5.1 Pratap S Birthal

16

Click here to load reader

description

Contract Farming report

Transcript of 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

Page 1: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

1

Making Contract Farming Work in Smallholder Agriculture Pratap S Birthal1

1. Background

Indian agriculture is dominated by smallholders - of the total 101 million farm households 86 percent have land holdings of less than or equal to 2 ha, and their average size of land holding is 0.53 ha (Government of India (GoI), 2006a). How long can these households survive cultivating such tiny pieces of land? Should they exit agriculture or diversify their production portfolio towards commodities that have a greater potential for returns to land, labor and capital? Given past trend in transfer of labor from agriculture to other economic sectors2

1 National Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy Research, New Delhi 110 012 (India) 2 Proportion of workers engaged in agriculture came down from 68.5 percent in 1983 to 56.5 percent in 2004-05 (Nagaraj, 2007).

, option to exit agriculture seems difficult. Diversification towards high-value agriculture appears to be a plausible option, at least in the short to medium run. The food basket of Indian consumer is changing fast. Sustained economic and income growth, and a fast-growing urban population are fuelling rapid growth in demand for high-value food products like fruits, vegetables, milk, meat, egg, fish and beverages. Between 1983 and 2004-05 the share of high-value food products (fruits, vegetables, milk, meat, egg, fish and beverages) in the food expenditure increased from 30.4 to 44.1 percent in rural areas, and from 45.4 to 55.4 percent in urban areas (GoI, 2006b). Apart from expanding opportunities in domestic market, global demand for high-value foods has been increasing fast, offering an opportunity for their exports. In the past, the share of horticultural and animal food products in total agricultural exports from India increased from 24 percent in 1981 to 35 percent in 2003 (Birthal, Joshi and others, 2006). It is however ambiguous whether smallholders can benefit from demand-driven growth in high-value agriculture. Their inability to access markets is one of the major limitations to diversify towards high-value agriculture. Rural local markets for high-value food commodities are thin, and trading in distant urban markets is uneconomical due to high marketing and transaction costs. They are also constrained by a lack of access to credit, technology, inputs and services. Access to foreign markets is restricted by stringent food safety and quality standards there. All these reduce incentives to grow high-value food commodities. Nonetheless, the agri-food marketing system in India is undergoing a transformation with unfolding of market liberalization and globalization. Traditional marketing systems, dominated by ad hoc transactions and intermediaries, are gradually giving way to organized marketing systems, such as cooperatives, producers’ associations and contract farming. Further, the corporate sector is entering into food retailing in a big way, which is expected to aid this process of market transformation.

Page 2: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

2

Organized marketing systems are claimed to reduce marketing and transaction costs, facilitate farmers’ access to technology, inputs, credit and services, and mitigate production and market risks, and thus aid speeding up agricultural diversification and commercialization. Nonetheless, there is an apprehension that smallholders may not benefit much from new marketing arrangements because of their inability to supply large volumes and comply with food safety and quality standards being imposed by the firms. Despite, contract farming is coming up in India. Will it sustain or not would depend on a number of factors including physical, socioeconomic and policy factors. In this paper, we have tried to identify and collate some factors underlying the success of contract farming. The paper is organized into five sections. Next section provides a brief overview of the potential advantages and disadvantages associated with contract farming. In section III, we have identified factors that were critical to the success of some contract farming schemes in India. Policy issues important to the success of contract farming are discussed in section IV. Concluding remarks are made in the final section. 2. Potential Advantages and Disadvantages of Contract Farming3

Contract farming is a partnership between agribusiness/marketing firms and farmers, and has both advantages and disadvantages to both the parties. For agribusiness firms, contract farming is an important means to have an assured access to desired products or a quantitative and qualitative control over material supplies without actually engaging itself in farming. Firms may provide inputs, technology and services to farmers as a part of contract. If a firm were to produce its raw material requirements itself, using own or rented land and hired labor, the costs towards wages, social benefits, training and supervision could be very high. Through contract farming, the firm can shift and/or share some of these responsibilities with farmers, and secure supplies at a lower cost. Contract farming thus enables agribusiness firms to optimally utilize their installed capacity, infrastructure and manpower, and respond to food safety and quality concerns of the consumers. Nevertheless, agribusiness firms can encounter some negative externalities of contracting. One major externality is the risk of extra-contractual sales by the farmers, especially when negotiated price is fixed/pre-determined and the market price, at the time of delivery, is higher than the negotiated price. Second, in smallholder agriculture while transaction costs (search, negotiation and enforcement) of contracting with a large number of small farmers are higher, contracting with a few large producers is riskier, particularly if the alternative supply sources are limited and non-dependable. Third, in resource sharing contracts, firms may also face risk of misuse/diversion of inputs and credit.

