1A_1_KeefeRENGIFO.pdf

43
Currency Options as Central Bank Risk Management Tool Preliminary version, April 2014 Helena Glebocki Keefe, Erick W. Rengifo Fordham University, Economics Department April 1, 2014 Abstract Many central banks in emerging markets and developing economies are concerned with excessive volatility in foreign exchange markets and wish to control the direction and speed with which the value of their currency changes. Historically, intervention has consisted of using foreign exchange reserves to purchase and sell foreign currency directly in the spot market. The research presented in this paper explores how currency options may be a viable central bank tool for intervention. Holding and issuing bundles of call and put options with multiple strike prices while dynamically delta hedging the port- folio position curbs excessive reserve accumulation, builds markets and domestic liquidity, establishes a more effective signaling process between policy makers and the market, and creates a more cohesive intervention plan than direct spot market intervention. We use the Garman-Kohlhagen options pricing model to analyze the case study of Colombia and to simulate the impact of using an alternative to a butterfly strategy as an intervention mechanism on the spot market position of the central bank, reserve accumulation and total costs accrued from intervention 1 . 1 The research conducted and presented in this paper has been sponsored by the Global Association of Risk Professionals. 1

Transcript of 1A_1_KeefeRENGIFO.pdf

  • Currency Options as Central Bank Risk Management Tool

    Preliminary version, April 2014

    Helena Glebocki Keefe, Erick W. RengifoFordham University, Economics Department

    April 1, 2014

    Abstract

    Many central banks in emerging markets and developing economies are concerned with excessive

    volatility in foreign exchange markets and wish to control the direction and speed with which the value

    of their currency changes. Historically, intervention has consisted of using foreign exchange reserves to

    purchase and sell foreign currency directly in the spot market. The research presented in this paper

    explores how currency options may be a viable central bank tool for intervention. Holding and issuing

    bundles of call and put options with multiple strike prices while dynamically delta hedging the port-

    folio position curbs excessive reserve accumulation, builds markets and domestic liquidity, establishes

    a more effective signaling process between policy makers and the market, and creates a more cohesive

    intervention plan than direct spot market intervention. We use the Garman-Kohlhagen options pricing

    model to analyze the case study of Colombia and to simulate the impact of using an alternative to a

    butterfly strategy as an intervention mechanism on the spot market position of the central bank, reserve

    accumulation and total costs accrued from intervention1.

    1The research conducted and presented in this paper has been sponsored by the Global Association of Risk Professionals.

    1

  • 1 Introduction

    Holding2 and issuing3 bundles of call and put options while dynamically delta hedging4 the net portfolio

    position allows central banks in developing economies to have a targeted approach to currency market

    intervention. Previous attempts to use options as an intervention mechanism by Mexico and Colombia

    have been abandoned. Deemed ineffective in curbing volatility by some, such as Mandeng (2003), past

    failure of options contracts may be due to their sporadic and unhedged issuance, leading to little sustained

    impact and no clear picture of how to operate in the spot market. This paper revisits the case of Colombia

    to analyze how using an alternative to the butterfly option strategy can provide central banks with an

    alternative policy tool to intervene in currency markets to control volatility, influence expectations, build

    markets and ensure domestic liquidity at a lower cost than pure spot market intervention.

    Central banks in emerging markets and developing economies are concerned with excessive fluctua-

    tions of their exchange rates. Such volatility can cause risks associated with banking crises, economic

    instability, slowed growth and diminished trade. According to a survey by the Bank of International

    Settlements of 19 central banks in developing economies, two-thirds conducted some type of currency

    market intervention and found it to be an effective tool for controlling exchange rate volatility (Mihaljek,

    2004). Most developing countries are engaging in some type of intervention into currency markets to

    exert control over exchange rates. Many intervene to calm disorderly markets and relieve liquidity short-

    ages, while others try to correct misalignment and stabilize volatile exchange rates. All policy makers

    surveyed stated that intervention which influences future expectations and signals a future stance of

    monetary policy is the most effective. Interventions are assumed to have primarily a short-term influ-

    ence on currency markets. Since currency markets are very dynamic, even in emerging markets and

    developing economies, the most effective strategy for the central bank will be one that is consistent.

    Holding and issuing bundles of call and put options at various strike prices on a consistent basis

    while dynamically delta hedging the portfolio position in the spot market will allow the central bank

    to influence the expectations of traders, target volatility and signal their policy stance. It will also

    provide policy makers with a clear target for operating in the spot market while increasing liquidity

    domestically. Additionally, the costs associated with intervention will be lower, sterilization problems

    2Holding options contracts will refer to ownership of the contract. Specifically, when it is holding a contract, the central bankwill be long the option contract and have the right, but not the obligation to exercise the contract.

    3Issuing options contracts will refer to writing and auctioning the option contract. Specifically, when it is issuing a contract,the central bank will be short the option contract and will be obligated to fulfill the contract if it is executed by the ownerat maturity.

