GATS (emphasisadded).”55 This bland assurance is quite misleading. It istrue that the co-existence of public and private serviceproviders does not mean, as a matter of logical necessity,that these providers are in competition with each other.However, the critical point is that such co-existence may,and indeed often does, entail competition—for clients,revenues, concessions, contracts, and scarce public re-sources. And wherever such competition is deemed tooccur56, the public service in question would, by defini-tion, fall outside the governmental authority exclusion and“into the purview of the GATS.”

A normal meaning of competition is “to try to get whatothers also seek.” 57 In this sense, for example, a publicuniversity or community college offering a non-creditcomputer training course could be considered to competefor the same students with private, for-profit universitiesor training institutes offering similar courses. In manycountries, public hospitals could be considered to com-pete with private hospitals for wealthy patients who areprepared to pay for services either out of their own pocketor through private insurance.58 Even public police serv-ices sometimes compete with private security services, for

Page 42: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 23

example, in contracts to provide security for special eventssuch as a rock concert.59 In these and many other similarinstances, if the public institutions enjoy government-pro-vided advantages (e.g. public funding, exclusive degree-granting authority, access to publicly funded facilities,publicly paid staff, research grants, etc.) that are not alsoavailable to their private competitors, GATS conflicts maywell arise.

Markets Matter thus obscures, but never explicitly de-nies, a very important point. GATS dispute panels can beexpected to view the co-existence, in many service sec-tors, of public, private-non-profit and private-for-profitservice providers as involving competition. In these cir-cumstances, the governmental authority exclusion wouldprovide no protection, and the GATS would apply to thepublic services and providers concerned.

With respect to the “commercial” criterion, MarketsMatter asserts that

“It would seem highly implausible to claim thatthe fact that fees might be charged for some gov-ernmental services, e.g., for school enrolments,automatically makes the service supplied ‘on a com-mercial basis’ (emphasis added).”60

Perhaps charging small fees (as some Canadian provincesdo for compulsory medical insurance) would not auto-matically put these services on a commercial footing. But,for example, as university tuition fees rise, at what pointmight they, in GATS terms, put the service on a commer-cial basis?61 As the OECD statement implies, this is a mat-ter of judgment and degree.62

As these examples illustrate, the pertinent issue iswhether “public services” are supplied neither on a com-

Page 43: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

24 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

petitive nor a commercial basis. If one or the other of thesecumulative conditions is not satisfied, then the GATS ap-plies. Governments and citizens should be alert to possi-ble GATS implications and conflicts, not lulled into a falsesense of security by the soothing, but shallow, assertionsof GATS promoters.

Significantly, like many official statements about thegovernmental authority exclusion, both documents sig-nal a willingness on the part of GATS proponents to con-template a “clarification” of the provision. Markets Matteracknowledges that the agreement “does not precisely de-fine the scope of” the exclusion, noting that this issue “isalmost certainly one that Member governments may wishto address in the context of the ongoing set of negotia-tions with a view to providing greater definitional clarityand legal certainty.”63

Such positive signals are a credit to the citizens andNGOs that have persistently raised concerns about theadequacy of the GATS governmental authority exclusion.A new legally binding, authoritative interpretation ofArticle I:3 or, better still, a new GATS exclusion that trulyprotected governments’ flexibility to deliver public serv-ices in the manner they see fit, would be a positive devel-opment.64 This matter is far too important to be left to WTOdispute settlement. As one thoughtful NGO analysis ofthe governmental authority exclusion concludes, thelarger issues about the scope of the agreement “are policyquestions which must be resolved by the governments ofthe WTO members which are accountable to their con-stituencies.”65

But a grimmer scenario is the release of a public state-ment without binding effect that merely repackages theexisting exclusion, with all its faults, in a more publicly

Page 44: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 25

presentable way. In one passage, Markets Matter hints atjust such an approach. Rather than obtaining greater clar-ity and legal certainty,66 it suggests that OECD Membergovernments could merely “clarify” their “intent” and so“go some way towards assuaging some of the concernsexpressed by civil society groups.”67 Such a cynical projectwould simply further obscure the application of the GATStreaty to public services and provide political cover forgovernments that have already made, or are planning tomake, new or more onerous GATS commitments affect-ing critical public services.

Nowhere are GATS proponents on shakier groundthan when they assert that this highly qualified exclusionfully protects public services. This exclusion is, at best,unclear and subject to conflicting interpretations and, atworst, if narrowly interpreted, of little or no practical ef-fect.68

The “bottom-up” features of the GATS

How flexible is the GATS?GATS proponents assert that, notwithstanding its

broad scope, the agreement provides “remarkable flex-ibility” which, according to Fact and Fiction, “allows Gov-ernments, to a very great extent, to determine the level ofobligations they assume.”69 Similarly, Markets Matter ar-gues that “WTO Members are not required under GATSrules to open any specific sector to foreign competition.The Agreement instead features a series of provisions bywhich countries can, if and when they choose, exemptspecific sectors from liberalization, set conditions or lim-its on the nature and pace of any domestically determinedliberalization, or even suspend or modify concessions that

Page 45: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

26 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

they have already made.”70 These arguments refer to the“bottom-up” features of the GATS, those rules which ap-ply only to sectors or sub-sectors where governmentsmake explicit GATS commitments.

This flexibility, and its limits, is another important areaof controversy. Proponents emphasize the opportunitythese bottom-up features give governments to open theirservices markets at their own pace. Critics stress the pres-sure under which governments are put to make furthercommitments and the difficulties they face in changingcourse, once commitments are made. Another point ofcontention is that the proponents stress the ability of gov-ernments, even where they agree to make commitments,to preserve non-conforming measures by listing them asexceptions in their country schedule. Critics point to theformidable practical obstacles to preserving policy flex-ibility through country-specific exceptions. A final con-sideration is that the GATS includes a provision that al-lows governments to withdraw or renegotiate its com-mitments, but they must compensate other GATS mem-bers for doing so.

As will be discussed below, certain GATS obligations,such as the most-favoured nation rule, apply uncondi-tionally across all service sectors. Governments have lit-tle choice in this matter.71 The most forceful GATS obliga-tions, however, including national treatment and marketaccess, apply only to sectors that governments explicitlyagree to cover. Each member government has its ownunique country schedule which lists these “specific com-mitments” on a sector-by-sector basis. These schedulesare an integral, legally binding part of the GATS.

The OECD refers to this as “a highly flexible, a la carteapproach to liberalization under the GATS.”72 The WTO

Page 46: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 27

Secretariat goes even further, declaring that “there is com-plete freedom to choose which services to commit.”73

While GATS scheduling procedures do provide govern-ments with certain flexibility, there are serious limits tothis flexibility that the proponents understate or ignore.

The GATS and power bargainingThe first problem with likening the process of formu-

lating a GATS schedule to casually ordering from amenu—let alone complete freedom—is that it completelyignores negotiating pressure. Such pressure can be intense.For example, at the end of the Uruguay Round in 1994,the U.S. refused to conclude an agreement covering thefinancial services sector because it was dissatisfied withdeveloping countries’ financial services offers. The U.S.refusal resulted in two years of further financial sectornegotiations during which southeast Asian countries inparticular were subjected to powerful pressure to opentheir financial services sectors to U.S. and European in-terests.74 Likewise, countries acceding to the WTO sincethe end of the Uruguay Round have also come understrong pressure on services issues. Haggling over serv-ices commitments was a major factor delaying China’saccession and remains a significant obstacle to Russia’saccession to the WTO.75

In the case of indebted developing countries, there ispressure from other quarters: especially from the Inter-national Monetary Fund and the World Bank, whosestandard policy prescriptions and conditions include pri-vatization of state enterprises, public spending cuts, userfees for basic services, and financial and other servicesliberalization. The functional role of the WTO agreements,and the GATS in particular, in enforcing “the Washington

Page 47: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

28 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Consensus” is to lock in market-oriented policies wher-ever they occur.

Negotiating pressures to make further substantialcommitments will be part and parcel of the GATS 2000negotiations and of future rounds. As previously indi-cated, GATS Article XIX, Progressive Liberalization, en-sures that these successive rounds of negotiation are aimedat achieving “a progressively higher level of liberaliza-tion.” The U.S., Japan and the EC have already made clearthat they intend to push for ambitious levels of liberaliza-tion and the elimination of country-specific limitationson existing coverage.

This pressure can also take forms other than straightpower bargaining. Developed country governments haveactively promoted a variety of negotiating and classifica-tion devices designed to coerce governments into mak-ing broader and deeper GATS commitments than theyotherwise might. These so-called “horizontal negotiatingmodalities” refer to the negotiation of cross-cutting GATScommitments that would apply across members, sectors,and/or modes of supply. Some examples might includerequiring that each government make baseline commit-ments in every sector, that governments make commit-ments that apply to entire clusters of services, or that gov-ernments eliminate certain types of non-conforming meas-ures altogether.76 Despite stiff resistance by developingcountry governments, the GATS 2000 negotiating guide-lines leave the door open to horizontal negotiating ap-proaches.77

Some readers may be surprised to learn that the intel-lectual muscle behind horizontal negotiating approacheshas been provided by the OECD Trade Committee. Whileits document, Markets Matter, now celebrates GATS flex-

Page 48: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 29

ibility, this committee has tirelessly advocated so-called“formula approaches” as tools to reduce this flexibility.Some of the potential formulas suggested by the OECDinclude: obliging “all participants to make initial offers insectors where they presently have no commitments;” that“measures listed in GATS Article XVI (Market Access) bephased out by all participants by a designated date;” andthe “removal of or phase-out of economic needs tests forapproval, quotas on number of firms permitted, and limi-tations on majority foreign ownership as general princi-ples for establishment of new services businesses.”78

The limits of limitationsAnother major problem is that, even if such “complete

freedom” to make specific commitments existed once, itclearly no longer exists. Most governments, especiallythose from developed countries, have already made verysubstantial GATS commitments.79 While a few sensitivesectors such as the health and education services remainrelatively uncommitted, most important service sectorsare already very heavily committed. Although little un-derstood or, until recently, even discussed outside tradeministries, these commitments already bind governments.This status quo, not some pre-Uruguay Round “state ofnature” where governments enjoyed “complete freedomto choose which sectors to commit,” must be the startingpoint of any serious discussion of GATS policy implica-tions.

Markets Matter, for example, suggests that a countrythat wishes to restrict the extent of its GATS commitments,

“might establish a ‘horizontal’ commitment thatapplies to all services. For example, many coun-tries have listed horizontal (i.e., applicable to all

Page 49: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

30 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

sectors) limitations on the commitments for move-ment of persons. (The term ‘commitment’ can bedeceptive in this context, as in practice it oftenmeans across-the-board limitations on market ac-cess and national treatment.)”80

But this option, while possible when initial commitmentswere made in 1994 or when a new member accedes to theWTO, is now practically unworkable. A WTO membergovernment that wanted to add a horizontal limitation toits schedule would be on the hook to provide compensa-tion to foreign governments on behalf of every affectedforeign service provider in every sector that is alreadycommitted.81 To imply that horizontal limitations remaina widely available and viable option to protect policy flex-ibility under the GATS is therefore quite misleading.

GATS proponents further emphasize that, even wheregovernments make commitments, they can exempt oth-erwise non-conforming measures. Fact and Fiction, forexample, states that, “for those services that are commit-ted, Governments may set limitations specifying the levelof market access and the degree of national treatment theyare prepared to guarantee.”82 The GATS certainly permitsgovernments to enter country-specific exceptions in theircountry schedules. But what is left unsaid is that suchlimitations must be scheduled when a government makesits initial commitments. When a member governmentmakes a binding commitment in a specific sector or sub-sector, it has a one-time opportunity to list non-conform-ing measures that it wants to protect. Any non-conform-ing measures that are not listed are lost—that is, they mustbe brought into conformity with GATS rules or risk chal-lenge.

Page 50: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 31

Even where governments recognize in time that apolicy or measure must be protected, the whole exerciseis fraught with difficulty. As a joint civil society responseto Fact and Fiction aptly remarks, protecting “the abilityto regulate depends on governments knowing how, andwhen, to make exceptions and impose limitations whenthey commit sectors to liberalization. This requires anunrealistic level of foresight and capacity.”83

In short, GATS country-specific exceptions:• must be drafted carefully,• will be interpreted narrowly, 84

• usually protect existing measures, not future policyflexibility,

• become targets in ongoing negotiations, and• cannot be changed without compensation.

Moreover, their effectiveness is uncertain, until they aretested in dispute settlement.

Even identifying all potentially non-conforming meas-ures in a sector or sub-sector is enormously difficult. Dur-ing the Uruguay Round, subnational governments, whosemeasures are fully covered, were not adequately consultedabout the GATS in many countries. For example, there isno indication that Canadian federal negotiators directlyconsulted local governments or informed them of theopportunity to exempt potentially non-conforming meas-ures. As a result, there are no purely municipal-level limi-tations in Canada’s GATS schedule.

It is also up to a country’s negotiators to consult withother ministries and levels of government. The quality ofthese consultations, if they even occur, may vary enor-mously. Trade negotiators may not be familiar with the

Page 51: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

32 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

programs of social policy ministries or the preoccupationsof local governments and may thus not fully appreciatethe importance of protecting them in negotiations. Un-derstandably, many trade negotiators often favour ad-vancing export interests over so-called defensive inter-ests. Negotiators tend to be predisposed to resist excep-tions, because every limitation must be paid for with pre-cious negotiating coinage. Finally, negotiators are usuallyreluctant to take a precautionary approach because themere listing of a grey area measure draws attention to itand may raise concerns about similar measures that havenot been similarly protected.

All these difficulties are compounded by the noveltyand the sweeping scope of the GATS and the uncertaintyabout key GATS provisions such as the exclusion for serv-ices provided in the exercise of governmental authority.The frenetic atmosphere at the conclusion of the UruguayRound was not conducive to sober reflection about po-tentially non-conforming measures. Indeed, few peopleoutside of GATS negotiators understood the agreement.There was no phase-in period during which governmentscould consult, reflect, and add to their limitations. Notsurprisingly, country schedules, including limitations, arerife with errors and inconsistencies.

The GATS does not permit governments to later addlimitations for non-conforming measures that may havebeen overlooked, to revise poorly drafted limitations thatdo not provide the protection that was intended, or toprotect measures that governments did not realize, at thetime they made their initial commitments, were exposedto GATS challenge. Nor, critically, does the GATS permitgovernments to schedule future measures in already com-mitted sectors. In all such cases, a government would in

Page 52: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 33

effect be subtracting from its GATS obligations and wouldbe required to provide other affected members “compen-satory adjustment.”85

For these many and varied reasons, country-specificlimitations are, in practice, far less effective safeguardsfor public policy flexibility than advertised by the WTOand the OECD.

Paying to govern: Withdrawing GATS commitmentsThe GATS does provide a means for governments to

withdraw previously made commitments, so long as theyare prepared to compensate other governments whoseservice suppliers are allegedly adversely affected. As bothMarkets Matter and Fact and Fiction highlight, GATS Arti-cle XXI allows countries to modify or withdraw a specificcommitment after three years from the time the initialcommitment is made.

As Markets Matter notes, if this article is invoked, “com-pensation must be provided to other countries.”86 If a ne-gotiated settlement can be reached, such compensationtakes the form of replacing the withdrawn commitmentswith others of equivalent value. But, in the more likelyscenario that a negotiated settlement cannot be reached,the government withdrawing a commitment faces retali-ation in the form of affected foreign governments impos-ing trade penalties of equivalent value. While there is somedissent, the predominant view appears to be that ArticleXXI permits cross-retaliation; retaliatory sanctions neednot be confined to services but could also be applied, toexert maximum pressure, to agricultural or goods trade.87

Article XXI is a potentially important provision; itwould be imprudent for non-governmental critics of theGATS to discount it. No member government has yet in-

Page 53: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

34 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

voked this feature, but some may well avail themselvesof this provision in future. But, by the same token, GATSproponents should frankly acknowledge that Article XXIis designed to make it difficult to use. In fact, the WTOdescribed this GATS provision much more frankly andaccurately in 1999, when it stated that, “because unbindingis difficult, the commitments are virtually guaranteedconditions for foreign exporters and importers of serv-ices and investors in the sector to do business.”88

Trade negotiators are quite comfortable with the no-tion that governments must pay if they want to lessen orwithdraw previous commitments. This concept originatedin the notion of bound tariffs on goods. GATT membersnegotiated bound tariff rates, agreeing that, if they wereever raised higher than the bound rate that equivalentcompensation—in the form of lower tariffs on some othergoods—would be forthcoming.