For farmers, contract farming serves as an assured market for their produce at their doorsteps, reducing marketing and transaction costs and also price risk. Availability of an assured market also acts as an incentive to farmers to use quality inputs, adopt improved technologies and scale up their production systems. In circumstances when farmers face problems in accessing inputs, technology, information and services, firms provide these as a part of contract and hence reduce uncertainty in their availability, quality and prices for the farmers. Further,

3 This section is heavily based on Eaton and Shepherd (2001) and Arthur B. da Silva (2005).

Page 3: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

3

contract farming is often practiced in high-value perishable commodities that are riskier and require a different set of production and management practices, while farmers, particularly smallholders, are risk averse and may not venture into production of such commodities without technical assistance. To enable farmers to cope up with risks, ex ante and expost, firms provide them inputs, technology and services, impart training in production management and share risks. Like firms, farmers too are vulnerable to negative externalities of contract farming. A farmer, being a weaker partner, is prone to exploitation by the firm. Agribusiness firms can extract monopsonistic rent in the output market, if alternative marketing options are limited and farmers have locked sizeable investment into assets specific to the contract commodity or the commodity is perishable and not amenable to transformation into less perishable products on the farm. Firms can also extract monopoly rent in the input markets. Agribusiness firms may introduce new crops and technologies that can increase production and market risks. Bound by the contract to produce a specific commodity, farmers lose flexibility to adjust their production portfolio to emerging market opportunities. Further, there is also an apprehension that farmers’ excessive dependence for credit on firms can lead them into perpetual indebtedness. 3. Factors That Make Contract Farming Work Contract farming works if its advantages outweigh the disadvantages for both agribusiness firms and farmers, and both feel better off with contract than without it. Putting it differently, success of contract farming depends on that factors that address sources of potential disadvantages that countervail the synergy between firms and farmers. There are several factors - economic and non-economic, internal and external to the contracts – that influence relationship between farmers and firms, and hence the performance and the sustainability of contract farming. Contract farming exhibits in various forms, depending on the type of commodity, buyers and sellers, and the socio-economic environment surrounding farmers. Hence, the factors underlying performance of contract farming could be different under different production and socioeconomic environments. In this section, we (ii) identify from empirical literature important factors that have contributed to the success of some contract farming schemes in India, and (ii) draw lessons for making contract farming work in particular with smallholders. 3.1. Some Successful Ventures of Contract Farming For the purpose of identifying factors underneath the success of contract farming, we examine three different models of contract farming in three different commodities viz., milk, broilers and vegetables4

Contract farming in dairying takes form of an intermediate contract. The model was developed and is being implemented by the Nestle India Limited – a multinational firm – to source milk from small-scale producers. It is well-known that dairying in India is an integral

.

4 For details of these models, see Birthal et al. (2005).

Page 4: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

4

part of rural economy, yet its scale of production is too small for a majority of the households to generate cash benefits (Birthal, 2007)5

5 Nearly 62 percent farm households in India produce ≤1000 liters of milk a year accounting for only 24 percent of the total milk produced in the country.

. Contracting with such a large number of small-scale producers raises transaction costs to any firm. To reduce the cost of contracting Nestle follows an intermediate model of contract farming where the agreement is done with a local villager, called as an ‘agent’. The agent collects milk from small-scale producers, and also facilitates distribution of inputs and delivery of services. Nonetheless, overtime there has been some scaling-up of dairying in Nestle’s milk shed area perhaps due to availability of an assured market in the form of contract farming. As a result, the firm has also started direct contracting with large producers. The intermediate contracting however remains the dominant form. In fact, majority dairy processors in India use intermediate contracts to procure milk supplies. The contract farming scheme of the Nestle now covers about 100 thousand dairy farmers in over 1500 villages in several districts of Punjab. In 2005, Nestle collected 438 million kg of milk from farmers. Most of the milk collected by Nestle firm is processed into value- added products like baby food, butter, ghee, curd, etc. The firm observes strict food safety and quality standards right from the milk production stage. It has a well-developed traceability and milk chilling systems, and for quality milk supplies it encourages farmers to use milking machines and quality inputs. The case of contract farming in vegetables relates to the Mother Dairy Fruits and Vegetables Limited (MDFVL) - a wholly owned subsidiary of the public sector parastatal, National Dairy Development Board (NDDB). Horticultural production in India is geographically dispersed; only about 15 percent farm households grow vegetables and 5 percent grow fruits (Birthal et al., 2007). This means high transaction costs to the firm in securing supplies from scattered producers. To reduce these costs, the MDFVL secures supplies of fruits and vegetables from growers’ associations promoted by it. The firm provides technical guidance, services and inputs to association members to ensure that farmers follow best production and marketing practices. MDFVL (earlier called SAFAL) is an organized retail chain and was started in 1988 in Delhi. As of now, the MDFVL secures its supplies from around 300 growers’ associations spread throughout the country, and has almost an equal number of retail outlets in Delhi. SAFAL is the brand name for MDFVL products. Recently, the MDFVL has established a 100 percent export-oriented HACCP certified processing plant in Mumbai. The model of contract farming in broilers in India is a replica of what prevails in most other countries. Firms provide day-old chicks, feed, vaccines and services to farmers at no cost to them, and lift entire output by paying fixed growing charges (per kilogram of body weight of bird) in lieu of their contribution to cost (labor, water and electricity charges, litter and rent for poultry shed and equipment). Farmers are thus insured against market risks.

