A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

download A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

of 7

Transcript of A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    1/7

    Production functions that combine material, capital, labor, and energy in a single

    algebraic expression reveal how entrenched economic methodology misapprehends

    reality. Everyone familiar with natural resource economics has seen equations likeY = F (M, K, L, E), where Y is the maximum level of output obtainable during a period

    via implied technique (F), from a given amount of raw material (M), capital services (K),

    labor (L), and energy (E) .

    Can energy be considered just another element in the input vector? Can it be treated as an

    independent variable in the same category as capital and labor? Hardly, yet discussionsabout the impact energy prices have on economic performance begin with such

    formulations. They show up in print and pixel, adorn slides and blackboards as symbols

    of pure logic cleansed from heterodox critique and the trappings of popular rhetoric.

    Explicit and abiding reliance on them -- as if they were axioms of Euclidean geometry --bears some responsibility for separating science from common reason and for abetting the

    unbroken effort to rationalize away the dangers inherent in losing the worlds easiest

    accessible and most potent energy carrier -- crude oil.

    Differentiation and simple manipulation of production functions are used to calculate the

    energy elasticity of output, the price elasticity of energy, the elasticity of substitutionamong resources, or losses incurred as a result of increasing energy/oil/gasoline prices.

    Factor proportions (intensities) are ever-present terms in all such calculations. They are

    the bait that fugitives from independent thinking keep swallowing year after year.

    Namely, the shares of energy, oil, and gasoline in the GDP are low, particularly in

    developed economies. U.S. energy expenditures, for example, stayed below 10 percent of

    the GDP during the past two decades while the national petroleum bill remained in the 4-6-percent range. Economic commentary revolves around these numbers, celebrating their

    lowness as a triumph of technology and the relentless drive for profit.

    The small share of natural resources in aggregate expenditures is not one hundred

    percent good news. The neoclassical prediction apparatus is false.

    Low energy shares indicate increased specialization. The variety of products and services

    widens and production becomes more roundabout, i.e., the vertical chain of

    intermediary stations lengthens. But beware! The study of biological evolution has shown

    that nature selects against rapid growth accompanied by a high degree of specialization.Growing demand on depleting resources brings inflexibility in a way that is ignored by

    conventional economics.

    The reciprocal of those low energy, oil, and gasoline shares would be an equally

    important indicator to describe the state of the world. It would show the extent to which

    material welfare has become vulnerable to the availability of extrasomatic energy inadequate quantities and at non-disruptive marginal costs. Detachment from nature is an

    illusion, not liberation. If the perspective of analysis is appropriately wide, factually

    relevant losses always appear to follow gains previously presumed to be pure.

    1

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    2/7

    To appreciate why the significance of energy/oil price hikes is understated and spuriously

    quantified when a function such as the one quoted becomes the theoretical basis of

    econometric work, we need to climb to a higher altitude of abstraction.

    Production is a process whereby labor expands somatic energy to mobilize

    extrasomatic energy for the purpose of operating physical capital, which, in turn,represents the potential to perform tasks beyond human biological ability and

    capacity.

    E in the production function stands for the medium of transmission that labor deploys

    to animate physical capital. It is the electricity used by the carpenter, the auto worker, the

    supermarket clerk, the dentist (all expanders of somatic energy, i.e., labor) to operate the

    chain saw, the assembly line, the store, and the high-speed drill. It is gasoline (with itsenergy stored in chemical bonds) which, upon burning, allows the driver to steer the

    truck, the car, the tractor.

    Extrasomatic energy can be measured in units of Human Energy Equivalent (HEE) -- agood yardstick of economic development. At the dawn of civilization HEE was zero. It

    grew gradually over tens of thousands of years and accelerated during the industrial age.According to ecological economists M. Common and S. Stagl, the average per capita

    HEE is now around 20, with a huge spread of above 90 for the most and below 10 for the

    least developed countries.

    It is clear that without an uninterrupted flow of extrasomatic energy from the

    environment into the economic system, the scientific-technological know-how

    symbolized by F would be lifeless. However, given the low share or intensity of E,it is much less obvious how unbreakable the historical correlation between the level of

    output and extrasomatic energy really is. Conserving carriers and enhancing their

    productivity (efficiency) -- although desirable goals -- help only within narrow limits andtemporarily.

    If a heuristic analytical model had to be chosen to illustrate the relationship between Eand the rest of the inputs at the global level, perhaps theLeontief production function,

    which presumes fixed proportions (i.e., between E and all other factors) and no

    substitution between the two vectors would best describe the unique role extrasomatic

    energy plays.

    E is not simply one of the guys among factors of production.

    Treating E as if it were on equal footing with other resources is what philosophers call

    a category mistake, a term psychiatrists borrowed to characterize symptoms of mental

    illness, e.g., the man goes to the cleaners and orders a Big Mac.

    In contrast to raw materials, capital equipment, and labor skills, which can be arbitrarily

    varied as technology evolves or changes in response to relative factor prices, energy is an

    irreplaceable complement with a high degree of homogeneity. Substitution among its

    2

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    3/7

    specific forms (i.e., heat, chemical, mechanical, electromagnetic, or nuclear energy) is

    limited and very slow.