Arguably, this arrangement worked well enoughwhen confined to tariffs and tariff rates. When transposedto the GATS, however, the very notion of bound commit-ments is quite problematic. The scope of the GATS is notconfined to a well-defined set of government measuressuch as tariffs. In fact, as we have seen, its scope is, inprinciple, very broad, restricting an almost unlimitedrange of measures, many of which independent observ-ers would not readily agree were trade-related.

To take one example: suppose a government is electedon a pledge to implement public automobile insurance.If, as typically would be the case, some private insurersthat would be affected are foreign-owned, the new gov-ernment could find itself challenged under the GATS ruleson government monopolies (if a previous government hadmade commitments in the insurance sector). Previously,

Page 54: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 35

insurance providers would have considered the possibil-ity of such a democratic policy change a commercial riskto be borne by all providers, domestic or foreign.89 Be-cause of the expanding reach of the new generation ofinternational commercial treaties such as the GATS, how-ever, such domestic policy choices have been transformedinto international treaty issues. Only a government de-termined enough to negotiate GATS compensation andto face potential retaliation would proceed. The very pros-pect of compensation might even be enough to tip thebalance against fulfilling such a promise. In this impor-tant sense, the transposition of the practice of bound com-mitments from tariffs to a vast new range of public poli-cies and measures diminishes democratic choice.

No doubt many in the corporate and trade policy com-munity believe that limiting democratic flexibility in thisway is a good thing. If so, they should make their casemore openly instead of resorting to platitudes about thepurported benefits of increased services trade. Many citi-zens, quite legitimately, will not be persuaded. In reality,the GATS is more of a governance agreement than a tradeagreement. One suspects that, as more people realize howtenuously related to international trade are many of thematters now restricted by so-called “trade treaties” suchas the GATS, dissent will grow.

The GATS general exceptions

For all the supporters’ emphasis on the GATS flexibility,the agreement contains just two general exceptions towhich governments can turn to try to save otherwise non-conforming measures. The first of these, and the mostimportant from a public interest regulatory perspective,

Page 55: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

36 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

is GATS Article XIV, General Exceptions, which is mod-elled on the GATT Article XX. The second is Article XIVbis,a far stronger exception for essential security interests thatis fashioned after GATT Article XXI, Security Exceptions.

Markets Matter inappropriately blends, or conflates,these two fundamentally different general exceptions,creating a false picture of the protection afforded for pub-lic interest measures. To deflect NGO concerns, it assertsthat “A country can take advantage of the various gen-eral exceptions to justify existing regulations, or to enactnew ones in pursuit of legitimate public policy concerns.Such exceptions can be invoked where governments deemit necessary to protect major public interests, includingsafety, human, plant or animal life or health, national se-curity, or public morals (emphasis added).”90

This passage suggests to an unwary reader that, if agovernment deems a measure necessary, then it is ex-empted.91 But this is true only of the Article XIVbis na-tional security exception, which provides that nothing inthe GATS shall be construed to prevent “any Member fromtaking any action which it considers necessary for the pro-tection of its essential security interests (GATS ArticleXIVbis, emphasis added).” This powerful exception is“self-judging,” testifying that, when governments attacha high priority to protecting important interests, theirnegotiators can craft highly effective exceptions.

Unfortunately, the cover provided by Article XIV forother vital public interest measures is far, far weaker.Unlike the national security exception, Article XIV is notself-judging. To successfully invoke this exception, de-fendant governments bear the burden of demonstratingthat a challenged measure is aimed at one of the specificlegitimate objectives listed in Article XIV, that it satisfies

Page 56: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 37

the qualifying language of the specific exception invoked,and that it meets the conditions in the introductory cha-peau of Article XIV that the measure is neither “arbitraryor unjustifiable discrimination” nor a “disguised restric-tion on trade in services.”92

These are formidable hurdles. While the general ex-ceptions under GATS article XIV have not been invokedyet in any WTO dispute, there is little reason to be opti-mistic that they will protect public interest measures fromsuccessful challenge. To date, the dispute settlement sys-tem of the WTO (and before it of the GATT) has inter-preted the similar language in GATT Article XX very re-strictively. Under the necessity test that has been devel-oped in Article XX interpretation, the government invok-ing the GATT exception must demonstrate that no alter-native, consistent measure was reasonably available to it,and, that, if all available measures were inconsistent, thatthey chose the least trade restrictive measure. Since, inthe abstract without reference to real-world costs or po-litical realities, there is usually an alternative less traderestrictive means available, this strict interpretation hasrendered Article XX ineffective as an exclusion.93

But there is another important concern: in certain cru-cial important respects, the GATS Article XIV general ex-ception has been crafted even more narrowly than GATTArticle XX. The wording of the chapeau contains the samereferences to arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination anddisguised restriction to trade found in GATT Article XX.There is little doubt that it will be interpreted in the samestringent manner as Article XX. But the list of permittedlegitimate objectives in Article XIV is considerably shorterthan that in Article XX.94

Page 57: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

38 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Subject to the provisos in the chapeau, the first twoclauses of Article XIV permit a defendant government tosave otherwise GATS-inconsistent measures if it can dem-onstrate that these are “necessary to protect public mor-als or to maintain public order” or are “necessary to pro-tect human, animal or plant life or health.” Significantly,GATS Article XIV omits the GATT Article XX reference tomeasures “related to the conservation of exhaustible natu-ral resources.” This omission is glaring and obviously de-liberate. It suggests that the grounds to defend environ-mental protection and conservation measures are evennarrower under the GATS than under the already desul-tory record of GATT Article XX. Otherwise inconsistentenvironmental protection measures would have to be ar-gued to fall under Article XIV(b), measures “necessary toprotect human, animal or plant life and health.” This omis-sion could prove highly problematic, especially given thebroad interpretation of GATS as covering measures aimedprimarily at goods (e.g., natural resources), but affectingservices.95

The third clause in GATS Article XIV contains newreferences to measures necessary to prevent deceptive andfraudulent practices, for the protection of personal pri-vacy, confidentiality of data, and consumer safety. Theseare all vital grounds for regulation, especially in the areaof services. But this clause refers only to measures “nec-essary to ensure compliance with laws and regulationsthat are not inconsistent with the GATS.” This extraordi-nary qualification neuters the effectiveness of the excep-tion for important consumer protection laws and regula-tions that themselves could be challenged under theGATS. In this respect, it hardly qualifies as an exceptionat all.96

Page 58: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 39

The final clauses under Article XIV shelter differen-tial treatment “aimed at ensuring the equitable or effec-tive imposition or collection of direct taxes” from the GATSnational treatment article and differential treatment thatresults from agreements on the avoidance of double taxa-tion from the GATS MFN article. These attest to the bu-reaucratic clout of finance ministries in international tradenegotiations. GATS critics can only wish that social serv-ice, health and environmental protection advocateswielded similar influence.

In short, the national security exception is the onlyGATS general exception that can be firmly relied upon.The GATS Article XIV exception is even narrower than inits moribund GATT counterpart, notwithstanding the farbroader scope—and political sensitivity—of GATS cov-erage. It is very troubling that the GATS general excep-tion is so weak. Amending it to provide for a more com-prehensive list of legitimate objectives and breathing newlife into its interpretation so that it provides greater pro-tection for public interest regulation should be a high pri-ority.

General exceptions to protect legitimate objectives area critical feature of any trade treaty. They are a perma-nent part of the agreement that can only be changed byamending the agreement. By contrast, the limitations dis-cussed earlier are a form of reservation—mere country-specific exceptions that can be eliminated unilaterally byany future government. And, as a practical matter, onceremoved, they are gone forever.

As Markets Matter notes, it is possible that such limi-tations can be maintained indefinitely. But the GATS isdesigned to create pressure to remove them over time.This is not only a function of the built-in negotiations that

Page 59: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

40 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

are aimed at broadening and deepening GATS coverage.It is also a function of the interplay between the GATSand the normal ebb and flow of democratic policy-mak-ing.

On matters where there is a broad multipartisan con-sensus to insulate certain national policies from theGATS—for example, as appears to exist for French cul-tural policy—it is conceivable that the limitations will re-main in place a very long time. But in societies where thereare serious ideological divisions on contentious issues,such as the role of private, for-profit provision of healthcare and education, the country-specific limitations thatprotect policy flexibility in these sectors are very likely todisappear over time. All it takes is the unilateral decree ofa single government committed to a market-oriented ap-proach to eliminate them. This insidious bias interferesgreatly with the normal ebb and flow of policy-makingin a democratic society. All future governments, whatevertheir policy orientation, will be bound by this decisionand the full force of GATS provisions.

It is to the policy implications of these GATS provi-sions that the book now turns.

Page 60: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 41

Chapter 3:GATS policy implications

In their account of the GATS, both Fact and Fiction andMarkets Matter put so much emphasis on the treaty’s flex-ibility that the agreement’s exceptions appear almost toeclipse its rules. Obviously, rules and exceptions must beread together. The previous section of this book exploredthe limits of this GATS flexibility. This section focuses onthe powerful GATS rules themselves and their seriouspolicy implications. It deals with the controversy overGATS substantive provisions—that is, what is the con-tent and force of GATS provisions and what are their po-tential public policy implications? First, it discusses thereference to the “right to regulate” in the GATS pream-ble, which GATS defenders continually suggest protectspublic interest regulation from GATS challenge. It thenanalyzes the policy implications of the most importantGATS unconditional obligation, the most favoured nationtreatment rule. This section then turns to the two power-ful GATS conditional obligations, national treatment andmarket access, which apply only where governments havemade specific commitments. Finally, it discusses the GATSprovisions restricting monopolies and exclusive servicesuppliers and the highly controversial GATS negotiationsto develop new restrictions on non-discriminatory domes-tic regulation.

The right to regulate in the GATS preamble

A common refrain in every official rejoinder to GATS crit-ics is that the GATS specifically recognizes governments’

Page 61: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

42 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

right to regulate.97 Both Fact and Fiction and Markets Mat-ter take up this theme in virtually the same terms. Mar-kets Matter states that: “The Agreement specifically rec-ognizes the right of Members to regulate, and to intro-duce new regulations, on the supply of services withintheir territories in order to meet national policy objec-tives.”98 Fact and Fiction asserts that: “The right to regu-late is one of the fundamental premises of the GATS. Theobjective of the GATS is to liberalize services trade, not toderegulate services, many of which are closely regulatedfor very good reasons. The GATS specifically recognizes‘the right of Members to regulate, and to introduce newregulations, on the supply of services within their territo-ries in order to meet national policy objectives.’” 99

These assurances, while textually based, are decep-tive. The reference to the right to regulate occurs in theGATS preamble. It recognizes “the right of Members toregulate, and to introduce new regulations, on the sup-ply of services within their territories in order to meetnational policy objectives.…”100 This recital was also re-peated in the Doha Ministerial Declaration.101

But, as the WTO and OECD authors are well aware,the GATS preamble has strictly limited legal effect.102 Af-firming the right to regulate in the preamble has someinterpretive value that it would be wrong to discount en-tirely. But this preambular reference cannot be construedas excusing government regulation from conforming tothe GATS. Regulations are clearly listed among the widerange of government measures restricted by the GATS.103

Regulatory measures, whatever their form or purpose,must conform with the GATS provisions in the main textand a member’s specific commitments.

Page 62: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 43

A 1999 publication by the WTO Secretariat puts “theright to regulate” in better context: “The GATS expresslyrecognizes the right of members to regulate the supply ofservices in pursuit of their own policy objectives, and doesnot seek to influence those objectives. Rather, the GATSestablishes a framework of rules and disciplines to en-sure that Members regulate their services sector in a man-ner which avoids that any ensuing trade restrictions anddistortions are more burdensome than necessary.”104 Laterin the same document, the WTO expresses this relation-ship even more plainly: “Governments are free in princi-ple to pursue any national policy objectives provided therelevant measures are compatible with the GATS (emphasisadded).”105

Dispute panels and the Appellate Body should takethe preamble of the GATS into account when interpret-ing the particular provisions of the GATS. But, as theAppellate Body, citing the Vienna Convention, has repeat-edly stated, “a treaty interpreter must begin with, andfocus upon, the text of the particular provision to be in-terpreted. It is in the words constituting that provision,read in their context, that the object and purpose of thestates parties to the treaty must first be sought.”106 Forexample, where the meaning of a particular GATS provi-sion is unclear, the preamble may provide “colour, tex-ture and shading to the rights and obligations of Mem-bers” under the main provisions of the Agreement.107

But the preamble does not create enforceable rightsor obligations. Rather it provides the context in which theoperative provisions (the rights and obligations of theGATS) should be interpreted.108 In other words, thepreambular reference to the right to regulate does not

Page 63: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

44 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

provide legal cover for regulations that are otherwise in-consistent with GATS provisions.

Moreover, the affirmation of the right to regulate isonly one of the objectives enumerated in the GATS pre-amble. The preamble also recognizes “the growing im-portance of trade in services for the growth and develop-ment of the world economy,” and that the GATS aims “toestablish a multilateral framework of principles and rulesfor trade in services with a view to the expansion of suchtrade under conditions of transparency and progressiveliberalization.”109 There is no hierarchy established amongthese recitals, leaving panels and the Appellate Body con-siderable discretion in the balancing of possibly compet-ing objectives in any specific case.

In short, affirming the right to regulate in the pream-ble may give WTO panels or the Appellate Body someleeway to defer to legitimate government regulation in adifficult interpretive matter. But it is ludicrous and terri-bly misleading to imply that the mere affirmation of theright to regulate in the GATS preamble fully protects theright to regulate. Government regulations, whatever theiraim or purpose, must conform with a member govern-ment’s GATS obligations and commitments. If they donot, they can be challenged and found inconsistent. As amatter of fact, the GATS legally qualifies and restricts gov-ernments’ ability to regulate.

Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment (Article II)

The GATS contains a number of general rules that applyto all members and, for the most part, to all services.110

These include transparency and most-favoured nation.111

There is little debate that the most important of these cross-

Page 64: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 45

cutting obligations is GATS Article II, Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment. Fact and Fiction, for example, acknowl-edges that: “The Agreement contains a number of gen-eral obligations applicable to all services, the most im-portant of which is the MFN rule.”112

But, despite its acknowledged importance, MFN is dis-cussed only briefly in both the WTO and OECD tracts.Any binding trade treaty provision that applies univer-sally and unconditionally merits far more serious exami-nation. While MFN is a long-established principle gov-erning tariff rates on goods, transposing it to the farbroader realm of “trade in services,” including investmentmatters, is quite problematic.

In the limited number of GATS-related disputes todate, MFN has proven to be a surprisingly powerful obli-gation. In the EC Bananas case, the Europeans were caughtunawares when the U.S. and a group of Latin Americancountries successfully challenged the EC regime favour-ing bananas imported from its former colonies. The EChad secured a GATT waiver for this preferential regime,but it was unexpectedly ruled inconsistent with GATSrules, including MFN. Likewise, the Canadian govern-ment was caught flatfooted when a WTO panel ruled thatCanada’s Auto Pact violated the GATS MFN obligation.113

Basically, the MFN provision states that the best treat-ment given to any foreign service or service provider mustbe extended to all like foreign services and service pro-viders—“favour one, favour all.”114 When concerns are ex-pressed about the policy implications of MFN, trade offi-cials sometimes react with surprise. They point out thatMFN allows countries to be “trade restrictive,” as long asthey treat all foreign services and service providers con-sistently. Why, they ask, would a government ever wish

Page 65: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

46 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

to discriminate between, say, a Swedish and a Japaneseservice provider? This reaction, however sincere, missesan important point. MFN is better understood as a most-favoured-foreign company rule.115

In effect, MFN requires that any regulatory or fund-ing advantage gained by a single foreign commercial pro-vider must be extended, immediately and uncondition-ally, to all. MFN rights, which apply to all services exceptthose “provided in the exercise of governmental author-ity,” therefore helps to consolidate commercializationwherever it occurs. For example, if a single foreign-owned,for-profit clinic gains the right to perform surgical proce-dures that require overnight stays, then the same rightmust be extended to all foreign-owned clinics on the sameterms. Or if a single foreign commercial education pro-vider gains degree-granting authority or access to publicsubsidies, then all others are entitled to degree-grantingauthority and subsidies on the same terms.

MFN treatment, as Markets Matter accurately observes,“does not entail any specific degree of market open-ness.”116 But even where governments retain the right toreverse the commercialization of services—that is, wherethey have not made any specific market access commit-ments—they are confronted with the opposition of notone, but many, foreign service providers if they try to doso. As a practical matter, MFN rights make it consider-ably more difficult for governments to retreat from theprevious high-water mark of commercialization.

Although it is still largely untested in dispute settle-ment, Article II has been interpreted forcefully in twoGATS-related cases to date. These unexpected rulings inthe EC Bananas and Canada Autos cases starkly under-line more limits to the GATS vaunted flexibility. When

Page 66: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 47

the GATS entered into force in 1994, member governmentshad a one-time opportunity to take exceptions to the uni-versally applicable MFN rule. But a government canhardly protect itself against a threat that it did not under-stand existed.