Page 5: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

5

The case of contract farming in broilers relates to the Venkateshwara Hatcheries Limited (VHL) - one of the leading firms in poultry business in India since early 1970s. The firm is engaged not only in contract farming poultry, but also manufacturing of poultry feed, medicines, vaccines and value-added poultry products. Recently, the firm has started a retail chain in poultry products with brand name ‘BROMARK’. 3.2.Critical Success Factors From the contract farming schemes mentioned above we distill out factors that have played an important role in their success6. Table 1 provides some indicators of their performance7

. More profit, lower marketing and transaction costs: There is a striking difference in the profits of contract and non-contract farmers particularly in the case of milk and spinach. Contract farmers realize more profits as compared to non-contract farmers; the difference is more than double in milk, and 78 percent in spinach. Other studies too indicate higher profits for contract farmers. Birthal, Jha and others (2006) have reported contract dairy farmers receiving 70 percent more profits over non-contract farmers. In potato, Kumar (2006) finds 143 percent higher profit for contract farmers over non-contract farmers.

Table 1: Economics of contract versus non-contract production (Rs/ton)

Milk Spinach Broilers8

Item Con-tract

Non-contract

% difference

Con-tract

Non-contract

% difference

Con-tract

Non-contract

% difference

Yield* 11.9 11.4 4.4 8.6 8.3 4.0 1.78 1.79 -0.6 Production cost

5586 5782 -2.5 1485 1630 -8.9 - - -

Marketing and transaction costs

100 1442 -93.1 35 437 -92.0 38 90 -57.8

Total cost 5686 7170 -20.7 1520 2067 -26.5 - - - Price 9337 8991 3.8 3311 3074 7.7 - - - Net revenue

3651 1821 100.5 1791 1007 77.9 2255 2003 12.6

* milk: 4 % fat corrected in kg per in-milk animal; spinach: tonnes/ha; broilers: body weight in kg/bird. Source: Birthal et al. (2005) Figures presented in table 1 provide that More profits with contract farming are due to savings in marketing and transaction costs, which otherwise are very high in the wet markets. For 6 Our focus is on the factors that are critical to a successful partnership between agribusiness firms and farmers. For detailed discussion of other factors such as infrastructure, production and socio-economic environment and market opportunities, see Eaton and Shepherd (2001). 7 For more details, see Birthal et al (2005) 8 Production cost and price in the case of broilers could not be estimated for contract farmers as the firm supplies critical inputs and lifts entire output without any obligations to the farmers.

Page 6: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

6

milk and spinach, marketing and transaction costs guzzle 15-22 percent of the gross revenue (sale price) of the non-contract farmers. Singh (2005) reports marketing costs eating away 13-27 percent of the sale price of vegetables. Gandhi and Namboodri (2002) also report high marketing costs and margins in fruits and vegetables. Through contracts farmers can avoid marketing and transaction costs to a large extent (Table 1). Dairy and spinach farmers could save as much as 90 percent of these costs over non-contract farmers. There are other sources, e.g. yield, production cost and price, of difference in profits of contract and non-contract farmers, their contribution however is not significant. Similar results have been reported for milk by Birthal, Jha and others (2006). The evidence leads to us to conclude that ceteris paribus success of any contract farming scheme would depend on its capability to improve farm profitability and reduce marketing and transaction costs. Reducing Risk: The difference in profits of contract and non-contract farmers in case of broilers is not as large as in case of milk and spinach, despite lower marketing and transaction costs for the contract farmers (Table 1). The extent of marketing and transaction costs however is too small for both contract and non-contract farmers to cause any significant difference in profits9. So is the case with average yield (body weight of the birds). Some studies (Mehta et al., 2003; Fairoze et al., 2006) also indicate that contract farming in broilers is not as profitable as independent production10. If the contract farming in broilers is not so profitable then why it is widely prevalent in India11

as well as other countries?

Poultry production is capital-intensive and faces high production and price risks (Figure 1), as compared to many other agricultural enterprises. Under such situations, contract farming performs banking and insurance functions. Agribusiness firms provide critical inputs, like day-old chicks and feed at no cost to the farmers, and farmers in lieu of their contribution to cost of production receive fixed growing charges independent of market prices, while profits for non-contract farmers depend on market prices, which are highly volatile. The firms also share production risks limited to natural mortality of about 5 percent. Contract farming thus reduces uncertainty in availability, quality and prices of inputs, eases capital constraint and insulates farmers against market risks. Ramaswami et al. (2006) have estimated that through contracts broiler farmers could shift as much as 88 percent of the market risk to the firms. Birthal et al. (2005) too observe little variation in profits of contract farmers (CV=3.5%) than of non-contract farmers (CV=70%). The above discussion brings out that there is a tradeoff between returns and risks in contract farming of commodities involving very high market risk. Studies on contract farming of 9 Both contract and non-contract farmers receive supplies of critical inputs (day-old chicks and feed) from firms and traders at their farm gates prices inclusive of marketing and transportation cost, and the farmers bear only the costs in acquisition of information and inputs other than these. 10 Such studies are based on information from a single production cycle (6-7 weeks), while a farmer can harvest upto six crops of broilers in a year. Prices of poultry products are highly seasonal in nature and thus are a major determinant of profitability of independent production, while contract farmers are insured against price risks. Ignoring price volatility may conclude either way depending on the behavior of market prices. 11 Approximately 40% of the broiler production in India comes from contract farming (Fairoze et al., 2006)

Page 7: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

7

some other commodities, like cotton, potato and Basmati rice also indicate that contract farming works well if agribusiness firms manage credit and insurance for farmers (Anon., 2003; Singh, 2007).