    4Dynamic delta hedging is the main hedging strategy considered in this research because it reflects a short-run strategy ofintervention, which has been found to be most effective by policymakers (Mihaljek, 2004) and because drastic changes in dayto day value of the currency are not anticipated. An alternative strategy, such as gamma hedging will be considered in futureresearch that builds on the current findings.

    2

  • will be alleviated, and signals between traders and the central bank will allow policy makers more time

    to react to speculative threats and deviations of the exchange rate from macroeconomic fundamentals.

    This paper explores how options may be a viable alternative policy tool for central banks in developing

    economies to use in currency market intervention. First, we analyze Colombias past experimentation

    with options contracts as the baseline case. Next, we explore which option strategies are most appropriate

    to meet the goals of central bank currency market intervention. For the analytical approach, we use both

    a random process and an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process with GARCH volatility to simulate the Colombian

    Peso-US Dollar (COPUSD) exchange rate. With the simulated series, we price options contracts at

    various strike prices and analyze the outcome of hedging a portfolio position that is tailored to counter

    persistent appreciation or depreciation in the exchange rate. We compare the spot market position and

    total costs to the central bank of such a strategy with the cost of daily interventions currently conducted

    by Colombia.

    The remaining sections of the chapter are structured as follows. Sections two presents an overview

    of options and basic strategies. Section three lays out the motivation for research and a review of the

    literature. Section four presents the data and historical analysis for the case of Colombia. Section five

    addresses the possible option strategies that are most effective to the goals of the central bank. Section

    six presents the analytical approach, models and methodology for simulation. Section seven reports

    the simulation results. Section eight discusses implications of the findings and future extensions of the

    research.

    2 Overview of Options

    An options contract provides the owner the right, but not the obligation, to exercise their position at

    the given strike price. In other words, a call (put) option offers the owner the right to buy (sell) the

    underlying asset at the given strike price on or before maturity of the contract from the writer or issuer

    of the contract. A call (put) option will be exercised when the spot market price at the end of the

    contract is above (below) the strike price.

    To be long in an option contract is to have purchased the contract, and therefore hold the right to

    exercise the option upon maturity. To be short in an option is to have written or sold the option contract

    to a market participant.

    As can be seen in Figure (1), a long call option has limited downside risk when the value of the

    underlying asset changes (S) but unlimited payoffs with an increase in the value of S. As the value of

    the underlying asset increases, the owner of the call option will be able to exercise the option at the

    3

  • agreed upon strike price (K). He is therefore able to buy the asset at a lower price than market value,

    in turn buying low, selling high. His downside risk is limited to the premium he must pay to own the

    contract if the contract is not exercised. In contrast, a short call option has unlimited downside risk

    and limited payoffs. The payoffs of a short call are limited to the premium received by the writer of

    the contract when the call is not exercised. As the value of the underlying asset increases, the writer of

    the call option is obligated to sell the underlying asset to the owner of the contract (the one in the long

    position) at the strike price, which is below the market value of the asset. He is therefore selling low,

    buying high, which puts him in a position of unlimited loss as the asset value rises.

    On the other side of the market, a long put option has limited downside risk as well as limited

    payoffs. The owner of the put option has the right to sell the underlying asset at the strike price K to

    the writer of the contract. The long put option will be exercised if the value of the underlying asset

    (S) is below the strike price (K). In this scenario, the owner of the long put option sells the asset at a

    price higher than the market value to the writer of the contract. He is therefore selling high, buying

    low. The downside risk of the long put option is limit to the premium the agent must pay for the right

    to own the contract, even if the contract is not exercised. The writer of the contract has a short put

    option position, and is also faced with limited payoffs and large but limited downside risks. He will be

    obligated to buy the underlying asset from the owner of the contract at the strike price K. Once again,

    his payoff is limited to the premium he receives if the contract is not exercised.

    Figure 1: Call and Put Option Strategies

    The above figure illustrates call and put option positions and payoffs. The value of the underlying asset in the spot market is represented by S and thestrike price of the option is K. Long calls have unlimited gains, and limited losses, whereas long puts have limited gains and limited losses. Short calls haveunlimited losses and limited gains, whereas short puts have limited gains and unlimited losses.

    In the context of the foreign exchange market, a currency call option on US dollars (USD) in Colombia

    (COP) gives the owner the right to buy USD from the writer of the contract at the strike price. The

    4

  • owner of the contract is long a call option in this case. Therefore, the call option will be exercised if the

    spot exchange rate of COPUSD is above the strike price, or in other words, COP has depreciated since

    the issuance of the option. On the other hand, a put option on USD in Colombia gives the owner the

    right to sell USD to the writer of the contract at the strike price. In other words, the owner is long a

    put option and the writer of the contract is short a put option. If the put option is exercised, then the

    spot price at maturity has fallen below the strike price and COP has appreciated in value.