In 1999, a senior WTO services official acknowledgedthat in the bananas case “both the panel and the Appel-late Body endorsed a broader view of the MFN principle,covering cases of both de jure and de facto discrimina-tion, than hitherto used by the defendant (European Com-munities) and, possibly, other WTO members as well.” 117

Both European and Canadian trade officials were caughtunawares by the expansive interpretation of MFN.

Clearly, if either government had understood thatthere was a possible conflict, they would have negotiatedan MFN exception for these important policies. The Eu-ropeans made the effort to negotiate a GATT waiver fortheir bananas regime. As recently as 1998, the Canadiangovernment, after a comprehensive government reviewinvolving all stakeholders, reaffirmed the Auto Pact asan important benefit to Canada. But, by the time thesegovernments realized their mistake, it was too late to pro-tect their policies. Such unanticipated results raise seri-ous issues about the legitimacy of a treaty whose provi-sions are so broadly worded that its full implications arenot understood—even by those who negotiated it.

This is not the place for a full assessment of MFN, butsuch a discussion is clearly needed. Universal coverageshould have triggered far more caution. Basically, anymeasure of any WTO member government that affectsthe production, sale, distribution, or import of any serv-ice in any sector must not result in discriminatory treat-ment between like foreign services or foreign service pro-

Page 67: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

48 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

viders. This is the sort of top-down edict that might makeeven the most zealous central planner blush.

MFN, while it does not legally preclude doing so, cer-tainly makes reversing any foothold gained by a foreigncommercial service provider more difficult. MFN ensuresthat any advantage granted to, or wrested by, any singleforeign service provider must immediately and uncondi-tionally be extended to all. This results in “piling on.” Ad-vantages gained by any single foreign service provider,even in controversial sectors such as health, education,social services, water, and energy—all of which are cov-ered by MFN—must be extended to all on the same terms.A government that intends to reverse commercializationwould no longer face opposition from just a single foreignservice provider. Instead, it would confront a far morepolitically powerful bloc of many foreign serviceproviders, all of whom have a stake in preventing thechange in public policy from taking place.

National Treatment (Article XVII)

The hard core of the GATS is comprised of those restric-tions that apply only to the sectors, or sub-sectors, wheregovernments have made express commitments. Thesespecific commitments, along with any country-specificlimitations, are listed in each member government’s GATSschedule. The country schedules are an integral part ofthe GATS.

The foremost of these conditional rules is nationaltreatment. The GATS national treatment rule, Article XVII,requires that governments extend the best treatment givento domestic services or service providers to like foreignservices or service providers.

Page 68: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 49

National treatment is a long-standing principle intrade in goods, where it has generally meant that onceimported goods clear the border and enter a country theymust be treated no differently than domestically producedgoods. Under the GATT, countries could control importsthrough tariffs and other measures, but once foreign goodsentered the country they had to be treated the same asany other. National treatment is not a commitment to har-monize. Countries are able to adopt differing regulatorypolicies or standards, as long as these do not discriminatebetween domestic and foreign goods.118

Nevertheless, the national treatment rule is quite in-trusive. The GATS adopts a very tough test of de factonon-discrimination. Measures which on their face are im-partial can still be found inconsistent if they “modify theconditions of competition in favour of domestic servicesor service providers.”119 Moreover, a measure that treatsforeign services supplied from within a member’s terri-tory without discrimination can still be found GATS-in-consistent if it disadvantages service providers locatedoutside the territory that could supply services throughanother committed mode. Finally, panels have interpretedthese obligations so strictly that a measure need only becapable of adversely affecting a foreign service supplier.That is, even if a measure has no actual effect on “trade-in-services,” it can be ruled GATS-inconsistent if, in thepanel’s view, it is merely capable of doing so.120

These strict tests give panels wide latitude to findmeasures GATS-illegal even when they are, on their face,non-discriminatory. While domestic courts typically strainto defer to legislators, WTO panels sometimes seem torelish rebuking them. For example, there is no trace ofindecision or irony in the WTO panel decision that ruled

Page 69: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

50 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

that the Auto Pact, arguably Canada’s most successfulindustrial policy ever, was GATS-inconsistent even thoughthe panel acknowledged that the policy likely had no ac-tual effect on trade in services.121

Both Fact and Fiction and Markets Matter devote somuch effort to extolling GATS exceptions that it is worthconsidering some examples of GATS-inconsistent meas-ures. There are many useful policy instruments that areoutright inconsistent with GATS national treatment. Theseinclude:• adjustment programs that target assistance to compa-

nies set up by dislocated timber workers;• assistance targeted to economic development corpo-

rations controlled by directors chosen from and ac-countable to the local community;

• programs that favour enterprises owned or control-led by indigenous peoples;

• restrictions on non-resident ownership of farm land;• programs that direct research and development sub-

sidies to locals or nationals;• technology transfer requirements;• requirements that skilled foreign employees provide

training to locals; and• requirements that publicly-funded research and de-

velopment produce benefits in the local or nationaleconomy.122

Not everyone would agree that such measures are pro-tectionist, or inappropriately so. But, where GATS com-mitments are made, all such measures must be scheduledas limitations in order to be protected from possible GATSchallenge. Nor can new measures of these types beadopted.

Page 70: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 51

Because of the extraordinary toughness and scope ofGATS national treatment criteria, there may be many otherless obvious conflicts with important public policy meas-ures. Many government regulations and programs alterthe conditions of competition, often as an unintendedconsequence of other policy goals. Some examples ofmeasures that arguably modify the conditions of compe-tition in favour of domestic services or service suppliersinclude:• Government subsidies offered exclusively to non-

profit child care providers could be argued to consti-tute de facto discrimination where most private, for-profit child care providers were foreign-owned whilemost not-for-profit child care providers were local.

• Requirements that grants to social service providers—for example, of services to the physically or mentallydisabled—go first to those with the support of localor regional organizations representing the clientgroup.

• Requirements that retailers recycle packaging couldbe argued to constitute de facto discrimination if theimpact on cross-border, mail-order retailers weredeemed more burdensome than the impact on domes-tic retailers selling through local outlets.

• Government subsidies or other advantages directedexclusively to small business could constitute de factodiscrimination in sectors where most small businessesare locally owned and large businesses are foreign.

• Requirements that, to operate in lucrative urban ar-eas, courier service providers must have counter serv-ice or depots in rural areas, or poor urbanneighborhoods could be construed as favouring na-

Page 71: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

52 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

tional postal administrations which already have adense network of service outlets covering all areas.

• Requirements that toxic waste be treated on-site or ata local facility could be argued to disadvantage for-eign industries or foreign waste treatment companiesthat have invested in facilities outside the local region.

Perhaps not all such challenges will materialize, or suc-ceed, but many more can be imagined. The GATS strongde facto standard of non-discrimination opens the doorsfor multinational companies, aggressive trade lawyers,or foreign trade ministries to frustrate a wide variety offormally non-discriminatory policies that foreign corpo-rations may oppose for reasons that are unrelated to in-ternational trade. This is another reason why the GATS isbetter understood as a governance agreement than a tradeagreement.123

Market Access (Article XVI)

Article XVI, Market Access, is one of the GATS most novel,and troublesome, provisions. In principle, national treat-ment is a relative restriction that allows each membergovernment to adopt the policy it chooses (even if thosediffer from other members) so long as the measure is notdiscriminatory in law or in effect. By contrast, the GATSmarket access provisions preclude certain types of poli-cies, whether they are discriminatory or not.

GATS Article XVI prohibits six types of mostly non-discriminatory measures. In sectors where specific com-mitments are made, there must be no limits on, for exam-ple:• the number of service suppliers,

Page 72: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 53

• the value of service transactions,• the number of service operations, or• the number of natural persons that may be employed

in a sector.

Such limits are prohibited, whether expressed “in theform of numerical quotas, or the requirements of an eco-nomic needs test.”124 Article XVI also prohibits restrictionson types of legal entities through which suppliers maysupply a service and limits on foreign capital participa-tion. Governments “shall not maintain or adopt” any ofthese quantitative restrictions “either on the basis of a re-gional subdivision or on the basis of its entire territory.”125

There is nothing quite like GATS Article XVI in otherinternational commercial treaties. The NAFTA serviceschapter, for example, simply requires federal governmentsto list non-discriminatory quantitative restrictions on thenumber of service providers or the operations of serviceproviders in an annex. But this list is merely for transpar-ency purposes.126

Reading Fact and Fiction’s account of the GATS mar-ket access provisions, it is easy to lose sight of their im-port.127 Through a subtle change in emphasis, Fact and Fic-tion minimizes the impact of Article XVI, stating that,

“If commitments are made, they can be subject tothe six types of limitations specified in the agree-ment, which include, besides quantitative limits,restrictions on the share of foreign capital and onthe type of legal entity permitted.”

But Article XVI is not permission to employ these sixtypes of limitations. Rather, it prohibits them unless they

Page 73: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

54 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

are specifically exempted in a member’s country sched-ule.

As the WTO Secretariat states more plainly elsewhere,“Measures restricting market access and national treat-ment are prohibited, unless scheduled, in sectors wherespecific commitments have been undertaken.…”128 A gov-ernment can maintain otherwise inconsistent measuresonly if it inscribes them in its country schedule when itmakes its specific commitments.129

From a public policy perspective, one of the biggestproblems with Article XVI is that it is framed in absolute,not relative terms. As the WTO Secretariat emphasized in1999 in its proposed revisions to GATS scheduling guide-lines, “Another confusion that sometimes arises is the ideathat only discriminatory measures should be scheduledunder Article XVI. This is not the case. Article XVI coversall measures that fall within the six categories listed,whether they are discriminatory or not.”130

“For instance,” the Secretariat analysis continues, “ifa limitation on the types of legal entity permitted in a givensector is applied to both nationals and foreigners, it hasto be scheduled.”131 What are the policy implications ofprohibiting non-discriminatory restrictions on the typesof legal entities permitted to provide services in sched-uled sectors? For example, many governments restrict theprivate delivery of certain social services, such as childcare, care for the elderly, or support for the physically ormentally challenged, to non-profit agencies. In the edu-cation sector, many governments restrict degree-grantingauthority to public or private educational institutions le-gally constituted as non-profit entities. In many countriesor regions, the provision of certain basic services such as

Page 74: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 55

rail transportation, water distribution, or energy trans-mission is confined to private, not-for-profit providers.

Such public policies certainly restrict the market ac-cess of commercial providers, whether domestic or for-eign. But they are non-discriminatory and have neverbefore been subject to binding international trade treatyobligations. Nor should they be. But now, whether thiswas intended or not, they are exposed to GATS challenge.Asserting that governments could protect such inconsist-ent measures by listing them as country-specific excep-tions is completely unsatisfactory. Governments also needthe flexibility to adopt new measures to meet changingneeds and circumstances. Such public policies are onlytenuously related to trade, and their prohibition has noplace in an international trade treaty.

If the intent of negotiators was simply to address spe-cific market access issues such as, for example, China’slimits on the number of foreign insurance providers orU.S. restrictions on foreign bank branches, these couldreadily be dealt with through specific understandings in-scribed as additional commitments. Instead, by devisinggeneral rules, framed in absolute terms, the GATS hascreated a host of policy problems. It also betrays its spon-sors’ characteristic animus towards public policy preroga-tives and flexibility.

Fact and Fiction engages substantively, although cur-sorily, on an important public policy issue related to Arti-cle XVI. Many NGO critics have raised concerns that lim-its on the number of service providers put in place forconservation or environmental protection purposes couldbe exposed to GATS challenges. The Secretariat dismissesthese concerns as “absurd,” stating that:

Page 75: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

56 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

“even...where no limitation has been scheduled,it is absurd to suggest that a Government or localauthority would have to set aside planning rulesbecause a foreign company wanted to open a ho-tel, set up a golf course or expand a waste dump.These are questions of domestic regulation, notmarket access, and foreign suppliers operating onthe basis of a market-access commitment are sub-ject to exactly the same domestic regulations asnational suppliers; they have no right to exemptionfrom planning or zoning rules, or any other kind ofregulation (emphasis added).”132

This carefully worded response implies that, if plan-ning limitations were to become a GATS issue, it wouldbe under Article VI, Domestic Regulation. But it also in-sists that there is no inconsistency with Article XVI.

These categorical assurances about Article XVI mustbe treated skeptically. As North Americans have learnedunder NAFTA’s investment chapter, when internationalinvestment and services treaty obligations are framed inabsolute terms they can lead to disturbing, sometimesabsurd, public policy results. Despite emphatic official as-surances to the contrary, foreign investors have employedthe NAFTA investment chapter to argue that non-discrimi-natory planning measures, permits, and product bans areNAFTA-illegal.133 Concerns that the blunt wording of Ar-ticle XVI which, like the most contentious articles inNAFTA’s investment chapter, is also framed in absoluteterms,134 may also interfere with environmental and re-source conservation policies are well-founded and needto be addressed.

Page 76: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 57

There is nothing in the plain language of Article XVIto suggest that numerical limits justified by physical ornatural limits, such as resource conservation or environ-mental carrying capacity, would be treated any differentlythan other numerical limits—limits that are clearly pro-hibited. Restrictions on beach front developments, limitson the numbers of fishing licenses, even anti-pollutionprovisions restricting new sources of pollution in de-graded air or water sheds, are all “limitations on thenumber of service suppliers.”

To take a specific example, at a GATS briefing in Ot-tawa in May 2000, a senior WTO services official con-firmed that new restrictions on the number of whale-watching operators, applied for conservation reasons,could violate Canada’s existing commitments in tourism.Canada’s existing commitments in tourism are unboundand there is no limitation that would provide legal coverfor numerical limits on whale-watching operators, a rela-tively new service industry. During a subsequent meet-ing in Geneva, the same official insisted that “there wasabsolutely no legal doubt” that limits applied for legiti-mate resource conservation purposes were consistent withGATS Article XVI. The official did offer that this legal pointcould perhaps be made more explicit through an inter-pretive clarification to Article XVI.135

A legally effective interpretive note stating that Arti-cle XVI does not interfere with governments’ ability toapply limits for conservation reasons would be a welcomedevelopment. Perhaps, with political will, this is one ofthe critics’ concerns that can be satisfactorily addressed.A straightforward step would be to ensure that ArticleXVI only applies to quantitative restrictions that discrimi-nate against foreign investors or service providers.

Page 77: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

58 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

But such an exercise would certainly bring some vex-ing issues to the fore.136 Who is to decide whether limitsapplied for conservation purposes are “objective, timely,transparent and non-discriminatory?” Judgments aboutthe appropriate level of development are complex andinescapably qualitative; they involve aesthetic, economic,scientific and other criteria. So are decisions about theappropriate rate of exploitation of non-renewable re-sources. Canadians know well that such decisions, forexample about the appropriate number of tourist estab-lishments in a wilderness area, can trigger fierce debateand strongly divergent political and scientific views.

Moreover, restrictions on development may also com-mercially advantage incumbents, those already estab-lished within a sector or region, to the detriment of out-siders or new entrants. These incumbents may supportlimits on new entrants for purely self-interested reasons.But these undeniably narrow self-interests should not beconstrued as negating the legitimate conservation impera-tives expressed by the broader community.

Rather, these unavoidably mixed motives, trade-offsand judgments are political decisions properly madedemocratically by the governments and communities di-rectly concerned. On such vital matters, commercial trea-ties should defer to democratically elected governments,not entangle these decisions in international trade law andpossible second-guessing by WTO dispute panels.

Monopolies and exclusive service suppliers(Article VIII)

GATS Article VIII, Monopolies and Exclusive Service Sup-pliers, is one of the GATS general obligations that applies

Page 78: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 59

in principle across all sectors. But in fact only certain as-pects of Article VIII apply generally to all services. Otheraspects of Article VIII are triggered only where servicesare listed. In other words, the GATS restrictions on mo-nopolies are hybrid provisions that combine both uncon-ditional and conditional obligations.137

These obligations include:• Article VIII.1 obliges governments to ensure that the

actions of monopolies, public or private, conform withthe most-favoured nation obligation and a govern-ment’s specific commitments.

• Article VIII.2 obliges governments to ensure that amonopoly supplier—where it supplies services out-side the scope of its monopoly rights, but that are cov-ered by a government’s specific commitments—doesnot “abuse its monopoly position.”

• Article VIII.3 stipulates that, if a government grants amonopoly in sectors where it has previously madeGATS commitments, it must negotiate compensationwith other member governments or face retaliation.

• Finally, all these provisions “also apply to cases ofexclusive service suppliers, where a member formallyor in effect a) authorizes or establishes a small numberof service suppliers, and b) substantially prevents com-petition among those suppliers in its territory” (Arti-cle VIII.5).