Figure 1: Farm-gate prices of broilers in India, 2004-06

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

1-Jan

1-Feb

1-Mar

1-Apr

1-May

1-Jun 1-Jul

1-Aug

1-Sep

1-Oct

1-Nov

1-Dec

Rs/kg

Source: All India Broiler Farmers’ Marketing Cooperative Ltd. The corollary to this is that the success of contract farming in capital-intensive and riskier enterprises would depend on the extent to which it can protect farmers against production and market risks. Competitive pricing: Contract farming is often criticized on the ground that it empowers firms to extract monopsonistic rent in the output market and monopoly rent in the input market, particularly if the markets are imperfect and farmers face high asset-specificity12

in terms of investment, time and skills.

From a comparison of output prices and unit cost of production for contract and non-contract farmers in Table 1 it however appears that firms abstain from extracting monopsony and monopoly rents. Output prices for contract farmers are marginally higher, and the unit cost of production is marginally lower than for non-contract farmers. Further, output prices (milk and spinach) are not pre-determined13

, but are linked to market prices. Over and above market prices, firms pay some premium as to manage the problem of extra-contractual sales. The firms have also advantage of scale economies in procurement of inputs and services, and pass on a part of these benefits to farmers by charging them less than the market prices. Singh (2007) also report similar evidence in case of potato and Basmati rice.

These observations lead to the inference that the probability of success of contract farming is high if prices of outputs and inputs are linked to open market prices, and firms abstain from anti-competitive behavior. 12 Asset-specificity refers to the relative lack of transferability of assets intended for use in a given transaction to other uses. Highly specific assets represent sunk costs that have relatively little value beyond their use in the context of a specific transaction. 13 Pre-determined prices often encourage opportunistic tendency by both the farmers and the firms, and ultimately the breach of contract and disputes.

Page 8: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

8

Cementing partnership through non-price factors: Non-price factors, like regular off-take of output, timeliness in payments and provision of inputs, technical advice and services, and incentives for efficiency and clean production have played an important role in the success of the contract farming schemes described above. Nestle rewards farmers for efficiency and clean milk production and observes timeliness in payments, inputs and services. VHL provides incentives to broiler farmers for better efficiency and also shares with them the incremental profits due to higher market prices. Some other studies, too have observed an important role of non-price factors in expanding/strengthening the partnership between farmers and firms (Singh, 2007; Thirunavukkarasu and Sudeepkumar, 2005). Thirunavukkarasu and Sudeepkumar (2005) have reported a strong tendency among dairy farmers to switch over from informal markets to formal markets, and also from one formal to another formal market mainly due non-price factors. The corollary to this is that the non-price factors are as important in cementing the long-run relationship and trust between firms and farmers as are the prices. Spreading supply risks by contracting with small producers: Agribusiness firms, to minimize costs of search, monitoring and enforcement of contracts with a large number of small farmers, often tend to partner with those farmers who can supply large volumes. Reliance on a few large suppliers, however, increases supply risk if the alternative supply sources are limited. Contracts with a large number of small farmers, on the other hand, spread supply risk. Firms can reduce transaction costs of contracting with small farmers following innovative approaches, like use of intermediate contracts, growers’ associations and self-help groups to source raw material supplies and distribute inputs and services. For example, Nestle uses intermediate contracts where a local villager procures supplies from small dairy producers on behalf of the firm. MDFVL secures its supplies of fruits and vegetables through growers’ associations promoted by it. Some textile mills, for example Appachi Cotton Company in Tamil Nadu, organize farmers as self-help groups to secure raw material supplies and provide inputs, services, credit and insurance (Anon., 2003). Such innovations not only reduce transaction costs of contracting with small farmers, but also supply risks. Further, it may be noted that in smallholder dominated agrarian economies, exclusion of small farmers from contract farming schemes is politically unacceptable and socially undesirable. Inclusion of small farmers in contract farming increases its political acceptability. Evidence from case studies on dairy, poultry and vegetables discussed in this paper show that firms could involve small farmers in contract farming through some organizational structures. Of the total milk suppliers to Nestle, 56 percent had less than or equal to 5 milch animals (Birthal et al., 2005). Similarly, about half of the vegetable suppliers to MDFVL had land holdings of less than or equal to 2 ha (Birthal and Joshi 2007). Erappa (2006) also reports over half of the contract farmers in gherkin as small farmers. It is thus inferred that in smallholder dominated agrarian economies contract farming would work if the agribusiness firms follow innovative approaches such as intermediate contracts and group action that not only reduce transaction costs of contracting with small farmers and