    Currency option contracts are beneficial for traders and hedgers alike because they mitigate some of

    the risk of drastic movements in the future value of the exchange rate. Market participants interested

    in further offsetting risks associated with long or short options positions can also engage in dynamic

    delta hedging, which allows them to continuously rebalance their portfolio in the the underlying asset

    (DeRosa, 2011).

    As explained in Chen (1998), the standard technique for a trader to hedge their position in the

    options market against the risk of changing prices is referred to as dynamic delta hedging. Traders are

    able to reduce risks associated with the movement in the price of the underlying asset by taking an

    offsetting position in the spot market. For small movements in the exchange rate, the value of the hedge

    will change in an equal but opposite direction. The delta is the responsiveness of the price of the option

    to changes in the value of the underlying asset. The delta of an option will change as the contract nears

    expiration or when implied volatility or the exchange rate changes. As the delta changes, traders will

    adjust their offsetting position through buying or selling the underlying asset.

    For a long call option, the offsetting delta hedging position in the spot market will be to short the

    underlying asset. When an owner of the long call wants to hedge his position, he will sell a given amount

    of the underlying asset directly in the spot market. The amount sold is determined by the delta of the

    option at the time of hedging. Therefore, if the contract is for USD, the owner will sell USD in the spot

    market. For a short call option, an offsetting delta hedging position in the spot market will be to long

    the underlying asset. For the writer of the contract, he will purchase a given amount of the underlying

    asset in the spot market to hedge his option contract position. If the contract is in USD, he will buy

    USD in the spot market.

    For a long put option, the offsetting delta hedging position in the spot market will be to long the

    underlying asset. For a contract in USD, the owner of a put option will purchase a given amount of

    USD in the spot market. The size of the purchase will be determined by the delta of the contract at the

    time of hedging. For a short put option, the writer of the contract will offset his position in the options

    market by selling the underlying asset in the spot market. For a contract in USD, the writer of the

    contract will sell a given amount of USD in the spot market to hedge his short put option position. Once

    5

  • again, the size of the offsetting spot market position is determined by the delta, or the responsiveness

    of the option price to changes in the value of the underlying asset at the time of hedging.

    By taking an offsetting position in the spot market, agents that are dynamically delta hedging their

    options contracts should theoretically cover their hedging costs by the premium or payoff they gain from

    the option contract. Even if the contract is not exercised, through consistent daily or weekly hedging,

    the agent will be able to purchase or sell off the underlying asset over the period to maturity and cover

    his costs with the premium or payoff derived from the option contract. Dynamically delta hedging allows

    the agent to hold a neutral portfolio position with lower costs than relying solely on the spot market or

    options market.

    3 Literature Review

    The following section will first delve into details on the currency options market and past literature

    that has addressed how they can be used by central banks. It will then detail literature on central

    bank intervention into foreign exchange markets in general. Finally, it will address macroeconomic

    fundamentals that influence exchange rate movements as well as the linkages between inflation targeting

    goals and exchange rates in emerging markets.

    3.1 Currency Options

    Currency options are used by various agents in the foreign exchange market, including currency traders,

    speculators, hedgers and portfolio managers. The options market is mainly an interbank over-the-counter

    market. The majority of currency options are European, meaning the option can only be exercised at

    expiration (DeRosa, 2011). The global daily average turnover on a net-net basis5 in the foreign exchange

    market in April 2013 was US$ 5.3 trillion, of which spot transactions were 38 percent and options were

    less than 6 percent. Net-gross daily turnover6 in emerging markets made up roughly 6 percent of the

    global foreign exchange market (BIS, 2013).3

    If the central bank is the main writer of options, it can crowd out all other writers who may engage

    in dynamic delta hedging that is potentially destabilizing (HKMA, 2000). Breuer (1999) argues that if

    market makers are net long positions, their dynamic delta hedging behavior can lower volatility. When

    option buyers purchase domestic currency in the spot market to hedge their positions when the currency

    5Net-net basis adjusts for local and cross-border inter-dealer double-counting6Net-gross basis adjusts for only local inter-dealer double-counting3This omits Singapore and Hong Kong turnover. Including these two would increase the share of turnover in emerging marketsto 40.2 percent

    6

  • is depreciating, and sell it when it is appreciating, this will help stabilize exchange rates. In other

    words, given the option is written for USD, in a long call a delta hedging position would sell USD

    when the domestic currency is depreciating and buy USD when it is appreciating, therefore canceling

    out volatile pressure. Archer (2005) argues that the transparency with which the central bank auctions

    options contracts to market participants introduces stability and additional hedging instruments into

    the market. Therefore, central bank use of currency options can be effective in stabilizing the foreign

    exchange market and controlling volatility when it influences market liquidity and expectations.