Once again, there is surprisingly little discussion ofthe policy implications of the GATS restrictions on mo-nopolies in either Fact and Fiction or Markets Matter. Factand Fiction simply notes that “it is possible to maintain amonopoly supplier, whether public or private, of any serv-ice.”138 Markets Matter goes somewhat further, asserting

Page 79: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

60 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

that “governments retain the right to designate or main-tain monopolies, public or private.”139

Neither tract acknowledges the new burdens imposedon monopolies, nor that monopolies and exclusive sup-plier arrangements are, in fact, inconsistent with GATSArticle XVI. In order to maintain a monopoly or exclu-sive supplier arrangement in any listed sector, govern-ments had to inscribe it as a country-specific exception intheir schedules. Furthermore, if a government wants todesignate a new monopoly in a listed sector, Article VIII.3requires it to negotiate compensation with other membergovernments or face retaliation. It is remarkable that theOECD describes this disagreeable prospect as a “right.”140

Monopolies, while not so prevalent as they once were,are still relied upon to provide basic services in manycountries. Postal services, the sale and distribution of al-coholic beverages, electrical generation and transmission,rail transportation, health insurance, water distribution,and waste disposal are just some of the more widespreadexamples. Exclusive supplier arrangements are common-place in post-secondary education, health care, and othersocial services. What then are some of the practical impli-cations of the rather formidable GATS restrictions on suchmonopolies and exclusive service suppliers?

The consequences of applying MFN unconditionallyto government monopolies have, to date, gone largelyunexamined. In one instance, some time after the GATSwas signed in 1994, international postal officials becameconcerned about the possible inconsistency between GATSMFN obligations and the multilateral rules that regulateinternational postal services under the Universal PostalUnion (UPU). The problems occur in two main areas: de-veloping countries pay lower fees to developed countries

Page 80: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 61

that process and deliver inbound international mail; andthe UPU has rules to prevent these preferential rates frombeing abused by commercial “re-mailers” who transportmail in bulk from one country to be posted in anotherwith lower rates.141 Both sets of arrangements were prob-ably GATS-inconsistent. In 1994, no member governmentslodged MFN exceptions insulating UPU rules from chal-lenge. It is now too late to do so and the UPU regime isbeing adjusted to conform to GATS obligations.

There may well be other conflicts that have gone un-detected. For example, the activities of alcohol monopo-lies and public electrical utilities typically involve prefer-ential agreements for sale of products or the wheeling ofelectricity. These may be preferential or applied on thebasis of reciprocity, not MFN. There is little evidence thatthe consistency of such arrangements with the GATS uni-versally applicable MFN obligations has ever been pub-licly discussed.

The GATS also exposes government monopolies, pub-lic or private, to charges that they are competing unfairlyin listed services outside the scope of their monopoly. Forexample, universities, where a small number of servicesuppliers have an effective monopoly over degree-grant-ing authority and public financial support, could readilybe construed as “exclusive service suppliers.” Where agovernment makes specific commitments covering pri-vate education, this could trigger complaints that post-secondary institutions are abusing their monopoly posi-tion.142 For example, if a university offers a non-creditcourse that competes with courses offered by private train-ing institutes, it could be exposed to charges that it isleveraging its monopoly position by using facilities and

Page 81: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

62 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

faculty supported by its monopoly status outside thescope of this monopoly.

Unfortunately, such aggressive interpretations of in-ternational trade obligations are not fanciful. United Par-cel Services Inc., the world’s largest courier company, iscurrently suing the government of Canada for at least$US160 million under NAFTA.143 UPS alleges that CanadaPost uses its monopoly of letter-mail services to “lever-age” its position in the competitive portions of its activi-ties, including courier services.144 In its claim, UPS is try-ing to invoke NAFTA anti-monopoly articles that are verysimilar to the GATS provisions.145

The GATS requirement that governments that desig-nate a monopoly must negotiate compensation with othermember governments or face retaliation is also a formi-dable hurdle.146 For example, many WTO members, in-cluding Canada, have made commitments covering healthinsurance.147 Consequently, any decision to expand com-pulsory public health insurance plans to cover new areassuch as prescription drugs or home care could result inGATS claims for compensation on behalf of private for-eign insurance companies. This prospect of litigation andpossible trade sanctions creates a serious disincentive tostrengthening the fabric of public health insurance inCanada and other countries.

Under most countries’ domestic laws, the possibilityof such democratic policy changes are considered com-mercial risks borne by all insurance providers, domesticor foreign.148 But, because of the expanding reach of thenew generation of international commercial treaties suchas the GATS, such a domestic policy choice has been trans-formed into an international treaty issue. Only a govern-ment determined enough to negotiate GATS compensa-

Page 82: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 63

tion and to face potential retaliation would proceed. Asalready noted, the very prospect of paying compensationmight be enough to chill such an initiative.

Domestic Regulation (Article VI)

As Markets Matter rightly remarks: “the work programmeenvisaged under Article VI(4)...has provoked the strong-est reactions from groups concerned about the GATS im-pinging upon governments’ regulatory rights.”149 Criticshave directed their harshest criticism at the GATS provi-sions authorizing the negotiation of new restrictions onnon-discriminatory domestic regulation. This is under-standable. Such restrictions, if ever agreed to, would bean extraordinary intrusion into democratic policy-mak-ing on a broad range of important regulatory matters thatare only obliquely related to trade.

GATS Article VI.4 specifies that Members shall de-velop any “necessary disciplines” to ensure that “meas-ures relating to qualification requirements and procedures,technical standards and licensing procedures do not con-stitute unnecessary barriers to trade in services (emphasisadded).” Sub-paragraph (b) of Article VI:4 further speci-fies that such disciplines shall aim to ensure that regula-tory measures are “not more burdensome than necessaryto ensure the quality of the service.”150 These negotiationsare currently underway in Geneva under the auspices ofthe GATS Working Party on Domestic Regulation(WPDR).

The first point to grasp regarding the profound sig-nificance of these negotiations is that the proposed “dis-ciplines” explicitly target non-discriminatory domesticregulations. In fact, the GATS Article VI restrictions are

Page 83: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

64 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

intended to apply exclusively to non-discriminatory meas-ures, regulations that treat local and foreign services andservice providers evenhandedly. So, even if a regulatorymeasure were wholly consistent with the tough non-dis-crimination rules of the GATS (Articles II and XVII) anddid not violate the GATS market access prohibitions (Ar-ticle XVI), it could still be overturned under the proposeddomestic regulation restrictions.151

A simple table reproduced from a 1994 OECD analy-sis of the GATS graphically presents how implementingArticle VI would fulfill the truly universal ambitions ofthe GATS’ architects:

Quantitativerestrictions

Qualitativerestrictions

DiscriminatoryRegulations

Market AccessArticle XVI

National TreatmentArticle XVII

Non-discriminatoryregulations

Market AccessArticle XVI

DomesticRegulations

Article VI

As the table illustrates, the GATS aims to restrict thefull gamut of government measures affecting “trade inservices,” whether these measures are discriminatory ornot. National treatment and MFN restrict discriminatorymeasures, Article XVI targets “quantitative non-discrimi-natory regulations” and Article VI is aimed at “qualita-tive non-discriminatory regulations.”152

A second consideration is that the subject-matter ofthese new restrictions—measures relating to qualificationrequirements and procedures, technical standards and li-censing procedures—is very broad. While none of the fourterms—“qualification requirements and procedures, li-censing requirements and technical standards”—are pre-

Source: OECD

Page 84: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 65

cisely defined in the GATS, many types of governmentalmeasures and regulatory authority would be restricted.Qualification requirements refer to professional accredi-tation, educational requirements, certification of compe-tency, and the like. Licensing requirements obviously in-clude professional licensing, but also apply to a wide va-riety of other licensing requirements such as broadcastlicenses, university accreditation, facilities licensing forclinics, hospitals and laboratories, waste disposal permits,and many other matters. Technical standards is a nearlyall-inclusive category, referring, according to the GATSsecretariat, not only to regulations affecting the “techni-cal characteristics of the service itself,” but also to “therules according to which the service must be per-formed.”153 Water quality standards, pipeline safety, andtoxic waste disposal and storage standards are just a fewimportant examples.

Article VI.4 catches not only these four broad catego-ries of measures themselves, but all measures relating tothem. For example, public subsidies that are made condi-tional on services meeting high technical standards, oron service providers attaining certain levels of accredita-tion, would be caught by this broader language. The pro-posed restrictions, therefore, would cover a wide swathof vital government regulatory measures.

A third, critically important, point is that the proposedrestrictions are intended to apply some form of “neces-sity test” to this wide range of non-discriminatory domes-tic regulations. The WTO Secretariat describes the two as-pects of a potential GATS necessity test in these terms:“the first aspect is the general requirement that regula-tions not be more trade restrictive than necessary; the sec-ond aspect is to examine whether an individual measure

Page 85: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

66 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

is actually necessary to achieve the specified legitimateobjective.”154

Necessity tests are a long-standing feature of theGATT-WTO system. Under GATT Article XX, a govern-ment can, as a last resort, try to save an otherwise GATT-inconsistent measure from successful challenge by argu-ing that it is necessary to achieve a GATT-sanctioned le-gitimate objective. But this general exception has beeninterpreted very restrictively. Indeed, under GATT juris-prudence, “a measure cannot be deemed necessary if sat-isfactory and effective alternative means to achieve thesame objective are reasonably available to the Memberenacting it.”155

Because it has been interpreted so restrictively, GATTArticle XX has been strongly criticized as an ineffectivesafeguard for legitimate public interest measures. It is ofquestionable value as a backstop to save important, al-beit trade-restricting, public interest measures. But Arti-cle VI.4 turns the logic of the necessity test on its head—with potentially alarming results for public interest regu-lation. Under GATS Article VI.4, the necessity test is trans-formed from a shield to save clearly discriminatory meas-ures from challenge into a sword to attack clearly non-dis-criminatory measures.

Fact and Fiction disapprovingly quotes from a CCPAbook that argues that the GATS provisions on domesticregulation pose one of the Agreement’s most “dangerousthreats to democratic decision-making”.156 Fact and Fic-tion observes that “The book claims that ‘governmentswould be compelled to demonstrate, first, that non-dis-criminatory regulations were necessary to achieve a WTO-sanctioned legitimate objective, and secondly, that no lesscommercially-restrictive alternative measure was possi-

Page 86: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 67

ble’.” This claim, however, is accurate, and Fact and Fic-tion does not contest it. Instead, the WTO Secretariat,rather lamely, objects that “the only circumstances inwhich any Member would be required to justify a domes-tic regulation would be in dispute settlement—when aspecific measure had been challenged by another Gov-ernment.”157

It is odd that the Secretariat seems to suggest that gov-ernments and citizens need only be concerned about WTOrules when a measure is challenged—in effect, when vio-lators are caught.158 The WTO Agreements set out bind-ing international norms. A basic principle of treaty law ispacta sunt servanda, the Latin for “agreements are to bekept.” Dispute settlement is just the tip of the iceberg whenconsidering the policy impacts of treaty obligations. It isfully expected that WTO Agreements will be implementeddomestically and that domestic laws and procedures willbe modified to the extent that they conflict with WTOobligations.

Even in the absence of disputes, the impact of broadlyworded restrictions—such as those under considerationunder Article VI.4, on the domestic policy-making proc-ess—would be considerable. Because of uncertainty re-garding their consistency, non-discriminatory regulationsmay be discarded or defeated before they ever see thelight of day. This chilling effect on domestic regulatorycapacity can be as important as the results of the (com-paratively speaking) fewer matters that proceed to fulldispute settlement.

GATS critics are, in any case, well aware that WTOenforcement is complaint-driven. It is precisely this abil-ity of multinational corporate interests to international-ize the domestic contest over non-discriminatory public

Page 87: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

68 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

interest regulation that concerns them. Corporate inter-ests are already very powerful within the domestic policy-making and legislative process. On those increasingly rareoccasions when public interest regulations strongly op-posed by corporate interests are enacted domestically,Article VI.4 restrictions would give multinationals theoption to convince a foreign government to take up theirfight by litigating at the WTO. This deeply troubling sce-nario must be avoided.

As the WTO Secretariat candidly acknowledged in anofficial discussion of Article VI, “The necessity test—es-pecially the requirement that regulatory measures be nomore trade restrictive than necessary—is the means bywhich an effort is made to balance between two poten-tially conflicting priorities: promoting trade expansionversus protecting the regulatory rights of governments.”159

But the WTO, with its structural bias toward commercialinterests and its closed dispute settlement procedures, isnot the place to balance these potentially conflicting pri-orities. These words of warning apply with even greaterforce when the regulatory measures at issue are clearlyand incontestably non-discriminatory.

Furthermore, for all their stress on GATS flexibilityand exceptions, neither the WTO nor the OECD acknowl-edges that no exceptions are contemplated to the proposedrestrictions on domestic regulation under Article VI.4. Thearchitecture of the GATS only allows country-specific limi-tations to Articles XVI and XVII. It does not permit coun-try-specific exceptions to the domestic regulation restric-tions. In an analysis of Article VI.4, the WTO Secretariatnotes that “measures [subject to Article VI disciplines]cannot be entered as limitations in a Member’s sched-ule.”160 And if a measure fails the necessity test under

Page 88: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 69

Article VI, it is logically inconsistent to expect it to be savedby the necessity test employed under the general excep-tions in Article XIV. Elsewhere, the OECD has argued thateven those measures a government explicitly exemptsfrom Articles XVI and XVII in its country schedule couldstill be challenged as more burdensome than necessaryunder Article VI.161

The provisions envisaged under Article VI.4 areamong the most excessive restrictions ever contemplatedin a binding international commercial treaty. Procedurally,they are unlike NAFTA Chapter 11 in that they cannot beinvoked directly by investors. But, substantively, they aresimilarly framed in absolute terms and, arguably, as ex-treme. As noted elsewhere, the reasoning underlying theproposed Article VI.4 restrictions is similar to the dan-gerous logic behind the abused “minimum standards oftreatment” and measures “tantamount to expropriation”provisions of NAFTA’s investment chapter and the failedMultilateral Agreement on Investment.

Indeed, under GATS Article VI, a complainant wouldactually have a lower legal threshold to meet. To arguethat a regulatory measure is “tantamount to expropria-tion” is (or should be) a difficult task. But to argue that aregulation is “more burdensome than necessary to ensurethe quality of the service” (or that it is not “pro-competi-tive”) would be a far easier case to sustain.162 Put anotherway, measures “equivalent to expropriation” are a meresubset of “burdensome measures.”

The proposed restrictions are a recipe for regulatorychill. Their excess is concrete evidence of the hazards ofleaving the neoliberal ambitions of commercial minis-tries—and the corporate lobbyists driving them on—un-checked by broader public scrutiny and debate. It would

Page 89: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

70 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

be a considerable initial achievement if the GATS’ non-governmental critics are able to draw public and politicalattention to, and to unsaddle, these extreme proposals.

Page 90: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 71

Chapter 4:Conclusions

When the Uruguay Round was concluded in 1994, theGATS was little known outside a small circle of negotia-tors and corporate lobbyists. As two well-placed observ-ers noted in 1999: “The negotiations were largely drivenby specific industry interests and trade negotiators them-selves.… After its inception, the GATS continued to at-tract little public attention. Its provisions, let alone its ex-istence, remain relatively unknown or understood, evenamong those who have an interest in the functioning ofthe trading system….”163 Largely due to the efforts of non-governmental organization critics and, more recently, ofsome Southern WTO member governments, this periodof obscurity is now ending.164 The GATS is a deservedlycontroversial agreement and, as its provisions becomemore widely known, public and political concern aboutits policy implications is certain to grow.

In most countries, the entire WTO agreements werehurriedly ratified and implemented, with little public orlegislative debate. Legislatures, where they were con-sulted, were presented with a “single undertaking;” nopart of the negotiated Uruguay Round package could bealtered without unraveling the whole. In this pressurizedcontext, it is not surprising that an agreement as complexas the GATS largely escaped public notice.

Many GATS insiders, however, were keenly aware ofthe novelty and import of this new treaty. Then Director-General of the WTO Renato Ruggiero hinted at the po-tential political controversies inherent in these new restric-tions: “[T]he GATS provides guarantees over a much

Page 91: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

72 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

wider field of regulation and law than the GATT; the rightof establishment and the [obligations]...in all relevant ar-eas of domestic regulation extend the reach of the Agree-ment into areas never before recognized as trade policy. Isuspect that neither governments nor industries have yetappreciated the full scope of these guarantees or the fullvalue of existing commitments.”165

Another key actor in the negotiations, former deputyUnited States Trade Representative Jeffery Lang, high-lighted “the overwhelming uncertainty about the mean-ing of the provisions of the GATS.” Lang observed that:“Virtually every normative provision of the GATS is in-teresting and even novel. Some of these provisions are soobviously problematic that they cry out for substantiverenegotiation. So little is known about their origin andintention,” he continued, “that it may be years before wediscover the impact of these provisions.”166

“Discovering” the practical impacts of the GATS mayprove a trying experience, at least for WTO member gov-ernments and their citizens. There have been only a fewGATS dispute cases so far, but in all three that have goneto full panel, the defendant government has lost.167 Moresignificantly, the panels and the Appellate Body have in-terpreted the broadly worded GATS provisions force-fully.168 While the GATS negotiations proceed, govern-ments will be reluctant to bring controversial GATS casesthat could upset the progress of the talks. But when thesenegotiations conclude—or falter—this self-restraint willlikely vanish.