Page 9: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

9

spread supply risk, but also make contract farming a politically acceptable and socially desirable market institution. A long-term commitment and mutual trust: Asset-specificity is very high in contract farming. Agribusiness firms lock in huge investment in infrastructure and manpower for processing, procurement and distribution, which, by and large, is commodity-specific. Similarly, farmers too invest in commodity-specific assets. Some enterprises like fruit plantation and poultry require considerable initial investment. Both firms and farmers would fail to realize returns on such investments if there is lack of a long-term commitment and trust between them. Often, a lack of a long-term commitment and mutual trust are major causes of breach of contract and disputes. Effective communication (monitoring), and transparency and flexibility in terms and conditions are needed to develop mutual trust. For example, Nestle has been sustaining its partnership with dairy farmers in Punjab for over the last four decades because of a commitment and mutual trust. Nestle started its processing facility in 1962 with 2 million kg of milk sourced from 4,660 farmers in 66 villages in Punjab. Its operations now have expanded manifold; in 2005 it procured 438 million kg milk from over 95 thousand farmers spread over 1,700 villages (Figure 2). The corollary is that a long term commitment and mutual trust between firms and farmers are essential to the success and sustainability of contract farming.

Figure 2: Scaling-up in dairy production in India

0

100

200

300

400

500

1962 1970 1980 1990 2001 2005

Milk s

upplie

rs an

d proc

ureme

nt

0

1000

2000

3000

4000

5000

Milk p

rocure

ment/

supplie

r

Number of milk suppliers (000)Milk procured (milion kg)Milk procurement/supplier (kg)

Source: Nestle India Limited

Scaling-out and scaling-up: Scaling-out and scaling-up of contract farming are important for both the firm and farmers. For a firm scaling-out as well as scaling-up are important to procure required volumes of agricultural produce as to optimally utilize its processing capacity, infrastructure and manpower. Scaling-out and scaling-up however have their own advantages and disadvantages. Scaling-out spreads supply risk, while scaling-up may increase it. For farmers, scaling-out offers market opportunities to new entrants, while scaling-up enables existing contract farmers to augment their income.

Page 10: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

10

Figure 2 suggests that a successful firm follows a combination of both scaling- and scaling-up not only to spread supply risk but also to discharge corporate responsibility of inclusive socio-economic development. It encourages and incentivizes its able partners to scale-up their production systems to climb-up income ladder, and makes new contracts with potential suppliers to reduce supply risk in case the scaled-up partners start exhibiting opportunistic tendency. The corollary is that in the long run the sustainability of contract farming would be influenced by the extent to which the agribusiness firms are able to scale it up horizontally and/or vertically, ceteris paribus. 4. Role of Policies in Promoting Contract Farming The success factors identified in the previous section are intrinsic to the partnership between firms and farmers, and provide that if managed properly contract farming can create a win-win situation for both the parties. Yet, there are several other factors, particularly those related to policy, that also play an important role in the performance, outreach and sustainability of contract farming. Contract farming in India is in the infant stage, and the evidence indicates it can be developed as a pro-poor market institution through appropriate policies and strategies. Also there are opportunities for farmers in contract farming. Sustained income growth, a fast-growing urban population and increasing westernization of diets are fuelling rapid growth in demand for high-value horticultural and animal food products, which have a greater scope for production under contracts. Between 2005 and 2025 the demand for different animal food products is projected to increase by 75-110 percent and for fruits and vegetable by 85-90 percent, as compared to a 20 percent increase in the demand for foodgrains (Kumar et al., 2007). The demand for processed food products and beverages is expected to grow even faster; the share of processed foods and beverages in the total food expenditure is projected to rise to 15 percent in 2020 from 9 percent in 1999 (Ravi and Roy, 2006). Besides, export opportunities are also emerging with unfolding of globalization. The share of high-value food products (dairy, poultry, fruits and vegetables) in the total agricultural exports has steadily increased; from 13.5 percent in 2001-02 to 15.9 percent in 2005-06 (GoI, 2007). Contract farming schemes are organized by large agribusiness firms including processors, exporters and supermarket chains. Developing contract farming thus requires appropriate policies, infrastructure and regulations that facilitate private investment in agribusiness. During the last 15 years the Government of India has taken a number of initiatives, such as de-regulation of food industry, pruning of the list of agricultural items reserved for small-scale industries, 100 percent foreign direct investment (FDI) in food processing, reduction in corporate taxes and excise duties on processed foods, establishment of agri-export zones, priority sector lending to food processing industry, enactment of an integrated food law, de-regulation of agricultural markets, etc. to boost food processing and promote agribusiness and contract farming. The following issues however merit further attention: Invest in physical infrastructure: A firm’s decision to invest in agribusiness, to a great extent, is influenced by the availability of good public infrastructure (roads, electricity,