    The Hong Kong Monetary authority notes that options contracts can lower costs of hedging risk,

    enhance the liquidity of the underlying asset and work to stabilize the foreign exchange market when

    issued by the central bank (HKMA, 2000). Options contracts issued by the central bank can mitigate

    the destabilizing dynamic delta hedging behavior that would otherwise be conducted by private market

    participants in reaction to changing market conditions.

    Authors such as Garber and Spencer (1995) and Grossman and Zhou (1996) have found a positive

    link between dynamic delta hedging and spot market volatility. Therefore, one risk central banks must

    consider when writing options contracts while dynamically delta hedging their position is that such

    hedging activity may amplify the appreciation or depreciation pressure on the exchange rate, which

    is contrary to the objectives of the central bank. The authors take into consideration only one-sided

    positions, such as issuing only calls or only puts. The alternative butterfly strategy position, or issuing

    both calls and puts, establishes a net hedging position that is smaller than a one-sided position in the

    market, and therefore will be less destabilizing.

    As HKMA (2000) notes, this stabilization will occur even if the amount of options contracts sold

    remains constant because the price of the option changes in response to changes in the market value of

    the domestic currency. When the central bank is holding a long position in the domestic currency (or

    a short position in USD), as market pressures increase, the central banks long position increases while

    the option buyers hold an offsetting short position. This would have a similar impact as a spot market

    intervention. The effectiveness of this strategy will depend on the extent to which market participants

    dynamically hedge their positions, and whether the size of the options contracts are large enough to

    have a significant impact.

    Wiseman (1999) argues that governments should commit themselves to frequent and regular auctions

    of short-dated physically-delivered currency options as a mechanism to stabilize exchange rates. Since

    almost all central bank authorities would like to reduce exchange rate volatility, without pushing it all

    the way to zero, official auctions would encourage private banks to buy options and exercise them when

    profitable. dynamic delta hedging on the part of the trader will substitute for actively pursuing the

    7

  • same position in the market.

    3.2 Central Bank Currency Market Intervention

    The main goals of the central bank when intervening in currency markets are to smooth exchange

    rate volatility, supply liquidity into foreign exchange markets and to control the amount of foreign

    exchange reserves (Moreno, 2005). The broad motives for intervention are driven by macroeconomic

    goals, such as inflation targeting, maintaining economic stability and competitiveness, preventing crises

    and boosting growth. Acosta-Ormaechea and Coble (2011) find that in emerging markets with high

    levels of dollarization and a strong exchange rate pass through, inflation targeting is more effective

    through policies that target exchange rates rather than interest rates.

    There are four main channels through which the central bank can intervene into currency markets

    (Archer, 2005). First, in the monetary channel, changes in the domestic interest rate relative to the

    foreign interest rate can alter the value of the domestic currency. This occurs through a change in

    the domestic monetary policy. Next, in the portfolio balance channel, relative scarcity of the domestic

    currency to the foreign currency can appreciate the value of the domestic currency. Here the central

    bank intervention into the spot market determines the relative scarcity or abundance of the domestic

    currency, in turn directly influencing the value of the nominal exchange rate. Third, through the signaling

    and expectations channel, the central bank can shape expectations on future monetary and exchange

    rate policy. Influencing expectations through the promise of future intervention can curb speculative

    behavior and coordinate the direction of the currency towards equilibrium. The credibility of the signal

    is also critical. Signals to control appreciation tend to be more credible than those to curb depreciation.

    Lastly, in the order flow channel, the central bank tracks order flows to predict subsequent price action.

    Central bankers can alter the order flow with their own orders that must be large relative to the total

    market turnover. Due to less liquidity in the market and better access to information on order flows,

    this channel may be more effective in emerging markets than advanced economies.

    Canales-Kriljenko (2003) finds that in emerging markets and developing economies, 82 percent of

    interventions take place in the spot market because this is the main or only currency market in the

    economy. If the intervention is unsterilized, it can directly influence the direction of nominal exchange

    rates through the monetary channel. If sterilized, the intervention will affect volatility through expecta-

    tions and by attempting to curb speculative behavior. The success of the latter interventions in lowering

    volatility has been questionable (Breuer, 1999).

    Sterilized spot market interventions involve exchange rate intervention by the central bank without

    any change in the countrys monetary base. The intervention occurs through the buying and selling

    8

  • of domestic and foreign bonds by the central bank (Weber, 1986). The primary purpose of sterilized

    interventions has been to counter appreciation of the domestic currency in fixed or managed float ex-

    change rate regimes without impacting real exchange rates to diminish inflationary pressure coming from

    changes in foreign currency inflows (Agenor, 2004).