GATS negotiators, in their eagerness to service corpo-rate desires, were remarkably casual about the conse-quences of these broadly worded provisions for demo-cratic governance. “Overwhelming uncertainty” about

Page 92: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 73

legally binding treaty obligations is debilitating andcostly—for the public, if not for commercial interests.169

The nearly open-ended prospect of litigation and possi-ble trade sanctions advantages commercial interests overother legitimate societal interests in the to-and-fro of policydebate. It chills regulatory initiative. It impedes the ex-pansion and revitalization of public services. It con-sciously and deliberately tips the balance of power fur-ther in favour of already powerful multinational corpo-rate interests.

But GATS proponents make no apologies. “I do notadvocate,” Lang declared, “pausing in the movement for-ward to accomplish some kind of ecclesiastical exerciseof figuring out what these provisions mean. That can onlyaid and abet those who want to frustrate progress.”170

It is fascinating to compare the early insider analysesof the GATS—which frankly concede, even celebrate, itsnovelty, scope and ambition—with the current defensiveaccounts. By contrast, today’s GATS proponents strive toimply that the GATS is so flexible that it leaves govern-ments completely free to govern as they choose. It ap-pears that frank discussion and analysis are reserved forcorporate and trade policy audiences, while the broaderpolicy concerns raised by critics must be categorically dis-missed.

For example, compare Ruggiero’s candid assessmentof the GATS with that of his successor, Michael Moore,who, at the opening of the Doha Ministerial, hectored civilsociety delegates concerned about the policy implicationsof the GATS for “wast[ing] time fighting windmills.” In aby-now-familiar mantra, Director-General Moore declaredthat: “There is absolutely no requirement in the GATS toprivatize any service. Governments retain the right not

Page 93: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

74 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

to make commitments on health and education services,or indeed any other services, if they so choose. Servicesprovided in the exercise of governmental authority arewholly excluded from the scope of the GATS. The GATSspecifically protects the right of governments to regulateservices and to introduce new regulations.”171 These em-phatic reassurances are half-truths: incomplete and mis-leading. Indeed, Moore’s belligerence leads him to makeunsupportable statements that slight not only the intelli-gence of his critics, but of the broader public to whom heis ultimately responsible.

It is remarkable that Moore bristles at any suggestionthat the GATS is an instrument of privatization. In thesimplest terms, privatization is the transfer of ownershipof public resources or assets to private hands. Liberaliza-tion is the opening of domestic markets to foreign owner-ship and competition. While privatization and liberaliza-tion are not interchangeable terms, they are certainly fel-low travellers.

Liberalization presupposes the existence of privatemarkets. This is especially so in the realm of serviceswhere, despite two decades of widespread neoliberalpolicies, many essential services—such as health care,education, social services, the arts, water, and electricity—are still dominated in many countries by public and not-for-profit provision. The global pool of resources devotedto these basic services is enormous. For example, world-wide spending on health is roughly US$3 trillion annu-ally, on education US$2.2 trillion annually, revenues fromthe generation and distribution of electricity over US$1trillion annually, and spending on postal and express de-livery services roughly US$250 billion annually.172 As thecorporate lobbies active in the GATS negotiations clearly

Page 94: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 75

grasp, the more these services are privatized, the greaterthe commercial opportunities.

Moreover, in many sectors, the commercial provisionof these basic services is dominated by a handful of mul-tinational corporations based in the developed world. Inthese cases, the clear alternative to public, not-for profitservices is provision by foreign multinationals. In ideol-ogy and in practice, therefore, privatization and liberali-zation are intimately connected.

Claiming that the GATS does not force governmentsto privatize public services is, deliberately, beside thepoint. As some southern WTO member governments re-cently expressed the relationship: “GATS does not man-date countries to liberalise and privatise. However, it cer-tainly does encourage and lock-in a country’s liberalisa-tion. Liberalisation in turn encourages privatisation. Manyof the problems that have been experienced by countriesthrough privatisation, could therefore well happenthrough GATS.”173

As previously discussed, through continuous built-innegotiations the GATS exerts constant pressure to openservices, including services now provided publicly or bynon-profits, to foreign commercial providers. The univer-sally applicable GATS MFN rule generalizes and helpsconsolidate commercialization wherever it occurs. TheGATS market access restrictions clearly identify publicmonopolies as market access barriers that must be spe-cifically exempted or dispensed with whenever govern-ments make GATS commitments. The general rules onmonopolies make it more difficult for governments tomaintain public monopolies by hamstringing their abil-ity to compete with commercial suppliers in areas out-side the scope of their monopoly. Critically, once GATS

Page 95: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

76 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

commitments are made, the GATS restricts the ability offuture governments to restore, revitalize, or expand pub-lic services. In such cases, compensation must be negoti-ated or retaliatory sanctions faced.

The GATS is, by design, a formidable instrument toencourage and to entrench privatization. As argued else-where, the GATS is, at root, hostile to public services. Ittreats them, at best, as missed commercial opportunitiesand, at worst, as unfair competition or barriers to entryfor foreign services and suppliers.174

Moore’s statement that “services provided in the ex-ercise of governmental authority are wholly excludedfrom the scope of the GATS” is even more misleading. Itis an empty statement, that merely repeats the wordingof the controversial GATS exclusion. It avoids the criticalissue: what is the scope and effectiveness of the GATSgovernmental authority exclusion? As discussed, this ex-clusion is highly qualified, subject to conflicting interpre-tations, and, quite possibly, ineffective in protecting evenexisting public services.

A truly effective GATS exclusion for public serviceswould need, above all, to ensure governments’ flexibilityto restore and revitalize public or not-for-profit serviceswhere experiments with private market provision fail.However dubious the value of the current exclusion inhiving off existing public services from GATS restrictions,it is incontestable that, as commercialization and compe-tition increase, the scope of the governmental authorityexclusion diminishes. As a result, the restrictive terms ofthe Article I:3 exclusion render it ineffective when it isneeded most: when services privatization and commer-cialization go badly and lose public support. By makingit more difficult to reverse failed privatizations, the GATS

Page 96: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 77

interferes significantly with democratic flexibility. WTOmember governments should reinterpret or amend thisexclusion to provide much-needed flexibility for publicservices, preferably by simply eliminating the qualifica-tions in Article I:3.c and making the exclusion self-defin-ing.

Finally, we are left with Moore’s statement, echoed inparagraph 7 of the Doha Ministerial declaration, that “TheGATS specifically protects the right of governments toregulate services and to introduce new regulations.”175

Certainly, the GATS does not eliminate governments’ abil-ity to regulate. But it does require that government regu-lation, whatever its form or purpose, be consistent withthe GATS.

If Moore’s statement were taken, as intended, at facevalue and in isolation, his audience would not know thatthe recognition of the right to regulate in the GATS pre-amble has little legally enforceable effect. Or that the GATSclearly applies to the full range of government regulatorymeasures. Or that the GATS applies a very tough test ofnon-discrimination when considering the possible ad-verse effects of regulatory measures on foreigners. Or thatthe GATS prohibits certain types of regulatory measures,even if they are non-discriminatory. Or, finally, that thegeneral exceptions that purport to protect public interestregulation are extremely difficult to invoke successfully.

Nor would the pubic have any idea that there are on-going GATS negotiations that aim to apply a necessitytest to non-discriminatory domestic regulation. If ArticleVI is ever fully implemented, it would give the WTO dis-pute settlement process the authority to rule a wide rangeof regulatory measures GATS-inconsistent. All that wouldbe required is for dispute panels to find that some less-

Page 97: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

78 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

restrictive or less-burdensome means was, in the panel’sor the Appellate Body’s view, reasonably available toachieve a particular regulatory objective. These contro-versial negotiations would radically expand the reach oftrade law restrictions and pose a very serious threat tocrucial public interest regulations. This is a threat thatMoore and other GATS proponents would obviously pre-fer to keep out of the public eye.

It is high time to apply a public interest version of thenecessity test to the ambitions of corporate lobbyists andQuad trade negotiators. Are these new broadly wordedprotections really necessary? Must the scope of “trade trea-ties,” which are ranging further and further afield fromconventional trade issues, be inexorably expanded? Arethere alternative means to achieve reasonable certaintyfor service providers and investors that are not so restric-tive and burdensome for democratic decision-making andflexibility? Can a sustainable multilateral system be builtaround rules that privilege multinational commercial in-terests, conferring powerful rights without responsibili-ties?

The adherents of the bicycle theory of internationaltrade negotiations insist that, if the WTO’s momentuminto new sectors and fields of regulation falters, then thewhole edifice of multilateral trade rules will be in jeop-ardy.176 As the remarkable statement by the former DeputyUSTR Jeffery Lang quoted above shows, this insistencecan degenerate into the bizarre or irrational, where sim-ply pausing to understand what the GATS provisionsmean is equated with “frustrating progress.”

In the power bargaining and pressure tactics that ledto Doha, the call for assessment of the WTO’s novel serv-ices agreement from NGOs and, importantly, a number

Page 98: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 79

of key Southern governments was brushed aside. Instead,negotiations to broaden and deepen GATS coverage willbe—along with agriculture and industrial market access—one of the centerpieces of the new Doha Round. The WTOnegotiating agenda now includes other new and conten-tious topics such as investment, competition policy, andstrengthening the WTO’s dispute settlement provisions.

Firm timelines for the services negotiations wereagreed as part of the Doha package, with initial requestsfor specific commitments due by June 30, 2002, and ini-tial offers by March 31, 2003.177 The GATS rule-makingissues, including the contentious talks on domestic regu-lation, are supposed to conclude prior to the end of themarket access phase of the services talks. All the elementsof the services packages are to be finalized, along withthe many other elements of the new negotiating agendaby the ambitious and seemingly unrealistic deadline ofJanuary 1, 2005. In short, the bicycle theorists appear tobe in firm control and setting a furious pace.

But, as author Susan George remarked at a recent con-ference on the WTO, it would be far wiser to get off thebicycle, put our feet on the ground, and have a look aroundto see where we are.178 Unfortunately, there is little signthat this much-needed debate and deliberation on theGATS will occur soon. The message from Doha is thatconfrontation and brinksmanship work—at least for thepowerful insiders who dominate WTO affairs. But thisapproach is bound to undermine the legitimacy of nego-tiations in the eyes of the public and, ultimately, will prob-ably prove unsustainable.

It is hardly surprising that such a broadly-worded,sweeping agreement as the GATS has become a lightningrod for controversy. It is highly inappropriate for Mr.

Page 99: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

80 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Moore or other GATS partisans to disparage the criticsand to attempt to dismiss out-of-hand their well-foundedconcerns. If there is one lesson proponents should havelearned from the Seattle debacle and the failed MAI, it isthat, no matter how emphatic or strident their voices, theycannot simply shut down or control the debate. Withmodest effort, non-governmental organizations, electedofficials, and ordinary citizens are more than capable ofsorting out the issues, of separating GATS fact from fic-tion. And when they do, they are likely to react withshocked disapproval at how far, and in what direction,the proverbial bicycle has been driven. Then the mainquestions will be how quickly citizens mobilize and howeffectively they bring their considerable influence to bearon their respective governments—both in changing thenature of GATS negotiations that are now underway inGeneva, and in charting a more balanced future.

Page 100: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 81

Endnotes

1 Hereafter, Fact and Fiction.2 Hereafter, Markets Matter.3 World Trade Organization, Trade in Services Secretariat,

GATS: Fact and Fiction, Geneva, March 2001, available on theWTO web site at http://www.wto.org.OECD, Working Party of the Trade Committee, Open Serv-ices Markets Matter, September 3, 2001, TD/TC/WP(2001)24/PART1/REV1.

4 The September 3, 2002 document is the first part of a 2-partstudy. Part 1 mainly addresses concerns about how the GATSoperates, while part 2 is to present evidence of the benefits ofservices trade and investment liberalization.

5 The United States, the European Union, Japan and Canadacomprise the so-called Quad countries.

6 Here are just a few illustrations of close government-corpo-rate collaboration in the response to GATS critics:In mid-November 2000, shortly after the Canadian Centrefor Policy Alternatives published the first book-length GATScritique, photocopies of the CCPA book were tabled by theEuropean Services Forum at one of its regular meetings withEC trade officials and the influential Article 133 committee.The managing director of the ESF reportedly complainedabout emerging civil society criticism of the GATS whilewarning the EC and Article 133 representatives against de-lays in the GATS negotiations.Speaking recently at the World Services Congress, AndrewBuxton, chair of the ESF, praised the OECD polemic and cor-porate-government alliances, “I think that the sort of alliancethat exists in some parts of the world … between govern-ment and industry through the CSI here in Hong Kong … isa way of having a combination that actually … needs to putthe business case for services liberalization. … I thought therecent OECD report on services trade and investment wasextremely good in setting out the case … So, we’ve got topublicize that. It’s our job to do it. The gossip that is comingout of Geneva at the moment is that not enough people aredoing that.” Excerpt from discussion at World Services Fo-rum, Hong Kong: Panel Discussion “Making Good Guys out

Page 101: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

82 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

of Globalization” 20 September 2001, Congress Dinner, Tran-scribed by Corporate Europe Observatory from webcastavailable at http://www.tdctrade.com/tdcwebcast/wsc.htm.Most disturbingly, confidential minutes of a high-level com-mittee comprised of senior UK trade officials and service in-dustry representatives “reveal that government officials haveallied with business in planning a campaign to defeat civilsociety opposition against the WTO services negotiations.”Erik Wesselius of Corporate Europe Observatory, who un-covered the previously confidential minutes, observes that:“While it is useful and justified for governments to take busi-ness concerns into account when formulating trade policy,privileged co-operative arrangements between business andgovernment as embodied in IFSL/LOTIS do not belong in atruly democratic policy-making process.” See Erik Wesselius,Corporate Europe Observatory, Liberalization Of Trade inServices: Corporate Power at Work, http://www.gatswatch.org/LOTIS/LOTISarticle.html.

7 Fact and Fiction was prepared under the former Director ofthe WTO Trade in Services Division, David Hartridge, withthe provocative working title “Refuting the Lies.” To viewthe original author and working title download the docu-ment in MS-Word format and pass your cursor over the docu-ment. The initiating author and working title will appear.

8 Fact and Fiction, p. 2.9 That is, accurately represented, as opposed to being re-cast

according to the WTO’s characterization of them.10 The Oxford English Dictionary defines “threaten” as “appears

likely to cause or do something undesirable”. It is in this or-dinary sense that this book argues that key GATS provisionspose serious threats to public services and public interestregulation.

11 The Oxford English Reference Dictionary defines “commercial-ize” as:“1 exploit or spoil for the purpose of gaining profit.2 make commercial.”The same dictionary defines “privatize” as:“make private, esp. assign (a business etc.) to private as dis-tinct from state control or ownership”

Page 102: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 83

The Penguin Dictionary of Economics is more detailed, defin-ing of “privatization” as:“Principally, the sale of government-owned equity in nation-alized industries or other commercial enterprises to privateinvestors, with or without the loss of government control inthese organization…. Other types of privatization may takethe form of … the subcontracting to the private sector of workpreviously carried out by state employees.”(The Oxford English Reference Dictionary, Oxford UniversityPress, 1996; The Penguin Dictionary of Economics, GrahamBannock, R.E. Baxter and Evan Davis, 1998. Both are avail-able online at http://www.xrefer.com ).

12 The draft WTO ministerial declaration states that “We reaf-firm the right of members under the GATS to regulate, andto introduce new regulations on, the supply of services.”Again, this dodges the important issue: what forms of regu-lation are consistent with the GATS and which are at risk ofchallenge? WTO Ministerial Conference, Fourth Session,Doha, Qatar, 9 - 14 November 2001, Ministerial Declaration,paragraph 7.Trade negotiators and officials sometimes get quite sancti-monious about carefully worded, but largely empty, reassur-ances. Another example of this type of reassuring sounding,though misleading, statement is contained in an article inNAFTA’s controversial investment chapter. NAFTA Article1114 reads that “Nothing in this chapter shall be construedto prevent a Party from adopting, maintaining or enforcingany measure otherwise consistent with this chapter that it con-siders appropriate to ensure that investment activity in itsterritory is undertaken in a manner sensitive to environmen-tal concerns (emphasis added).” This hardly protects the rightto regulate to protect the environment—as the unwary or thecredulous are meant to suppose.