Page 11: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

11

communication network, electricity, etc.). Public infrastructure is essential to reduce marketing and transaction costs and post-harvest losses, and for quick access and dissemination of information. Unfortunately, the public infrastructure in India has remained underdeveloped, leading to a slow growth in private investment in refrigerated transport, cold storages and food processing. This is reflected in the low level of value-addition to agricultural produce; only 2.2 percent of the production of fruits and vegetables, 6 percent of the poultry meat, 21 percent of the buffalo meat and 15 percent of the milk produced in the country are processed into value-added products by the organized sector (GoI, 2005a). The evidence also shows a greater concentration of production of high-value agricultural commodities (in which contract farming is more pronounced) in the areas well-connected with roads and urban centers (Parthasarathy Rao et al., 2006). Investment in public infrastructure is thus essential to trigger private investment all along the supply/value chain. FDI in food retailing: The Government of India allows 100% FDI in food processing14 but restricts FDI in retailing in general, because of opposition from traders’ lobby and some political parties that argue that FDI in retailing would adversely affect livelihood of millions of workers in the unorganized retailing. Restricting FDI in food retailing however may act as barrier to FDI in food processing and thereby to the growth of food processing industry, which is crucial to establish strong backward linkages with agriculture. For example, despite a provision of 100% FDI in food processing the growth in output of food processing sector has remained almost the same as in the pre-FDI period15

Promote competition: By enacting the Model Act (The State Agricultural Produce Marketing Development & Regulation Act) in 2003 the Government of India has taken a noteworthy step towards creating a level playing field for the private investment in agricultural markets, agribusiness and contract farming. Its implementation by the state governments

. The Government, however, has permitted FDI in single brand retailing in 2006. Evidence from elsewhere shows that FDI in food retailing is beneficial to both consumers and producers (Reardon and Gulati 2008). FDI in retailing means rise of supermarkets offering benefits of convenience shopping, and access to a variety of products at lower prices to consumers. Supermarkets procure food commodities from independent procurement companies (dedicated suppliers) who often work with farmers or through contract farming. Such market linkages create opportunities for farmers to have a better access to markets for produce, inputs, services and technology.

16

14 Before initiation of economic reforms in 1991 FDI upto 40% was allowed only in some selected sectors. In 1991 some more sectors were opened up for FDI and the limit was raised to 51%. This process continued, and in the year 2000, FDI was allowed upto 100 percent in all sectors except those on the negative list. In 2006 the FDI has been permitted in single brand retailing. 15 Our estimates show that food processing industry grew at an annual rate of around 7 percent a year during pre-reform period (1980-81 to 1991-92) and almost at a similar rate after initiation of economic reforms in 1991. 16 Agriculture in India is a state subject, and implementation of the Model Act lies with state governments.

has remained half-hearted. Only a few states have amended their existing Agricultural Produce Market Committee Acts on the lines of Model Act, others have done some partial amendments or are yet to decide on the modifications. The implementation of the Model Act, 2003 in its true spirit is likely to promote competition and strengthen industry’s linkages with

Page 12: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

12

agriculture. It is, however, cautioned that the governments should take appropriate measures to curb any tendency of regional monopsony and collusive oligopsony. Evolve mechanisms for resolution of conflicts: The Model Act, 2003 outlines provisions for regulation of contract farming to protect interests of both agribusiness firms and farmers. However, one of the provisions that merit attention concerns mechanism for dispute resolution. Considering the lengthy legal procedures, the Act provides that disputes between firms and farmers, if any should be mutually resolved or settled by the Marketing Committee with which the contract farming scheme is registered. However, at present a considerable number of contract farming schemes are informal and remain unregistered with the Marketing Committee. Non-registration of contract farming schemes creates a scope for opportunism, breach of contracts and rise in disputes. These problems would appear in a severe form with spread of contract farming, which is likely. Thus, there is a need to (i) enforce registration of contract farming schemes, and (ii) establish a judicial or quasi-judicial body for speedy resolution of disputes. Develop grades and standards: Price and quality of products are two major factors that can render a contract farming scheme a success or failure. Agribusiness firms may reject farm produce or pay a lower price on the ground of it poor quality. This happens because of a lack of well-defined grades and standards for farm produce. Organized retailers, exporters and processors are imposing their own grades and standards on producers. The requirement for developing effective grades and standards and their compliance by both sellers and buyers cannot be ignored with rising demand for safe and quality foods in both the domestic and the international markets. Promote farmers’ organizations and other intermediaries: Often, agribusiness firms tend to ignore small farmers in contract farming schemes because of higher transaction costs of dealing with a large number of them. An effective way of involving smallholders in contract farming is to encourage them to organize themselves into cooperatives, self-help groups and growers associations. Such organizational structures help them improve their bargaining power vis-à-vis agribusiness firms, and also generate scale economies in acquisition of inputs, technology, services and information. Non-governmental organizations (NGOs) can also play an important role by acting as intermediaries between firms and farmers. Public-private partnership in agricultural research and extension: Contract farming is more prevalent in high-value agricultural commodities that have a considerable market demand. This implies a greater diversification of agricultural production portfolio, and sets a demand-driven agenda for agricultural research and extension. Agricultural research and extension in India have remained largely in the public-domain. However, increasing participation of the private sector in agribusiness offers considerable scope for public-private partnership in agricultural research and extension to effectively address rising (i) consumers’ concerns for food variety, safety and quality, and (ii) farmers’ requirement of information, technology and services. Improve farmers’ capacity to invest, and cope up with risks: Two important factors in scaling-out/up of the contract farming relate to credit and insurance. An overwhelming