    Weber (1986) finds that from a theoretical perspective, sterilized interventions can in fact influence

    exchange rates if bonds denominated in different currencies are not perfect substitutes, but empiri-

    cal evidence from the US indicates that sterilized interventions do not impact exchange rates. Craig

    and Humpage (2001) agree that such interventions have been ineffective because they do not affect

    macroeconomic fundamentals and instead influence expectations and perceptions, whereas unsterilized

    interventions can conflict with price stabilization but are unnecessary because the same effect can be

    achieved through open market operations.

    In terms of the size, frequency and timing of intervention, Mihaljek (2004) cites that when the

    goal of the intervention is to influence the exchange rate, central banks find larger and less frequent

    interventions to be more effective. In contrast, when the goal is reserve accumulation, frequent but

    smaller interventions are more successful. Emerging market policy makers viewed small and less frequent

    interventions as more likely to be successful than large but less frequent interventions.

    Over the last decade, emerging markets have experienced a significant increase in international finan-

    cial flows. Even though these flows are generally beneficial in terms of growth and welfare enhancement,

    emerging markets frequently experience surges or sudden stops in flows, creating economic instability.

    Such volatile flows contribute to large fluctuations in exchange rates, fueling of domestic asset bubbles,

    poor resource allocation, balance sheet risks and banking or financial crises. One way central banks have

    created a buffer against the downside of surges and sudden stops has been the build up of reserves and

    intervention directly in the spot market (IMF, 2010).

    3.3 Macroeconomic Fundamentals, Inflation Targeting and Exchange Rates

    The value of one countrys currency reflects the markets expectation about current and future macroe-

    conomic conditions, and therefore reacts to changes in macroeconomic fundamentals, such as trade,

    monetary policy, balance of payments, aggregate demand and aggregate supply (Obstfeld and Rogoff,

    1999). Many theoretical models have linked exchange rate movements to changes in macroeconomic

    conditions. These include the monetary model presented in Dornbusch (1976) where an increase in

    the money supply decreases domestic interest rates to adjust for the excess supply of real money bal-

    ances. Through the uncovered interest rate parity, the decrease in the domestic interest rate requires

    a change in the nominal exchange rate. Due to short run sticky prices, the depreciation in the short

    9

  • run is larger than in the long run equilibrium. In portfolio balance model presented in Dornbusch and

    Fischer (1980), the exchange rate determines the equilibrium between domestic money, domestic bonds

    and foreign bonds. Changes in money supply or supply of bonds will drive changes in the exchange rates

    to maintain equilibrium. An increase in the supply of domestic bonds, an increase in the foreign interest

    rate, or expectation of future depreciation will result in a depreciation of the domestic currency. An

    increase the supply of foreign bonds or an increase in the domestic interest rate result in an appreciation

    of the domestic currency.

    Inflation targeting has been adopted by a number of both emerging and advanced economies over

    the last two decades. Even though it has been considered advantageous as a framework for monetary

    policy, the macroeconomic effects of inflation targeting in empirical terms have been limited (Levin,

    Natalucci and Piger, 2004). In industrialized economies, inflation targeting has been most effective in

    controlling long run inflation expectations and lowering the persistence of inflation. Fraga, Goldajn

    and Minella (2003) argue that emerging markets face more acute trade-offs when choosing the design

    of their inflation targeting monetary policy, including higher output and inflation volatility. Due to a

    more volatile macroeconomic environment, the implementation and commitment to inflation targeting

    becomes more difficult in emerging markets than in advanced economies.

    The impact of exchange rates on inflation targets and on monetary policy goals has been a concern

    for many emerging economies due to the weaker financial system and their susceptibility to external

    shocks. Stone, Roger, Nordstrom, Shimizu, Kisinbay and Restrepo (2009) argue that the exchange rate

    is more important as a policy tool for inflation-targeting emerging markets than for their counterparts

    in advanced economies for a number of reasons. In emerging markets, a high exchange rate pass-

    through indicates lower policy credibility and translates to a closer link between price and exchange rate

    movements. Additionally, less developed financial systems in these countries correspond to more rigidity

    in currency markets, which amplifies the impact of exchange rate shocks on the domestic economy.

    Intervention into currency markets reflects the desire of central banks in emerging markets to mitigate

    the impact of short-term currency fluctuations on output. Finally, active management of the exchange

    rate is seen as a way to promote financial stability, which can also minimize the negative impact of

    sudden stops in foreign currency inflows.

    In contrast, Sek (2008) finds that the reaction of monetary policy7 to exchange rate shocks in three

    inflation-targeting East Asian economies has declined after the East Asian crisis.6 A high exchange

    rate pass-through in emerging markets makes it more difficult for central banks to target low inflation

    rates and maintain price stability (Minella, de Freitas, Goldfajn and Muinhos, 2003, Fraga et al., 2003).

    7The monetary policy measures used include money demand (M1), short-term interest rates, output gap, and inflation6The three economies are Thailand, Korea and Philippines.