13 Some of the best of the NGO responses to the WTO’s Factand Fiction include:• “Separating WTO Fact and Fiction,” June 2001, Ellen

Gould, Council of Canadians. Available at http://www.canadians.org/campaigns/campaigns-tradepub-gats-fact_fiction.html.

• Technical Comments on the WTO’s “GATS: Fact and Fic-tion” Paper, April 2001, Vice Yu, Friends of the Earth In-

Page 103: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

84 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

ternational. available at http://www.xs4all.nl/~ceo/gatswatch/factfict/foei.html.

• World Development Movement’s summary response tothe World Trade Organisation document “GATS - Factsand Fiction”, April 2001, World Development Movement.Available at http://www.wdm.org.uk/cambriefs/Wto/factfictionrebuttal.htm.

• “GATS—Fact and Fiction: at best a partial truth,” April2001, Chakravarthi Ragavan, Third World Network.http://www.twnside.org.sg/title/fiction.htm.

• “GATS—What Is Fact And What Is Fiction? A Civil Soci-ety Response to the WTO’s Publication ‘GATS—Fact andFiction.’” 25 May 2001, available at http://www.xs4all.nl/~ceo/gatswatch/factfict/rebuttal-intro.html.

14 What certain interest groups view as beneficial results, oth-ers may rightly regard as negative impacts.

15 For example, “An Introduction to the GATS,” WTO Secre-tariat, Trade in Services Division, October 1999. See also “TheGeneral Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS): An Analy-sis,” OECD, Paris 1994.

16 Ironically, many of the policy objectives – for example, greatercommercialization of public services or pro-competitive regu-latory reform – that GATS supporters in trade policy andcorporate circles now strenuously deny they plan to achievethrough the GATS are openly embraced or promoted in docu-ments published before the GATS became publicly contro-versial. See, for example, the papers presented at the 1999World Services Congress, available at http://www.worldservicescongresss.com.

17 David Woods, a former Director of Communications for theWTO, now in the private sector, launched a furious attack onGATS critics that is even more extreme than Fact and Fiction.Tellingly, Woods contemptuously denounced not just the crit-ics but “the limp-wristed acquiescence of ministers who can-not risk being seen publicly to challenge the demagogues of‘civil society’.” “Lies, damn lies and what the GATS reallysays” at http://www.tradeagenda.com.

18 Markets Matter, p. 4.19 Fact and Fiction, p. 6.20 Fact and Fiction, p. 6. Markets Matter, p. 10 para. 12.

Page 104: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 85

21 cf. Scott Sinclair, GATS: How the World Trade Organization’snew ‘services’ negotiations threaten democracy, Ottawa, Cana-dian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2000, pp. 24 ff.

22 See the United Nations Provisional Central Product Classifi-cation (New York: United Nations, 1991), also known as theprovisional CPC, which most member governments haveused as the basis for their GATS commitments. The provi-sional CPC and its subsequent versions are available onlineat http://esa.un.org/unsd/cr/registry/regrt.asp .

23 Markets Matter, p. 6.24 GATS Article XXVIII (Definitions) contains no definition of

services. GATS Article I simply states that “‘services’ includesany service in any sector, except those supplied in the exer-cise of governmental authority.”

25 This definition is adapted from: The Oxford English Diction-ary, 1989, Clarendon Press, Oxford, Vol. XV, pp. 34-39; andfrom the Canadian Oxford Dictionary, 1998, Oxford UniversityPress, Toronto, pp. 1322-3; Webster’s Encyclopedic Dictionary,1988, Lexicon, New York, p. 910; Webster’s New InternationalDictionary, 2nd Ed., Mirriam, Springfield, Mass., p. 2288; andA Dictionary of Canadian Economics, David Crane, Hurtig, Ed-monton, 1980, p. 308.

26 WTO, “Canada: Certain Measures concerning Periodicals,”Panel Report, 14 March 1997, para. 5.18.

27 As noted later in the book, despite these clear ecological im-pacts of services, the GATS drafters omitted the general ex-ception for measures “relating to the conservation of exhaust-ible natural resources” that is found in GATT Article XX gov-erning goods – an omission that was almost certainly delib-erate.

28 Markets Matter, p. 9.29 For example, “Member governments individually have cho-

sen and will choose in which sectors to make binding com-mitments and in which not. This is known as positive listing,or bottom-up approach and was the preferred method ofdeveloping countries in the original GATS negotiations.”Briefing note on the GATS, United Kingdom Department ofTrade and Industry, March 2001, p. 1, mimeo.

30 Emphasis is added. Article I (Scope and Definition) must beread in conjunction with Article XXVIII (Definitions).

Page 105: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

86 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

31 Article XXVIII states that “‘measure’ means any measure bya Member, whether in the form of a law, regulation, rule, pro-cedure, decision, administrative action, or any other form.”Government procurement is the only broad category of meas-ure that is excluded from certain, but not all, GATS rules. SeeGATS Article XIII.

32 See, for example, “Canada: Certain Measures Affecting theAutomotive Industry,” WTO Appellate Body, 31 May 2000,para. 149.

33 See “European Community: Bananas,” Panel Report, 22 May1997, para. 7.280. WT/DS27/R/USA.

34 “An Introduction to the GATS,” WTO Trade in Services Di-vision, October 1999. p. 3.

35 Ibid., p. 3.36 Cf. Sinclair, 2000, op. cit, p. 47.37 See “European Community – Bananas,” Appellate Body Re-

port, para. 220.38 The Canada Autos panel, for example, affirmed that the GATS

non-discrimination provisions “protect competitive oppor-tunities, not actual trade flows.” Canada Autos, X Findings,D.6 (d) para. VIII.3. The complainants did not need to showthat Canadian value-added requirements had any actual ef-fect on trade flows in services, but only that, hypotheticallyor in the future, they might have. See Canada Autos, X Find-ings, D.6 (d) and (e). “Canada: Certain Measures Affectingthe Automotive Industry,” Report of the Panel, 11 February,2000.

39 Renato Ruggiero, former WTO Director, June 2, 1998.40 Fact and Fiction, p. 6.41 Markets Matter p. 17.42 Section II.5, “Guidelines and procedures for the negotiations

on trade in services,” Adopted by the Special Session of theCouncil for Trade in Services on March 28, 2001, S/L/93.

43 The relevant excerpt, contained in GATS Article I:3, is:“For the purposes of this Agreement … ‘services’ includesany service in any sector except services supplied in the ex-ercise of governmental authority;… ‘a service supplied in theexercise of governmental authority’ means any service whichis supplied neither on a commercial basis, nor in competi-tion with one or more service suppliers.”

44 Markets Matter, para. 102.

Page 106: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 87

45 “Liberalization? Don’t reject it just yet”, Mike Moore, Guard-ian, 26 February 2001.

46 OECD, “The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS):An analysis,” op. cit., p. 7.

47 Article 31(1) of the Vienna Convention provides that “a treatyshall be interpreted in good faith in accordance with the or-dinary meaning to be given to the terms of the treaty in theircontext and in the light of its object and purpose.”

48 “GATS and Public Service Systems: The GATS ‘governmen-tal authority’ exclusion is narrower than it first appears, mayundergo urgent review,” Ministry of Employment and In-vestment, Government of British Columbia, Canada, April2, 2001, 23 pp. (now available at http://members.iinet.net.au/~jenks/GATS_BC2001.html).

49 “Public Services and the Scope of the General Agreement onTrade in Services,” Krajewski, M., Center for InternationalEnvironmental Law, May, 2001.

50 The European Communities highlighted this fact to a WTOcommittee in 1999, stating:“These provisions [Article 55 of the EC treaty] are similarwith those of Article 1.3.(b) of GATS which excludes from itsscope services ‘supplied in the exercise of governmental au-thority’…. There are no examples in the European Court ofJustice jurisprudence where the Court found that an activitywould fall under the scope of Article 55.” European Com-munities, Joint Communication from the Parties, Committeeon Regional Trade Agreements, WT/REG50/2/Add.3; WT/REG51/2/Add.3; WT/REG52/2/Add.3 19 May 1999, Item3, paras. 3 and 6.

51 Council for Trade in Services, Report of the Meeting Held on14 October 1998, Note by the Secretariat, S/C/M/30, 12 No-vember 1998, p. 4. Cited in GATS and Public Service Sys-tems, op. cit..

52 Some official publications, including the WTO paper previ-ously cited, refer to central banking as a specific example ofan excluded governmental service. But central banking is aspecial case; it is positively listed as excluded in the GATSFinancial Services Annex (see Financial Services Annex Arti-cle 1(b)(i)), and thus is not directly relevant to the exclusioncontained in the main text of the GATS.

53 Fact and Fiction, p. 10.

Page 107: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

88 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

54 Markets Matter, para. 101.55 Markets Matter, para. 101. The OECD’s reference to “like serv-

ices” is puzzling. A recent legal opinion draws attention tothe fact that the GATS drafters did not restrict the meaningof the term “competition” in Article I:3 to interaction betweenlike services or like service providers:“Placed in the context of its GATS provisions, the term ‘com-petition’ would normally imply the interaction of ‘like’ serv-ice providers. However, Article I:3 c) did not make referenceto this notion which is commonly used in GATS and GATTnon-discriminatory provisions to qualify ‘competition.’”In sharp contrast to the OECD, this legal opinion concludesthat, “in accordance with Article I:3(c), service providers donot have to be ‘like’ service providers or provide ‘like’ serv-ices to be in competition with one another. To be in competi-tion, they could simply ‘try to get what others also seek’.”The opinion notes: “Had GATS drafters wanted to limit com-petition to like service providers, they would have used theword ‘like’ as it was used in GATS Article XVII in relation tonational treatment (which also makes reference to the word‘competition’).”Gottlieb and Pearson, “GATS Impact on Education in Canada,October 2001.” The full legal opinion is available on the website of the Canadian Association of University Teachers athttp://www.caut.ca.

56 In the event of a dispute, this determination would be madeby a GATS dispute panel, using the ordinary meaning of“competition” and “compete”, which are very broad. A col-lation of definitions of these terms is contained in Gottlieband Pearson, op. cit., and in GATS and Public Service Sys-tems, op. cit..

57 Webster’s Encyclopedic Dictionary, 1988, New York, Lexicon,p. 200.Cf. Gottlieb and Pearson, op. cit., 2.4.1.2: “The term ‘compe-tition’ also has an ordinary meaning: ‘The effort or action oftwo or more commercial interests to obtain the same busi-ness from third party,’ Black’s Law Dictionary, 7th Ed., 1999,West Group; ‘The act of competing; a rivalry for supremacy,a prize, honor, or advantage,’ Random House Webster’s CollegeDictionary, 1997, Random House, New York; ‘Rivalry betweenindividuals (or groups or nations), and it arises whenever

Page 108: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 89

two or more parties strive for something that all cannot ob-tain,’ (The New Pelgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, MacmillanPress Ltd, 1987); ‘Rivalry in the market, striving for custombetween those who have the same commodities to disposeof,’ The Oxford English Dictionary, 1989, Oxford ClarendonPress, p. 604; ‘the act or an instance of competition or con-tending with others (for supremacy, a position, a prize, etc.)’The Canadian Oxford Dictionary, Don Mills, Oxford Univer-sity Press Canada, p. 290.‘Compete’ is defined as: ‘to try to get what others also seekand which all cannot have, to compete for export markets.’Webster’s Encyclopedic Dictionary, 1988, New York, Lexicon,p. 200.”

58 Cf. “The hospital sector in many countries, however, is madeup of government- and privately- owned entities which bothoperate on a commercial basis, charging the patient or hisinsurance for the treatment provided. Supplementary subsi-dies may be granted for social, regional and similar policypurposes. It seems unrealistic in such cases to argue for con-tinued application of Article I:3 and/or maintain that no com-petitive relationship exists between the two groups of sup-pliers or services. In scheduled sectors, this suggests thatsubsidies and any similar economic benefits conferred on onegroup would be subject to the national treatment obligationunder Article XVII.” WTO Secretariat, Background Note,Health and Social Services, Sept. 18, 1998. S/C/W/50, para.39.

59 Cf. “Police services don’t ‘compete’ with the private securityfirms working alongside them.” Speech by David Hartridge,Director, WTO Trade in Services Division, to the EuropeanServices Forum, Brussels, Nov. 27, 2000.

60 Markets Matter, para. 104.61 Some business administration courses, for example, charge

full cost fees. And in some countries, including Canada, for-eign students are charged higher fees that approach full costrecovery.

62 As in the case of competition, the ordinary meanings of “com-mercial” and “commerce” are broad, making it quite likelythat dispute settlement panels would judge many public serv-ices to fall outside the protective ambit of the governmental

Page 109: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

90 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

authority exclusion. Some of these definitions are consideredin Gottlieb and Pearson, op. cit..

63 Markets Matter, para. 102.64 A thorough discussion of the “legislative options” for

strengthening or replacing Article I:3 is contained in “PublicServices and the Scope of the General Agreement on Tradein Services,” by Markus Krajewski, Center for InternationalEnvironmental law, May 2001, Section VII, available at http://www.gatswatch.org/docs/markus.html.

65 Ibid., Section VII, p. 17.66 As is suggested earlier in the document, Markets Matter, para.

102.67 Markets Matter, para. 139.68 If one looks beyond the technical aspects, the controversy

surrounding the governmental authority exclusion may haveless to do with the threats that GATS entails for public serv-ices and more to do with a basic disagreement about the im-portance of public services per se. Tellingly, the Director ofthe WTO Information and Media Relations Division KeithRockwell revealed a thinly disguised contempt for concernsabout the potential for the GATS to pressure Britain and otherMembers to “open services like health, education, energy,film and television to competition from private corporations.”Responding to a critical column by journalist Nick Cohen,Rockwell wrote: “It may have escaped Cohen’s notice butcompetition between private and public services providersalready exists in Britain in these sectors and yet the nationseems to be thriving.” “WTO spokesman answers a critic,”Keith Rockwell, Director, Information and Media RelationsDivision, 19 March 2001, available at http://www.wto.org.

69 Fact and Fiction, p. 6.70 Markets Matter, p. 9.71 As discussed, governments had a one-time opportunity to

list country-specific exceptions to MFN. These exceptions aresubject to further negotiation and, in principle, are limited to10 years.

72 Markets Matter, p. 8.73 Fact and Fiction , p. 1, emphasis added.74 Chakravarthi Ragavan, “GATS—Fact and Fiction at best a

partial truth,” Third World Network. April 2001, http://www.twnside.org.sg/title/fiction.htm.

Page 110: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 91

75 See, for example, “Insurance Agreement Ends Stalemate onChina’s Accession to WTO,” BNA WTO Reporter, Septem-ber 18, 2001.

76 For a fuller discussion of horizontal negotiating modalitiessee Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., pp. 72 ff. and Rachel Thompson,“Formula Approaches to Improving GATS Commitments”in Pierre Sauvé and Robert M. Stern, eds. GATS 2000, NewDirections In Services Trade Liberalization Washington,Brookings Institution, 2000.

77 The GATS negotiating guidelines, agreed in March 2001, statethat “liberalization shall be advanced through bilateral,plurilateral or multilateral negotiations. The main methodof negotiating shall be request-offer.” This wording leavesopen recourse to horizontal and formula approaches. WTO,“Guidelines and Procedures for the Negotiations on Tradein Services,” March 29, 2001, S/L/93.

78 OECD Trade Committee, “Assessing Barriers to Trade in Serv-ices: Cross-cutting (Formula) Approaches to Multilateral serv-ices Negotiations.” September 1999. Box 4.

79 Forty-four, mainly least-developed, countries have madeGATS commitments in 20 sectors or less. But this is far fromthe norm. Most developed countries have already made com-mitments in 100 or more sectors. See Rudolph Adlung, “Serv-ices Trade Liberalization from Developed and DevelopingCountry Perspectives.” Table 5-1, in Sauvé and Stern, op. cit.,p. 115.

80 Markets Matter, p. 37.81 Canada, for example, has made commitments in over 100

sectors representing hundreds of billions of dollars of eco-nomic activity.

82 Fact and Fiction, p. 7.83 “The GATS: What is Fact and What is Fiction, A Civil Society

Response to the WTO’s Fact and Fiction, Summary,” May 25,2001, available at http://www.gatswatch.org/docs/rebuttal.html.

84 It is a general rule of treaty interpretation that country-spe-cific reservations, as derogations from the general objectivesof a treaty, will be interpreted narrowly. See Shaw, Interna-tional Law (4th ed.) pp. 641-649 and J. K. Koh, “Reservationsto Multilateral Treaties,” Harvard International Law Journal,

Page 111: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

92 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

1982, p. 71. The limitations in GATS country schedules are,arguably, a form of reservation.