    A significant shift among the ways work (change in kinetic energy) is obtained affects the

    entire industrial infrastructure. The spectrum of difficulties facing the introduction of

    electric cars on a mass scale (substitution of electromagnetic for chemical energy) is atelling example.

    E may be comparable to the energy living organisms need to exist.

    Lifes intrinsic tendency toward copious variation is accompanied by a supremely

    universal process of sucking free energy from the environment. In the context of the

    production function, while the economy is wide open to the development of possibilitiesin one sense, it remains virtually closed in another. We can create infinitely many things

    in infinitely many ways, but the actual production process remains bound to the

    requirement of metabolizing energy sources in proportions that remain largely insensitive

    to market signals.

    Energy carriers (or, for that matter, any other natural resource, e.g., oil as material input,copper or timber) saved through conservation or efficiency appear to the economic

    system as new reserves. The incentive to draft them into production is bound up with an

    overweening pressure for output maximization, a momentum unstoppable by

    environmental advocacy. GDP growth rate -- the higher the better -- remains the singlemost important indicator whereby national governments are judged. More output is

    associated with job creation and improved living standards.

    If the fuel efficiency of combustion engines doubles, twice as many vehicles will be

    produced. If energy-efficient buildings will be constructed and people become conscious

    about using electricity in their homes, the natural gas saved will show up on supermarketand department store shelves as refined product inputs in tens of thousands of consumer

    goods, from electrical appliances to shiny plastic dishes, aspirins and their containers, all

    the way to the asphalt on the parking lot.

    Upon giving due consideration to the structural inelasticity among forms of energy and

    the sustained tendency to gobble up substances saved through conservation and

    efficiency, we can see that the demand for the medium of transmission from somaticenergy to physical capital is bound to grow, making the world economy increasingly

    vulnerable to its price and availability.

    The rising value of extrasomatic energy becomes a drag on growth.

    Energy derived from nonrenewable sources is slated to demand increasing bundles ofresources, making them unavailable to produce what the world really wants. Costs will

    increase across the board. In Econ-101 speak; supply curves will shift upwards to the left,

    indicating smaller amounts being supplied at any given price. In practical terms, washing

    machines, as well as the electricity to run them, will become more expensive.

    3

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    4/7

    Having entered the temporal zone of peak oil -- a period of history when the nearness of

    the de facto maximum of worldwide oil production exerts a decisive influence on globaleconomic performance -- is the leading indicator that the depletion of material

    resources has begun to constrain the spontaneous multiplication of productive activities.

    Indeed, it would be salutary for the international community to remember that oil is not

    just another commodity traded along with bauxite, coffee, pork bellies, and gold.

    It is interesting (that is, if you are into econ lit) to look back at the struggle of

    economists in the 1950s to reconcile the mathematics of smooth and endless expansion

    with theLeontief technology that allows no substitution between some groups of

    resources. It is a credit to their perspicacity that they saw the inevitability of chaoticdevelopments and breakdowns when the neo-orthodox conditions of virtually

    uninterrupted growth change into the current ones; that is, when Leontiefs growth-

    limiting, fixed-proportion, numerically-based model acquires practical relevance.

    Depletion of conventional oil challenges economic organization.

    The question is plain but historic: Can existing institutions (including property relations

    and forms/patterns of distribution) and a largely short-run profit-based problem-solving

    mechanism generate the dynamism required to break through the growth-constraining

    rise in the share of extrasomatic energy in the global production function?

    Those who say yes emphasize the plethora of business opportunities that the need to

    rely on more expensive supplies of oil (e.g., from the arctic region and deep seas),unconventional oil (i.e., shale, sand-based crude, liquids obtained from coal, biomass, and

    natural gas processing), and alternative sources of energy will bring. They believe that

    private entrepreneurship, mans engineering genius, and a minimalist government is thebest medicine to cure any shortage -- if such ailment exists at all. History shows an

    inevitable progress toward the ever-more plenty.

    Market debacle in energy transition

    Dismissal of this pious first principle begins by underscoring that the era of cheap

    extrasomatic energy is over and that such a critical juncture was in the cards all along.The coupling of unlimited material ends with the means of limiting each others gains to

    achieve it (i.e., gladiatorial rivalry for shares in markets that were once imperfect but by

    now are venal) defines a system that is indifferent to the finiteness of space, materialendowments, and absorbing capacity. And as the statistics of highway fatalities illustrate,

    inattentiveness and full-tilt rush is a combination with consequences.

    The motive of maximizing private gains is a winner as long as societys explicit goal is

    the mass-provision of goods and services. Firm-level competition tends to optimize the

    employment of factors and the resultant dynamism keeps the engine of resource

    expansion humming. But when the implicit need to supply more expensive energy begins

    4

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    5/7

    to affect economic performance, the market-signal-based nexus between wants and their

    satisfaction loses traction; it becomes a fortuitous hash of stop-and-go actions and wait-

    and-see inactions.

    Without that much maligned and dreaded public interference (some form of government

    handout), the last thing that would emerge from a corporate boardroom is the decision tosecure a loan (pledging real property and blue chip stocks as collateral) in order to invest

    in solar energy that could be sold profitably only when the price of oil rises to the same

    level that upended the economy in late 2007.