    10

  • Reyes (2013) argues that the lower pass-through effect is a natural reaction to the implementation of

    inflation-targeting policies in emerging economies, but the effects of nominal exchange rate fluctuations

    on inflation rates can still be felt. If the pass-through effect is on the decline, this may explain why Sek

    finds a lower reaction of monetary policy to exchange rate shocks post-crisis.

    An appreciation of the domestic currency can lead to lower output and inflation in future periods

    due to expenditure switching and because import prices will not rise as quickly with the appreciation

    (Taylor, 2001). The reaction of interest rates to an appreciation is indirect as interest rates react to

    changes in inflation and real GDP instead of directly to fluctuations in the exchange rate. Taylor

    concludes the reaction of policy makers to changes in the exchange rate by adjusting interest rates may

    not improve performance because this mechanism is already build into the policy rule indirectly and

    because the reaction may make swings in real output and inflation even worse. Additionally, changes

    in exchange rates under floating exchange rate regimes may indicate changing productivity and should

    not be negated.

    4 Historical Analysis of Issuing Options: The Case of Colombia

    Colombia has experimented with many different intervention tools in its recent history. The Colom-

    bian central bank began systemic currency market intervention following the introduction of a floating

    exchange rate regime and adoption on inflation-targeting monetary policy in 1999 (Uribe and Toro,

    2005). It first started with the introduction of currency options for the purposes of reserve accumulation

    and later to control for volatility. From 2000 to 2012, the average yearly purchase of US dollars by

    the Colombian Central Bank was US$ 2.2 billion8, or an average of 1.7 percent of market transactions

    (Echavarria, Melo, Tellez and Villamizar, 2013). From 2005 to 2007 as well as from 2010 to 2012, the

    purchase of US dollars by the central bank was much larger, the latter reflecting a change in policy to

    daily discretionary purchases.

    Trading of Colombias currency represents approximately 0.05 percent of all currencies traded on a

    net-gross basis, amounting to daily average trades of US$ 3.34 billion in 2013. The domestic interbank

    forex market makes up only 25 percent of the total market for COPUSD. Domestic foreign exchange

    markets in Chile and Peru represent similar characteristics, as can be seen in Table (1). As discussed

    above, the majority of domestic forex transactions are interbank transactions. In Chile, for example,

    interbank spot market transactions make up approximately 52 percent of all domestic spot transactions.2

    8Sales were smaller at US$ 571 million2Based on data from Central Bank of Chile. Data from statistics on forex trading in the formal market. Represents sum ofinterbank transactions, total sales and total purchases in USD in Chile in 2013.

    11

  • Table 1: Foreign Exchange Markets: Global vs. Domestic

    Colombia2004 2007 2010 2013

    Global Amount (USD Mil) 802 1,860 2,794 3,343Percent World Total 0.03% 0.04% 0.06% 0.05%

    Domestic Amount (USD Mil) 396 780 1041 845Percent of Total Traded 49.38% 41.93% 37.26% 25.28%

    Chile2004 2007 2010 2013

    Global Amount (USD Mil) 2,462 4,003 5,544 11,956Percent World Total 0.09% 0.09% 0.11% 0.18%

    Domestic Amount (USD Mil) 1,295 1,698 1,518 2,488Percent of Total Traded 52.59% 42.42% 27.38% 20.81%

    Peru2004 2007 2010 2013

    Global Amount (USD Mil) 306 805 1,425 2,171Percent World Total 0.01% 0.02% 0.03 % 0.03%

    Domestic Amount (USD Mil) 81 140 477 841Percent of Total Traded 26.39% 17.42% 33.50% 38.72%

    Global amount traded reflects average daily net-gross transactions. Domestic amount traded reflects interbank trading volume asreported by the central banks. Data for global transactions from Bank of International Settlements.

    The Colombian peso has been experiencing steady appreciation since 2009. From 2002 to 2009, it

    experienced a number of periods with high volatility, where the bid-ask prices on the market exchange

    rate were notably different official exchange rate. Figure (2) illustrates the differences between the bid

    price, ask price, and official exchange rate in Colombia from 2002 to 2014, as well as the differences

    between the official rates and bid or ask prices. Since 2012, the spread between official rates and market

    prices has been much lower than in previous periods.

    Colombia is one of the few countries to date that have auctioned call and put options to mitigate

    exchange rate volatility and accumulate reserves. For the purposes of reserve accumulation and decu-

    mulation, the central bank auctioned options contracts on a monthly basis. The options were exercised

    when the exchange rate appreciated or depreciated over than 20-day moving average mean, and the

    amount to be auctioned in the subsequent month was determined at the end of each contract.

    The volatility options with 30-day maturity were auctioned whenever the exchange rate changed

    more that 4 percent of the 20-day moving average. The maximum exercise amount was US$ 180 million.

    From 1999 to 2009, there were a total of 38 options contracts auctioned by the Colombian central bank.