85 See the subsequent section of this book.86 Markets Matter, Table 4, “Exceptions for Goods and Services

in the WTO Agreements.”.87 Japan’s dissenting view that cross-sectoral retaliation is not

permitted is noted in the minutes of the July 1999 Commit-tee on Specific Commitments meeting. Japan “recalled thatits position was that the scope of retaliation was limited toservices.” Report of the Meeting Held on 19 July 1999,” Noteby the Secretariat , 25 August 1999, S/CSC/M/11.

88 WTO, “Trading Into The Future,” on-line guide to the WTOAgreements, 1999.

89 Like all other interested parties, insurance providers wouldhave the opportunity to make their case against such a changein the domestic policy debate.

90 Markets Matter, para. 82, table 4.91 The Canadian Oxford Dictionary defines “deem” as “regard,

consider, judge.”92 For a discussion of these three elements in relation to GATT

Article XX see Jon R. Johnson, International Trade Law, Con-cord, Ontario, 1998, pp. 66 ff.

93 Cf. Robert Howse and Makau Mutua, Protecting Human Rightsin a Global Economy: Challenges for the World Trade Organiza-tion, (Montreal: Rights and Democracy, 1999). The authorsexpress the view that under a new interpretive approachdeveloped by the Appellate Body, “the meaning of the ne-cessity test would have to be considered in light of relevantrules of international law, including international agreementson human rights.” Such an approach, Howse and Mutuahope, might breathe new life into GATT Article XX. See pp.11-12.

94 GATT Article XX describes ten categories of permissible meas-ures, GATS Article XIV just five.

95 All manner of conservation measures aimed primarily atnatural resources as goods are nevertheless bound to affectmany related services such as distribution, transportation,and processing, or related services such as silviculture, wastedisposal, recycling and so on. GATS Article XVI 2(c) indi-cates that the prohibition of limitations on the total numberof service operations, or on the total quantity of service out-

Page 112: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 93

put, “does not cover measures of a member which limit in-puts for the supply of services.” This qualification wouldpresumably insulate conservation measures limiting naturalresource inputs from the application of this specific article.But it raises the concern that, by inference, other aspects ofArticle XVI and the GATS would apply to such conservationmeasures if they affected “trade in services.” See GATS Arti-cle XVI, note 9 and Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., p. 58.

96 Fact and Fiction misrepresents this exclusion when it tries todeflect concerns expressed by Ralph Nader “about sovereignprivacy protections deemed to be overly restrictive to inter-national trade.” Fact and Fiction asserts that “a safeguard forindividual privacy is built into the framework of the GATSitself. One of the General Exceptions in Article XIV of theGATS, overriding all other provisions, covers measures Gov-ernments might find it necessary to take for ‘the protectionof the privacy of individuals in relation to the processing anddissemination of personal data and the protection of confi-dentiality of individual records and accounts.’” The Secre-tariat fails to note that this clause refers only to measures“necessary to ensure compliance with laws and regulationsthat are not inconsistent with the GATS” – and therefore pro-vides no protection to privacy laws and regulations that aredeemed overly restrictive to international trade in services.See Fact and Fiction, p. 13.

97 The Government of Canada web site, for example, states that“The GATS specifically recognizes the right of governmentsto regulate services, public or private, in order to meet na-tional policy objectives.” GATS: Frequently Asked Questions,available at http://strategis.ic.gc.ca/SSG/sk00100e.html.

98 Markets Matter, Executive Summary.99 Fact and Fiction, p. 11.100 GATS preamble.101 “We affirm the right of members under the General Agree-

ment on Trade in Services to regulate, and to introduce newregulations, on the supply of services.” Paragraph 7, “Minis-terial Declaration,” Fourth Ministerial Conference, Doha,Qatar, November 9-13, 2001.

102 A chairman’s report on a WTO consultation with NGOs raisesa red herring when it states that “Concern was also expressedover whether the GATS preamble, which explicitly recognizes

Page 113: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

94 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

the right of governments to regulate, and to create new regu-lations, was equally legally binding as the main GATS text.The response was affirmative .…” “Symposium on issuesconfronting the world trading system – summary reports bythe moderators. Session IV Services.” July 6, 2001. Availableon the WTO web site (http://www.wto.org). While the GATSpreamble is a legally binding part of the GATS, it nonethe-less has strictly limited effect – particularly when contrastedto the substantive provisions in the main text of the agree-ment.

103 “‘Measure’ means any measure by a Member, whether in theform of a law, regulation, rule, procedure, decision, adminis-trative action, or any other form.” GATS Article XXVIII (Defi-nitions).

104 WTO Secretariat, Trade in Services Division, “The GATS: Ob-jectives, Coverage and Disciplines (Everything you wantedto know about the GATS but were afraid to ask),” October1999, p. 3.

105 Ibid., p. 5.106 The preambular language comes into play “where the mean-

ing imparted by the text itself is equivocal or inconclusive,or where confirmation of the correctness of the reading ofthe text itself is desired, light from the object and purpose ofthe treaty as a whole may usefully be sought.” World TradeOrganization, “United States - Import Prohibition Of Cer-tain Shrimp And Shrimp Products,” Report of the AppellateBody, 12 October 1998, WT/DS58/AB/R. para. 114.

107 Cf. Ibid., para. 153.108 We are indebted to Elisabeth Tuerk of the Centre for Interna-

tional Environmental Law for this point.109 GATS Preamble.110 See Part II of the GATS, “General Obligations and Disci-

plines.” Cf. WTO Secretariat, Trade in Services Division, “AnIntroduction to the GATS,” October 1999, p. 4.

111 Transparency is, in most respects, an unproblematic obliga-tion. Most governments routinely publish changes in rulesand regulations as a matter of course under domestic law.Certain GATS 2000 negotiating proposals, however, wouldgo beyond simple transparency—for example, by requiringprior notification of regulations that affect foreign serviceproviders. Such prior comment requirements could skew

Page 114: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 95

domestic decision-making by giving multinational commer-cial interests greater rights than domestic interests such asconsumer, environmental and public interest groups. Priornotification would give already powerful commercial inter-ests a leg up in the policy debate—an opportunity to mobi-lize earlier and externally against regulatory initiatives theyoppose.

112 Fact and Fiction, p. 9.113 The WTO’s Appellate Body later set aside the panel’s find-

ings on MFN. In doing so, it emphasized that it had not ruledthat Canada’s measures were consistent with the GATS MFNruling, but simply that the panel’s reasoning on this matterwas flawed. In the decision’s concluding passage, the AB ob-served that “Given the complexity of the subject-matter oftrade in services, as well as the newness of the obligationsunder the GATS, we believe that claims made under the GATSdeserve close attention and serious analysis. We leave inter-pretation of Article II of the GATS to another case and an-other day.” “Canada – Certain Measures Affecting the Auto-motive Industry,” Report of the Appellate Body, 31 May 2000,WT/DS139/AB/R, WT/DS142/AB/R. Section IX. B.

114 See the GATS section of “Trading Into the Future,” an on-line guide to the WTO Agreements, available on the WTOweb site (http://www.wto.org).

115 For example, insurance services were a major stumbling blockduring protracted negotiations to finalize China’s accessionto the WTO. China wanted to cap foreign ownership of lifeinsurers at 50%. But a single US company, New York-basedAmerican International Group (AIG), which has been presentin China since 1992, owned 100% of its Chinese ventures.The EC insisted that under MFN China must either limit AIGto 50% or extend the right to full ownership to European andother foreign service providers. US trade officials complainedthat the EU was seeking a “most favoured company treat-ment.” “China Challenges US Interpretation of InsuranceProvision in WTO Talks,” BNA WTO Reporter, July 20, 2001.This dispute was fudged in the final accession deal, with AIGclaiming that it will be able to expand its existing branchoperations on the basis of its current 100% ownership struc-ture, and the Chinese chief negotiator stating that China re-tained the right to limit all new insurance ventures to 50%.

Page 115: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

96 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Because of MFN, European insurers are satisfied that, which-ever way the US-China dispute is settled, they will be enti-tled the best treatment given AIG. “Insurance AgreementEnds Stalemate on China’s Accession to WTO,” BNA WTOReporter, September 18, 2001.

116 Markets Matter, para. 77.117 Rudolph Adlung, “Services Trade Liberalization: Developed

and Developing Country Perspectives, in Sauvé and Stern,op. cit., p. 121, n.20.

118 Although freer trade can create powerful competitive pres-sures to harmonize.

119 CF. GATS Article XVII, para. 3.120 For example, the complainants in the Auto Pact case noted

that “the national treatment obligation in Article XVII of theGATS … protects competitive opportunities, not actual tradeflows.” The panel agreed. It found that even though therewas little or no existing cross-border supply, and that it mightbe impractical to supply certain services on a cross-borderbasis from Europe and Japan to the Canadian auto industry,that “any eventual inherent disadvantages due to the for-eign character of services supplied through modes 1 and 2do not exempt Canada from its national treatment obliga-tion with respect to the Canadian value added requirements(Canadian Autos, para. 10.301). The panel also noted, withpalpable relish, that even if the Canadian value-added re-quirements were currently met, as the Canadian governmentargued, on the basis of GATS-consistent labour costs alone,there could still be a hypothetical, discriminatory effect infuture (Canadian Autos, op. cit., para. 10.303).

121 See note 38 above.122 All these examples are drawn from non-conforming meas-

ures listed as limitations to national treatment in the Cana-dian and US GATS schedules or from illustrations of incon-sistent measures in the GATS scheduling guidelines (S/CSC/W/19).

123 Many free traders complain that incorporating environmen-tal and social considerations into trade deals risks “disguisedprotectionism,” that is economic protectionism in the guiseof environmental activism or social welfare concerns. Butcasting the net of trade treaty restrictions so widely that theycatch non-trade-related regulatory initiatives invites “dis-

Page 116: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 97

guised deregulation” – opposition to environmental and so-cial policy regulation in the guise of pro-trade sentiments.

124 Monopolies and exclusive service suppliers are also GATS-inconsistent restrictions on “the number of services suppli-ers.”

125 GATS Article XVI.126 NAFTA Article 1207 provides for further negotiations on these

lists, but these have never occurred. Local government meas-ures need not be listed.

127 Markets Matter describes Article XVI (Market Access) as oneof “the two key liberalizing principles of the GATS (para.80).” It briefly describes the market access provisions andthen never discusses them directly again. There is no analy-sis of the impacts of this key article, its policy implications,or the critics’ concerns about it.

128 World Trade Organization, “Article VI:4 Of The GATS: Dis-ciplines On Domestic Regulation Applicable To All Services.”Note by the Secretariat, S/C/W/96, 1 March 1999, para. 14.

129 GATS Article XX.130 WTO, Committee on Specific Commitments, “Revision of

Scheduling Guidelines: Note by the Secretariat,” 5 March1999, S/CSC/W/19, p. 6.

131 Ibid., p. 6.132 Fact and Fiction, p. 10.133 See, for example, Metalclad Corporation vs. Mexico where a

US investor successfully argued that the rejection by a Mexi-can municipality of a permit for a hazardous waste facilityand a state government decree establishing an ecological re-serve in the area where the hazardous waste facility was lo-cated violated the NAFTA investment protection provisions.See also Ethyl Corporation’s successful claim, settled outsidethe arbitration, that a ban on a Canadian gasoline additive,MMT violated NAFTA and S.D. Myer’s successful claim thata temporary Canadian ban on the export of toxic PCBsbreached NAFTA’s investment chapter. There are a signifi-cant number of other controversial claims that have yet to bedecided, including challenges to: California’s phase-out ofthe gasoline additive MTBE, a Canadian phase-out of an ag-ricultural pesticide, the operations of the Canadian publicpostal services, US municipal planning decisions, US federal

Page 117: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

98 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

procurement practices, and the awarding of punitive dam-ages by a US jury, among others.

134 The most contentious NAFTA articles have been Article 1110(Expropriation and Compensation), Article 1105 (MinimumStandards of Treatment), and Article 1106 (Performance Re-quirements). Like GATS Articles XVI and the restrictions in-tended to be developed under GATS Article VI, all are draftedin absolute terms, prohibiting certain practices, whether dis-criminatory or not.

135 The GATS information session, organized by the Departmentof Foreign Affairs and International Trade, took place in Ot-tawa on May 4, 2000. The informal meeting with WTO serv-ices officials took place at the WTO Geneva offices on No-vember 30, 2000. See also note 95 above.

136 The GATS Telecommunications Reference Paper, whichelaborates sector-specific obligations for telecommunications,provides that “any procedures for the allocation and use ofscarce resources, including frequencies, numbers and rightsof way, will be carried out in an objective, timely, transpar-ent and non-discriminatory manner. …”

137 As summarized by the WTO secretariat, GATS Article VIIIrequires that “a monopoly supplier of a service must not beallowed to act inconsistently with a member government’sMFN obligations or any specific commitments, nor to abuseits monopoly position,” An Introduction to the GATS, op.cit., p. 6.

138 Fact and Fiction, p. 10.139 Markets Matter, para. 89.140 Surely, rather than stating that governments “retain the right

to designate or maintain monopolies,” it would be more ac-curate to say that “the GATS restricts or qualifies govern-ments’ right to designate monopolies.”

141 See Perrazzelli, Alessandra and Paolo R. Vergano (2000), “Ter-minal Dues Under The UPU Convention And The GATS: AnOverview Of The Rules And Of Their Compatibility.” FordhamInternational Law Journal, Vol. 23:736. and “US Postal Service:Unresolved Issues In The International Mail Market,” U.S.General Accounting Office, GAO/GGD-96-51, March 1996.

142 The GATS restrictions against “abuse of monopoly position”do not define the key term “abuse.” The chief US GATS ne-gotiator during the Uruguay Round noted that “After con-

Page 118: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 99

siderable debate, ‘abuse’ was left undefined …” Richard B.Self, “General Agreement on Trade in Services,” in TerenceB. Stewart, ed. The World Trade Organization: the MultilateralTrade Framework for the 21st Century and US Implementing Leg-islation, Washington, American Bar Association, 1996, p. 532-3.

143 See Appleton and Associates, “Notice of Intent, United Par-cel Service of America Inc. v. Canada,” January 19, 2000, avail-able at http://www.dfait-maeci.gc.ca/tna-nac/NAFTA-e.asp#Notes. For further discussion of this NAFTA claim andits relation to the GATS, see Scott Sinclair, “The GATS andCanadian Postal Services,” Canadian Centre for Policy Al-ternatives, March 2001, available at http://www.policyalternatives.ca.

144 To be technologically up-to-date and financially viable na-tional post offices must be active in providing services thatcomplement their primary focus on letter-mail. This invari-ably brings them into competition with private courier com-panies.

145 NAFTA Article 1502.3.d states that NAFTA parties must en-sure that any monopoly “does not use its monopoly positionto engage … in anticompetitive practices in a non-monopo-lized market …”. It is not clear that investors have the rightto invoke directly this particular provision of NAFTA as UPSis attempting. However, a government-initiated dispute onbehalf of courier companies, whether under NAFTA or theGATS, would have clear recourse to these agreements’ re-spective anti-monopoly provisions.

146 In the GATS context, as discussed elsewhere, compensationtakes the form either of adjustments to a country’s GATSschedule or, if a negotiated settlement cannot be reached, oftrade sanctions.

147 For further discussion of this issue see Mathew Sanger, Reck-less Abandon: Canada, The GATS and the Future of Health Care,Ottawa, Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2001, esp.pp. 77-90.

148 Insurance providers would have the opportunity to maketheir case against such a change in the policy debate and inthe domestic courts like all other interested parties. In Canada,domestic courts have rejected the view that expanding a pub-lic monopoly must result in governments paying compensa-

Page 119: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

100 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

tion to affected investors. This has generally been treated asa commercial risk that is not necessarily compensable. Forexample, in a 1986 case a private home care company arguedthat it should be compensated because its business was ad-versely affected by a decision by the Manitoba governmentto directly provide home care through the public sector. TheCourt disagreed, stating that “Government decisions of thesort in issue have serious private repercussions, but they areessentially political choices made with justifiable impunityin the pubic interest as perceived by the elected government…”. Home Orderly services, et al. vs. Government of Mani-toba (1987) D.L.R. (4th) p. 365, quoted in Mathew Sanger,Reckless Abandon, Canada, the GATS and the Future of HealthCare, op. cit., p. 107.

149 Markets Matter, para. 95.150 See GATS Article VI.4 and “Application of the Necessity Test:

Issues for Consideration,” Working Party on Domestic Regu-lation, Informal Note by the Secretariat. Job No. 5929. 2 May,2000.