Page 13: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

13

majority of farmers in India are smallholders. They lack capacity to invest in high-value agriculture and are risk averse. Some activities like poultry and fruit plantation are capital-intensive and riskier, and need institutional support in terms of finance and insurance. Although formal rural credit system in the country is fairly well-developed, institutions to protect farmers against risks have remained under-developed. Hardly around 4 percent farm households in the country insure their farming activities (GoI, 2005b). 5. Conclusion

There is no single recipe to make contract farming work in smallholder agriculture. A number of factors, intrinsic and extrinsic to the contract, influence the relationship between agribusiness firms and farmers, and therefore the performance and the sustainability of contract farming. We have distilled out some important factors from the empirical literature for consideration of agribusiness firms and policymakers to manage and promote contract farming more effectively. Agribusiness firms while improving their own profits should ensure that contract crop/commodity is more remunerative for farmers than the competing crops/commodities and they earn more with contract farming than without it; and the marketing and transaction costs associated with farmers’ disposal of produce and acquisition of inputs, technology and services are lower with contract farming. Second, for high-risk commodities firms must share production and marketing risks to the extent possible, and also assist farmers managing production risks. Third, firms should abstain from a tendency of extracting monopsony and monopoly rents. Fourth, firms should base their pricing strategy on the market trends, and create incentives for farmers for better efficiency and product quality as to manage problem of extra-contractual sales or any problem of moral hazards. Fifth, firms should value timeliness in off take of produce, and delivery of payments, inputs, technology and services. Sixth, to make contract farming politically acceptable and socially desirable it is important to adopt innovative approaches such intermediate contracts, growers’ associations, self-help groups, etc. to create opportunities for smallholders to participate in contract farming, and also to reduce their own transaction costs of contracting and supply risks. Finally, for making contract farming a sustainable institution, it is important for firms to win confidence and trust of the farmers through price and non-price instruments. To develop contract farming as a pro-poor market institution the central and state governments should create a conducive climate for private investment in agribusiness, promote competition among various market players whilst curbing any tendency of regional monopsony and collusive oligopsony, develop and facilitate implementation of grades and standards, improve farmers’ access to credit, insurance, technology and extension services, and facilitate smallholders to organize themselves into cooperatives, growers’ associations and self-help groups as to empower them to effectively deal with big business firms.

Page 14: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

14

References

Anon.2003. Contract farming ventures in India: A few successful cases. Spice, Vol. 1(4), 6p.

Arthur B. da Silva, C. 2005. The growing role of contract farming in agri-food systems development: Drivers, theory and practice. Agriculture Management, Marketing and Finance Service. Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome, Italy. Available at: http://www.fao.org/ag/agS/subjects/en/agmarket/docs/AGSF9.pdf.

Birthal, P.S. 2007. Linking smallholder livestock producers to markets: Issues and approaches. Keynote paper presented at the 67th Annual Conference of the Indian Society of Agricultural Economics at Bankers Institute of Rural Development, Lucknow (India), November 5-7. Available at: http://www.isaeindia.org/Keynote%20Paper-Pratap%20Birthal.doc.

Birthal, P.S., A.K. Jha, M. Tiongco, C. Delgado, C. Narrod and P.K. Joshi. 2006. Equitable

intensification of smallholder market-oriented dairy production in India through contract farming, Annex I of the IFPRI-FAO Final Report Contract farming of milk and poultry in India: Partnerships to promote the environmentally friendly and equitable intensification of smallholder livestock production. International food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC.

Birthal, P.S. and P.K. Joshi. 2007. Institutional innovations for improving smallholder

participation in high-value agriculture: A case of fruit and vegetable growers’ associations. Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture, 46(1), pp. 49-68.

Birthal, P.S., P.K. Joshi and Ashok Gulati. 2005. Vertical coordination in high-value food

commodities: Implications for smallholders. Markets, Trade and Institutions Division Discussion Paper No. 85, International food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC. Available at: http://www.ifpri.org/divs/mtid/dp/mtidp85.htm.

Birthal, P.S., P.K. Joshi, D. Roy and A. Thorat. 2006. Diversification in Indian agriculture

towards high-value food products: What determines it and who participates in it? Paper Presented at the Workshop Plate to Plough: Agricultural Diversification and Its Implications for the Smallholders, organized by the International Food Policy Research Institute, Asia office, New Delhi, and the Institute of Economic Growth, New Delhi at New Delhi, September 20-21.

Birthal, P.S., P.K. Joshi, D. Roy and A. Thorat. 2007. Diversification in Indian agriculture

towards high-value crops: The role of smallholders. IFPRI Discussion Paper 00727. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C. Available at: http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/dp/IFPRIDP00727.pdf

Page 15: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

15

Eaton, C., and A.W. Shepherd. 2001. Contract farming: Partnership for growth. FAO Agricultural Services Bulletin 145. Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome, Italy.