    When the exchange value of E reaches output- and employment-damaging heights, the

    system is unable to direct resources released by the setback toward the broad goals of

    energy and environmental sustainability.

    Ecology as a comprehensive and multifold obstacle to economic growth is revealing its

    presence by nullifying efforts to overcome it. Nothing keeps oil prices somewhere

    between the obscenely high and the tolerably modest in order to encourage investment innonconventional oil and other energy sources. The financial crisis, which is closely tied

    to self-feeding excesses in oil trade, has weakened both ability and appetite to underwriteenergy infrastructure development. Fiscal and monetary policy pedals have been pushed

    and are being pressed to the metal to no avail.

    The jury is still out -- but not much longer -- on the aptitude of national governments toescape from economic policy traps and overcome institutional rigidities (vigilantly

    guarded by trenchant private interests) in order to steer the structure of energy supplies in

    the desired direction.

    A fundamental rift separates the present from the past.

    The singularity inherent in having left thesans souci puberty of ingesting and egesting

    nonrenewable resources as if they were poured from a magically self-replenishing

    container (call it the Global Strategic Energy and Material Reserve) broke thesymmetry between the past and the future.

    The relevance of projecting forward what lies backward has waned. But, of course, the

    recognition that the world economy has about as much chance to outgrow its alreadymanifest resource and environmental limits as a mud ball has to fly through a cement

    wall (the textbook example of inelastic collision) will be a slow and messy process.

    Some measure of hope may nonetheless be derived from the growing moral and logical

    intuition that humanity must reorganize its relationship with nature. (And how could this

    occur without reorganizing relationships among its own ranks?)

    The anthropocentric delusion of an eternally cycling, forever growing economy

    unimpaired by earthly constraints

    5

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    6/7

    Stashing quickly- and slowly-diminishing nonrenewable resource inputs as equivalents

    into ordinary production functions is the first innocent step contemporary mainstream

    economics, which may be characterized as neoclassical for the past threescore years,makes toward disprizing concern over oil as the front barricade to economic growth.

    Without a blink of the eye, flows from an apparently declining reservoir are put side byside with labor and capital services. The human biomass, from where labor flows; and

    buildings, machinery and equipment, which render capital services, also comprise natural

    resources but these are relatively abundant, i.e., they do not decline, degrade, or disperseat an alarming rate. (Much of the human body is made up of oxygen, carbon, and

    hydrogen; and contemporary capital goods are built mainly of abundant reserves of iron

    and bauxite. There is plenty of silicon to manufacture semiconductors.)

    Would you trust a physician who believes that the healthiest, rather than the sickest, part

    of the organism determines life expectancy? This is the analogue of assuming seamless

    substitutability between rapidly and barely diminishing resources.

    The second step is to consider these algebraic expressions (originally applied to

    optimizing activities at the level of industrial firms or plants) the valid representation ofan infallible, self-programmed and self-correcting navigational equipment that guides

    society toward long-run equilibrium. Reliance on the so-called Constant Elasticity of

    Substitution (CES) functions in general equilibrium models, used to analyze national

    economies as well as the world economy, is the prime example.

    Relative factor shares and substitutability among factors are of central importance in CES

    functions (of which the Cobb-Douglas format, the workhorse of neoclassical modeling, isa special case). Thus, the ability of a given enterprise to increase the productivity of a

    factor (any factor, hence energy and oil) is subtly stipulated to be possible everywhere

    and all the time.

    Under the banner of rationalism, resource scarcities are automatically rendered harmless

    by the interaction of market forces and technological development. Such is the convictionthat breeds a hypertrophied, compulsive fixation with ever greater details within the

    protective enclosure of a fictitious economy in which the Earth plays the supporting role

    of standby reserve and fodder for consumption.

    Taking the part for the whole

    A recurring practical way to smear away the relevance of natural resources in theeconomic process is to cite the post-industrial character of high-income OECD

    countries. This is an incredibly transparent distortion of reality. The majority of the

    planets population is now industrializing. Before you can have a respectable car servicesector you must first have cars, roads, and gas stations.

    Being economically advanced by itself implies the maintenance of a high-fixed-cost

    industrial infrastructure made up not only of the most abundant elements in the Earths

    6

  • 8/8/2019 A Critique of Contemporary Economic Beliefs

    7/7

    crust. Hence, the worlds appetite for exhaustible resources, with fossil fuels as the top

    exponent, is accelerating rather than decelerating when global factors of production are at

    or trend toward full employment.

    One may be inclined to ascribe the splendid intellectual self-incarceration of

    contemporary economics to discourse -- postmodern philosophys explanation of howan internally coherent conceptual universe attached to the academic merit system

    prevents minds from seeing that a fading epochs moribund ideology postures as State-of-

    the-Art science, armed with a positivist research agenda.

    But complete exoneration is no longer possible, not when the world population is pushing

    seven billion; not when data on proven oil reserves and their rates of depletion are

    compared to projections about the number of motor vehicles doubling in two decades --not with the air we breathe.

    7