151 Cf. Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., pp. 75-81.152 OECD, “The General Agreement on Trade in Services: An

Analysis,” op. cit., p. 16.153 World Trade Organization, Working Party on Professional

Services, “The Relevance of the Disciplines of the Agreementson Technical Barriers to Trade and on Import Licensing toArticle VI.4 of the GATS,” Note by the Secretariat, 11 Sep-tember 1996 (S/WPPS/W/9).

154 “Application of the Necessity Test: Issues for Consideration,”op. cit., 2 May 2000.

155 World Trade Organization, Council for Trade in Services, “Ar-ticle VI.4 of the GATS: Disciplines on Domestic RegulationApplicable to all Services,” Note by the Secretariat, March 1,1999, para. 27 (S/C/W/96).

156 Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., p. 10.157 Fact and Fiction, p. 15.158 Professor Robert Stumberg made this point in his remarks to

a recent symposium. Robert Stumberg, Remarks, Royal So-ciety of Canada symposium on the WTO, November 17, 2001,Ottawa.

159 “Application of the Necessity Test: Issues for Consideration.”op. cit.

Page 120: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 101

160 “The right to maintain domestic regulatory measures is how-ever specifically recognized and will be subject to the disci-plines to be developed under Article VI:4 with the aim ofminimizing their negative impact on trade. These measurescannot be entered as limitations in a Member’s schedule.”Ibid., para. 13.

161 An OECD analysis notes that “there is a fine, and indeed notalways clear line between de jure non-discriminatory regu-lations which may be scheduled as limitations to nationaltreatment under Article XVII because of their de facto dis-criminatory effect, and those which are to be treated as con-trary to Article VI on domestic regulations because they are‘unnecessarily burdensome.’ For instance, if the issuing of alicense requires prior residency, such a requirement mighthave to be scheduled under Article XVII as a de facto dis-crimination, being less likely to be met by foreign nationals.But it could also be assessed, depending on the circumstances,as ‘unnecessarily burdensome’ under Article VI (5) – in whichcase it might have to be abandoned all together.” The Gen-eral Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS): An Analysis,op. cit., para. 61.

162 Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., p. 79.163 Hoekman, Bernard and Messerlin, Patrick A., Liberalizing

Trade in Services: From Reciprocal Negotiation to DomesticRegulatory Reform, Draft paper presented at the “Services2000: New Directions in Services Trade Liberalization” Con-ference at the University Club in Washington, D.C., 1-2 June1999, p 1-2.

164 Prior to the Doha Ministerial, and subsequently, a number ofsouthern governments have called for a thorough assessmentof trade in services. Sensibly, these proposals insist that “fur-ther [GATS] negotiations may only commence after conclu-sions from this first assessment have been drawn, and nego-tiations should be adjusted in accordance with these conclu-sions.” See Communication from Cuba, Dominican Repub-lic, Haiti, India, Kenya, Pakistan, Peru, Uganda, Venezuelaand Zimbabwe, “Assessment of Trade in Services,” 9 Octo-ber 2001, S/CSS/W114 and Communication for Cuba, Sen-egal, Tanzania, Uganda, Zimbabwe and Zambia, “Assess-ment of Trade in Services,” 6 December, 2001, S/CSS/W/132.

Page 121: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

102 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

165 Address given by Mr. Renato Ruggiero, Director-General ofthe World Trade Organization, (2 June 1998) in Brussels, tothe Conference on Trade in Services, organized by the Euro-pean Commission.

166 Lang, Jeffrey and Charles D. Lake II, “The First Five Years OfThe WTO: General Agreement On Trade In Services,” Law &Policy in International Business, Spring 2000, Vol. 31.

167 The three cases are EC Bananas, Canada Autos and CanadaPeriodicals. See, “European Communities - Regime for theImportation, Sale and Distribution of Bananas: Complaintby the United States” Report of the Panel, 22 May 1997, WT/DS27/R/USA; “Canada: Certain Measures Affecting theAutomotive Industry,” Report of the Appellate Body, 31 May,2000, WT/DS139/AB/R, WT/DS142/AB/R; and “Canada -Certain Measures Concerning Periodicals,” Panel Report, 14March 1997, WT/DS31/R. For a summary and analysis ofeach case, see Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., chapter 3.

168 Five key themes emerge from the jurisprudence to date: 1)The GATS applies to any measure; 2) The GATS prohibits defacto discrimination; 3) The GATS is “modally neutral;” 4)WTO restrictions on goods and services are overlapping; and5) Exceptions will be interpreted narrowly. The interpreta-tion of GATS by dispute panels and the Appellate Body isanalyzed in Chapter 3 of Sinclair, 2000, op. cit..

169 Warming to his theme of “overwhelming uncertainty,” Langelaborated: “It gets worse. There is another half to the GATScommitment system, the specific sectoral commitments,which are contained in special schedules, and the provisionsthat surround them, called annexes. … The main difficultywith these provisions is the difficulty of reading them, muchless interpreting them. The reading and writing of good tar-iff schedules was always something of an art, but the serviceschedules make this skill less art than fetish.” Lang, op. cit.

170 Ibid.171 Michael Moore, “Speaking Points to the ICFTU Conference

on Making Globalization work for People: Development andWorkers’ Rights,” Doha, Qatar, November 8, 2001.

172 Estimates for health spending are from the World Health Or-ganization. For education from Michael T. Moe and HenryBlodget, “The Knowledge Web: People Power—Fuel For TheNew Economy,” by Merrill Lynch Global Securities Research

Page 122: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 103

And Economics Group, May 23, 2000. For electricity fromMarjorie Griffin Cohen, “From Public Good to Private Ex-ploitation: The Deregulation of Electricity and the GATS,”Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, forthcoming, 2002.For postal and courier services from the Canadian Union OfPostal Workers, Research Department, based on Manner-Romberg-Unternehmensberatung, “Demand for Communi-cation: The increasing need for ways of efficient communi-cation within the courier, express and postal markets,” June2001, and Universal Postal Union figures.

173 Communication from Cuba, Senegal, Tanzania, Uganda, Zim-babwe and Zambia, “Assessment of Trade in Services,” 6December, 2001, S/CSS/W/132, para. 8.

174 Sinclair, 2000, op. cit., p. 94.175 Paragraph 7 of the Ministerial Declaration “reaffirms the right

of Members under the General Agreement on Trade in serv-ices to regulate, and to introduce new regulations on, thesupply of services.” “Ministerial Declaration,” Fourth Min-isterial Conference, Doha, Qatar, November 9-13, 2001. Thisreaffirmation adds nothing to the similar recital in the GATSpreamble and has the same shortcomings.

176 The analogy is that like a bicycle, multilateral trade negotia-tions must continue to go forward; if they slow down or stop,the bicycle will fall over.

177 Doha Ministerial Declaration, op. cit., para. 15.178 Susan George, Remarks, Royal Society of Canada symposium

on the WTO, November 17, 2001, Ottawa.

Page 123: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

104 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Page 124: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 105

Appendix 1:List of acronyms

CCPA Canadian Centre for Policy AlternativesCPC Central Product ClassificationEC European CommunitiesGATT General Agreement on Tariffs and TradeGATS General Agreement on Trade in ServicesMAI Multilateral Agreement on InvestmentMFN Most Favoured NationNAFTA North American Free Trade AgreementNGOs Non-Governmental OrganizationsOECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and

DevelopmentUPU Universal Postal UnionUSTR United States Trade RepresentativeWPDR Working Party on Domestic RegulationWTO World Trade Organization

Page 125: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

106 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Page 126: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 107

Appendix 2:Glossary of key GATS terms

Commercial presence mode: applies to services providedby a foreign service supplier through investment in theterritory of another member. This ensures the right of for-eign firms to establish a commercial presence in a foreigncountry, for example through branches, subsidiaries, of-fices, or any type of business or professional establish-ment.

Consumption abroad mode: applies to services consumedby citizens or firms of one member country in the terri-tory of another member where the service is supplied.Essentially, the service is supplied to the consumer out-side the territory of the member where the consumer re-sides. Examples include tourism, students studyingabroad, or patients travelling to a foreign country to getmedical treatment.

Country schedule: each member government has aunique annex to the GATS that sets out the sectors that ithas agreed to cover under the national treatment andmarket access provisions of the GATS. The schedule liststhe sectors where a member has taken specific commit-ments as well as any limitations on commitments withinthose sectors. These annexes are an integral part of theGATS.

Cross-border mode: applies to services provided from theterritory of one member into that of another. Only the serv-ice itself crosses the border, without the movement of per-

Page 127: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

108 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

sons or investment. The service supplier does not estab-lish any presence in the territory of the member wherethe service is consumed. Examples include informationor advice provided through fax, phone or electronicmeans. This ensures the right of a foreign service sup-plier to supply services cross-border without having toestablish locally.

De jure treatment: cases where government measures giveforeign service suppliers and services formally identicallegal treatment to that offered to their domestic (nationaltreatment) or foreign (MFN) counterparts.

De facto treatment: Cases where government measuresthat treat service suppliers and services alike neverthe-less allegedly modify the conditions of competition in fa-vour of domestic services or service suppliers (nationaltreatment) or in favour of certain foreign services andservice providers compared to others (MFN). The GATSguarantees de facto treatment, which is sometimes referredto as “equality of competitive opportunity.”

Dispute settlement: GATS disputes are settled under thegeneral dispute settlement rules of the WTO. WTO dis-pute settlement decisions are binding. If a governmentthat loses a case fails to bring its inconsistent measuresinto conformity with the GATS within a reasonable pe-riod, the complaining party can try to negotiate satisfac-tory compensation. If no satisfactory compensation canbe negotiated, the complainant can impose equivalenttrade penalties on the offending member. The WTO al-lows “cross retaliation” so penalties may be imposed ontrade in any area.

Page 128: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 109

Domestic regulation: The GATS calls for further negotia-tions to ensure that “qualification requirements and pro-cedures, technical standards and licensing requirements”do not constitute “unnecessary” barriers to trade in serv-ices. The intended restrictions would apply to non-dis-criminatory government measures and allow WTO pan-els to decide whether such measures were based on trans-parent and objective criteria and not more burdensomethan necessary to achieve their stated objective. Theseproposed restrictions are intended to apply generally toall services and all member governments.

Exceptions: Certain measures that are otherwise incon-sistent with GATS rules can still be maintained if the gov-ernment taking the measure can demonstrate to a WTOpanel that it falls within the parameters of a GATS excep-tion (e.g. GATS Article XIV). Such exceptions will be in-terpreted narrowly.

Formula approaches: are a type of horizontal negotiat-ing approach. They do not aim to develop new rules tobe incorporated into the GATS text, but are binding ne-gotiating guidelines —for example, an agreement to makespecific commitments in every sector or to eliminate alllimitations in certain sectors.

General obligations: GATS obligations (such as MFN ortransparency) that apply automatically and uncondition-ally to all member governments across all service sectors.General obligations apply regardless of a member gov-ernment’s specific commitments. (General obligationsapply “horizontally” and are sometimes referred to as“horizontal obligations.”)

Page 129: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

110 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Government procurement: The GATS does not definegovernment procurement other than stating that it mustbe “for governmental purposes.” Although definitionsdiffer in different countries, government procurement isusually defined as governmental purchasing of goods,services or construction for the direct use or benefit ofgovernments.

Horizontal negotiating approaches: refers to the nego-tiation of crosscutting commitments that would applyacross members, sectors and/or modes of supply. Thesemight include developing new horizontal rules orstrengthening GATS rules that already apply horizontally.They might also include so-called “formula approaches.”

“In the exercise of governmental authority:” The GATSapplies to all services except those provided “in the exer-cise of governmental authority.” This has been definednarrowly to mean only those services that are providedneither on a commercial basis nor in competition withother service suppliers.

Limitations: refer to notes in a country’s schedule thatlimit, or qualify, the application of the GATS nationaltreatment or market access provisions within coveredsectors —for example, by exempting an existing, other-wise inconsistent, measure.

Market access: Market access has two meanings in theGATS. First, in a general sense, it refers to the right of aservice supplier to supply a service through any of thefour modes of supply. More specifically, it refers to GATSArticle XVI, which prohibits government measures that

Page 130: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 111

limit the number of service operations, the value of serv-ice transactions or assets, the number of operations orquantity of output, the number of persons supplying aservice and the participation of foreign capital, and alsoany requirements for specific types of legal entities. Suchmeasures are absolutely prohibited; that is, they are GATS-illegal even if they apply equally to foreign and domesticservice suppliers.

Measures: government laws, regulations, rules, proce-dures, decisions, administrative actions, and any otherform of government action affecting “trade in services.”The GATS covers measures by all levels of governmentand any non-governmental bodies exercising authoritydelegated by government.

Most-favoured-nation (MFN) treatment: requires thatgovernments “immediately and unconditionally” extendthe best treatment given to any foreign services or serv-ices suppliers to all like foreign services and service sup-pliers, both in law (de jure) and in fact (de facto).

National treatment: requires that governments give for-eign services and service providers the best treatmentgiven to like domestic services and service suppliers, bothin law (de jure) and in fact (de facto).

Natural persons mode: applies to services provided bynationals of one member who travel to another membercountry to provide a service. This mode applies only toreal, flesh-and-blood persons (as opposed to “legal per-sons,” that is, corporations). This mode ensures the rightof “natural persons” to stay temporarily in another coun-

Page 131: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

112 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

try for the purpose of supplying services; for example,executives, consultants, or engineers who travel abroadfor business purposes.

Necessary: Under the intended restrictions on domesticregulation, non-discriminatory government regulationsmust not “constitute unnecessary barriers to trade in serv-ices.” Governments would have to demonstrate that regu-lations were “necessary” to achieve a WTO-sanctionedlegitimate objective. A government could not justify aregulation as necessary if there were an alternative onethat was less burdensome on trade in services. If the onlyregulatory measures that were reasonably available wereall burdensome, then the government would have toemploy the measure that was least burdensome.

Safeguards: refer to emergency actions intended to pro-vide temporary protection against “fairly traded” prod-ucts that cause or threaten to cause serious injury to do-mestic producers. Safeguards are permitted under theGATT rules on goods but would be a new concept underthe GATS.

Service: The GATS does not define a service. Broadly de-fined, a service is a product of human activity aimed tosatisfy a human need, which does not constitute a tangi-ble commodity.

Specific commitments: The GATS national treatment andmarket access provisions apply only to those sectors thateach government has listed in its country schedule. Theselisted commitments are referred to as specific commit-ments.

Page 132: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Facing the Facts 113

Subsidies: The GATS does not define subsidies. The GATTrules on goods define a subsidy as a financial contribu-tion (or any form of income or price support) by a gov-ernment, or any public body within the territory of a mem-ber, which confers a benefit.

“Trade in services:” The GATS defines this very broadlyto include services supplied through every mode of sup-ply whether through cross-border transactions, consumertravel, foreign investment, or labour mobility. The fourmodes of supply are called “cross-border,” “consump-tion abroad,” “commercial presence” and “movement ofnatural persons.”

Transparency: the requirement that member governmentsmake publicly available their laws, regulations, proce-dures, administrative rulings and judicial decisions. Thereare negotiating proposals to extend this concept to pro-vide rights to foreign governments to be consulted ongovernment measures affecting services both before andafter they are introduced.

Page 133: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

114 Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives

Page 134: A guide to the GATS debate - Public Citizen€¦ · GATS obligations only apply to sectors that governments ex-plicitly agree to cover, there are serious limits to this flexibility.

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternativeshttp://www.policyalternatives.ca

ISBN 0-88627-278-5

The GATS debate is heating up.

Non-governmental organizations have lifted the veil of obscurity on the little-known General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). To counter the growingpublic opposition that has resulted, the WTO and OECD recently published twobooklets trying to reassure citizens and governments about what they call GATS“scare stories.”

This book critiques these official responses. Meticulous and clear, it explains thepractical implications of key features of the GATS, showing how the WTO andOECD reassurances are frequently simplistic or misleading. The book demon-strates that the key concerns of critics are well-founded: the GATS does in factthreaten essential public service systems and public interest regulation.

The GATS – and the negotiations now underway to expand it – are certain to behotly contested during the broad new round of WTO negotiations. This timelybook will be an essential resource for researchers, academics, policy-makers,activists and ordinary citizens as the debate about the GATS comes to a boil.

Scott Sinclair is a Canadian trade policy specialist with extensive internationaltrade policy expertise and experience. Author of the influential book “GATS:How the World Trade Organization’s new ‘services’ negotiations threaten democracy”, he is currently a senior research associate with the CanadianCentre for Policy Alternatives.

Jim Grieshaber-Otto, Ph. D. is an independent trade policy consultant based nearVancouver, British Columbia, Canada. His recent work focuses on the impact ofthe GATS on health-based alcohol regulation and on public education and otherpublic service systems.

$14.95