Erappa, S. 2006. Contract farming in Karnataka: A boon or a bane? Research Report

9/ADRT113. Agricultural Development and Rural Transformation Centre, Institute for Social and Economic Change, Bangalore (India). Available at: http://www.isec.ac.in/CONTRACT%20FARMING%20FINAL%20REPORT.pdf

Fairoze, M.N., L. Achoth, K.K. Prasanna Rashmi, M. Tiongco, C. Delgado, C. Narrod and

P.G. Chengappa. 2006. Equitable intensification of smallholder market-oriented poultry production in India through contract farming, Annex I of the IFPRI-FAO Final Report Contract Farming of Milk and Poultry in India: Partnerships to Promote the Environmentally Friendly and Equitable Intensification of Smallholder Livestock Production, International food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC.

Gandhi, V., and N.V. Namboodiri. 2002. Fruit and vegetable marketing and its efficiency in

India: A study in wholesale markets in Ahmedabad area. Memio. Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad (India).

Available at: http://www.iimahd.ernet.in/publications/data/2002-12- 05vasantgandhi.pdf+Gandhi+fruit+and+vegetable+marketing&hl=en&ct=clnk&cd=2&gl=in Government of India. 2005a. Vision, strategy and action plan for food processing industries

in India. Ministry of Food Processing, Government of India, New Delhi. _________________. 2005b. Some aspects of farming. Report No. 496(59/33/3). National

Sample Survey Organization, Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation, Government of India, New Delhi.

_________________. 2006a. Some aspects of operational land holdings in India, 2002-03.

NSS Report No. 492 (59/18.1/3). National Sample Survey Organization, Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation, New Delhi.

_________________. 2006b. Level and pattern of consumer expenditure 2004-05. Report No.

508(61/1.0/1), National Sample Survey Organization, Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation, Government of India, New Delhi.

_________________. 2007. Agricultural Statistics at a Glance. Department of Agriculture

and Cooperation, Ministry of Agriculture, Government of India, New Delhi. Kumar, P. 2006. Contract farming through agribusiness and state corporation. Economic and

Political Weekly, Vol. 41 (52), December 30. Kumar, P., Mruthyunjaya and P.S. Birthal. 2007. Changing consumption pattern in South

Asia. In: Agricultural Diversification and Smallholdersin South Asia, P.K. Joshi, Ashok Gulati and Ralph Cummings Jr., eds). Academic Foundation, New Delhi.

Page 16: 5.1 Pratap S Birthal

16

Mehta, R., R.G. Nambiar, C. Delgado and S. Subramanyam. 2003. Policy, technical and environmental determinants and implications of the scaling-up of broiler and egg production in India. Annex II of the IFPRI-FAO Final Report Livestock Industrialization, Trade and Social-Health-Environmental Impacts in Developing Countries, phase II, International food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC. Available at: http://www.fao.org/WAIRDOCS/LEAD/X6170E/X6170E00.HTM

Nagaraj, R. 2007. Employment situation in India. Indira Gandhi Institute of Development

Research, Mumbai. Available at: http://www.un.org/esa/socdev/social/meetings/egm5/papers/Nagaraj_Rayaprolu.ppt#281,27,G

DP and Workforce Distribution

Ramaswami, B., P.S. Birthal and P.K. Joshi. 2006. Efficiency and distribution in contract farming: The case of Indian poultry growers. Markets, Trade and Institutions Discussion Paper No. 91, International food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC. Available at:

. Parthasarathy Rao, P., PS Birthal and PK Joshi. 2006. Diversification towards high-value

agriculture: Role of urbanization and infrastructure. Economic and Political Weekly, June 30, pp. 2747-2753.

http://www.ifpri.org/divs/mtid/dp/papers/mtidp91.pdf Ravi, C. and D. Roy.2006. Consumption patterns and food demand projections: A regional

analysis. Paper Presented at the Workshop Plate to Plough: Agricultural Diversification and Its Implications for the Smallholders, organized by the International Food Policy Research Institute, Asia office, New Delhi, and the Institute of Economic Growth, New Delhi at New Delhi, September 20-21.

Singh, M.K. 2005. Economics of production and marketing of vegetables in Madhya Pradesh,

India. International Journal of Rural Studies, Vol. 12 (2): 11-23. Singh, S. 2007. Leveraging contract farming for improving supply chain efficiency in India:

Some innovative and successful models. Paper presented at the Third International Conference on Linking Markets and Farmers: Exploring Leading Practices to Foster Economic Growth in Rural India. New Delhi. March 11-15, 2007. Available at: http://www.globalfoodchainpartnerships.org/india/Papers/SukhpalSingh.pdf

Thirunavukkarasu, D. and N.K. Sudeepkumar. 2005. Milk marketing options for the dairy

farmers in open economy and their choice in Tamil Nadu, India. Livestock Research for Rural Development, Vol.17 (8). Available at:

http:// www.cipav.org.co/lrrd/lrrd17/8/thir17092.htm.