    The options intervention strategy was abandoned when the central bank switched intervention strategies

    to a daily discrete intervention plan, where the central bank purchased an average of US$ 20 million

    per day. From August 2012, the amount purchased varied from US$ 20 million to US$ 50 million daily.

    The average intervention was 3.72 percent of total USD traded in the Colombian FOREX market, with

    12

  • Figure 2: Colombian Peso Dynamics

    The top graph represents the value of the official COPUSD exchange rate, the bid price and the ask price in the market. The bottom graph illustrates thedifference between the official exchange rate and the market exchange rates (bid price and ask price). The spread between official and market rates hasdiminished in recent years. Market rates from OANDA. Official exchange rate data from Banco Republica de Colombia.

    13

  • a maximum intervention that totaled 33.6 percent of the market volume.

    The auction of options contracts in Colombia were fully transparent and the benefits of these auctions

    were derived from the hedging operations of market participants (Uribe and Toro, 2005). When issuing

    options contracts, the main objectives of the central bank were to avoid excessive volatility in the

    exchange rate in a way that would uphold inflation targets, to strengthen the international liquidity

    position domestically, and smooth any deviations of the exchange rate from its long run trend. From

    2000 to 2005, call options were deemed successful in influencing both the value of foreign exchange rate

    and the volatility. The call options were able to mitigate the increasing depreciation trend in 2003 that

    threatened inflation targets. Mandeng (2003) finds that volatility call options issued until 2003 were only

    moderately successful. On the other hand, Uribe and Toro (2005) state that put options were successful

    in the accumulation of reserves from 1999 to 2002. They also find that Colombias intervention policies

    have been largely consistent with its goals of inflation targeting, such that changes in monetary policy

    came first through interest rates, and then through intervention in currency markets.

    Starting in 2008, the Colombian central bank began purchasing US$ 20 million daily, first for two

    months in 2008, then in 2010 for five months, in 2011 for six months, and every month since 2012.

    Following the policies of Chile and Israel for daily discretionary intervention, US$ 20 million is the

    average of the daily purchases in those countries (Echavarria et al., 2013). Colombia abandoned the use

    of options-based intervention once it began the daily purchase of US dollars. The change in policy has

    been considered a good mechanism for accumulating reserves without promoting speculative behavior

    because it is a consistent and transparent intervention.

    Mandeng (2003) uses an event study to observe the impact of auctioning three call options on

    exchange rate volatility, comparing the volatility before and after the time of maturity. At the time of

    his paper, Colombia had only issued these three options as a means to control volatility, and Mandeng

    finds them to be only slightly successful in lowering volatility. Using a similar approach, Table (2)

    illustrates the same analysis for all the call and put options issued since 2002. Volatility is measured

    as the annualized standard deviation of the log difference in daily exchange rates over a 10 day rolling

    window. Comparing volatility 2, 5, and 10 days before and after the contract maturity yields similar

    results, where volatility is successfully lowered only in 30 to 40 percent of the cases.

    In Table (3) the volatility calculation spans a two day, five day and ten day window depending on

    which period is observed. Volatility is measured as the annualized standard deviation of the log difference

    in daily exchange rates with a rolling window of 2, 5, and 10 days. With this calculation volatility after

    contract expiration compared to volatility at the time of maturity is lower in 52 to 58 percent of the

    cases. Using the latter calculation with different rolling windows captures the volatility in exchange rates

    14

  • related specifically to the period that is being observed. The previous calculation compares volatility

    that includes exchange rates before, during, and after maturity, yielding misleading results.

    Part of the reason that past volatility options contracts were only moderately successful in lowering

    volatility in Colombia may be due to their sporadic issuance that went unhedged. Figures (3) and (4)

    illustrate intervention with put options and call options respectively. The sporadic issuance of options

    yields inconsistent results in lowering volatility. The benefits of greater liquidity, building markets

    and increasing the flow of information between policy makers and traders occur when auctions of the

    contracts occur consistently, as discussed in (Breuer, 1999).

    Additionally, the Central Bank only issued either calls or puts, not bundles of calls and puts at

    different strike prices. Auctioning bundles of calls and puts at different strike prices, while holding an

    offsetting position increases the information flow between policy makers and traders of expectations,

    lowers the chances of speculative attacks9, and mitigates some of the costs of hedging. The net hedging

    position is lower for a mixed portfolio, therefore the position of the central bank in the spot market is

    less disruptive than if it took only one side of the market. Though the Colombian central bank issued

    only one side of the market at a time, there is no evidence that it engaged in dynamic delta hedging to

    offset the risks associated with issuing volatility options.

    In Tables (4) and (5), a simple regression tests the impact of the volatility options on the change in

    the value of COPUSD from the day before maturity to the day the contract was exercised(t-1 to t), and

    from the day of exercise to one day after maturity (t to t+1). The issuance of volatility calls options

    had a significant, contemporaneous effect on exchange rate value at the time of maturity. At the day

    of exercise of the call options, the change in COPUSD from the previous day was lower. The issuance

    of volatility put options had a lagged effect on the exchange rate value. The exercise of put options

    impacted the difference in value of the COPUSD the following day. In Table (5), the dummy variable

    represents the size of the option relative to the total volume traded in one day. If the exercised volume

    at maturity was greater than 20 percent of total volume, the dummy variable took on the value of one,

    otherwise zero. Taking into consideration the relative size of the intervention did not significantly alter

    the results, which may reflect the influence of volatility options through the expectations channel rather

    than through the portfolio balance channel.

    9Speculative attacks in currency markets occur when there is a massive sell off of a particular currency, leading to a significantdepreciation or devaluation of the currency, depending on whether the exchange rate regime is floating or fixed.

    15

  • Table 2: Volatility Options Contracts Issued in Colombia - Part 1

    Put OptionsDate Exercised Volatility Before Volatility After Success

    USD Mil 10 Days 5 Days 2 Days 2 Days 5 Days 10 Days Short Mid Long17-Dec-04 179.9 4.57% 5.14% 5.0% 5.46% 4.75% 6.93% - Lower -11-Jul-06 180.0 15.94% 13.81% 14.14% 13.50% 15.83% 11.27% Lower - Lower31-Jul-06 180.0 11.27% 13.90% 13.93% 9.56% 9.99% 9.21% Lower Lower Lower10-Aug-06 33.8 14.17% 9.99% 7.77% 9.00% 6.75% 4.86% - Lower Lower30-Oct-06 180.0 2.81% 5.31% 4.22% 3.89% 4.32% 5.83% Lower Lower -21-Dec-06 10.0 3.64% 3.01% 3.14% 4.14% 4.21% 3.22% - - Lower30-Mar-07 0.0 4.37% 7.22% 6.21% 11.30% 12.37% 11.58% - - -3-May-07 180.0 7.75% 7.06% 3.15% 5.51% 7.45% 9.76% - - -15-May-07 180.0 5.51% 10.31% 9.76% 11.49% 8.18% 9.04% - Lower -4-Jun-07 14.5 9.04% 12.56% 15.05% 12.77% 15.80% 9.40% Lower - -20-Sep-07 180.0 9.00% 14.04% 10.23% 19.59% 19.91% 14.09% - - -11-Dec-07 0.0 12.51% 11.66% 9.09% 8.11% 6.73% 5.44% Lower Lower Lower15-Jan-08 102.7 5.63% 4.25% 6.75% 13.16% 15.25% 18.77% - - -20-Feb-08 168.0 8.25% 7.55% 6.91% 10.98% 10.41% 11.94% - - -25-Mar-08 62.5 18.50% 16.72% 13.10% 15.26% 9.82% 11.15% - Lower Lower4-Jun-08 180.0 5.64% 5.89% 5.20% 7.39% 7.81% 10.10% - - -18-Dec-08 2.3 3.87% 9.37% 8.38% 14.47% 15.35% 6.61% - - -17-Mar-09 179.0 12.93% 14.71% 12.31% 16.06% 17.80% 21.00% - - -27-Apr-09 0.0 11.84% 16.53% 16.61% 19.96% 18.32% 18.46% - - -3-Jun-09 180.0 11.60% 12.88% 14.93% 17.18% 16.20% 14.27% - - -22-Jul-09 179.5 12.37% 17.85% 16.27% 13.69% 11.87% 24.92% Lower Lower -

    Call OptionsDate Exercised Volatility Before Volatility After Success

    USD Mil 10 Days 5 Days 2 Days 2 Days 5 Days 10 Days Short Mid Long29-Jul-02 180.0 9.28% 9.90% 11.23% 10.55% 8.45% 6.57% Lower Lower Lower01-Aug-02 109.5 8.50% 10.63% 10.55% 6.14% 6.57% 20.24% Lower Lower -02-Oct-02 124.5 7.00% 10.70% 9.87% 9.72% 8.75% 6.25% Lower Lower Lower10-Apr-06 168.5 2.87% 4.08% 8.62% 10.52% 10.16% 10.98% - - -16-May-06 179.8 7.46% 6.49% 11.84% 17.90% 14.57% 13.37% - - -18-May-06 179.8 3.42% 11.86% 16.60% 15.34% 15.92% 16.88% Lower - -23-May-06 179.9 11.86% 17.90% 14.57% 16.25% 16.88% 13.01% - Lower -25-May-06 179.9 11.79% 15.34% 15.92% 17.57% 16.62% 12.78% - - -27-Jun-06 56.4 11.30% 9.96% 7.72% 7.19% 15.93 % 13.92% Lower - -26-Jun-07 176.5 13.13% 17.10% 16.28% 17.45 % 11.00% 10.41% - Lower Lower13-Aug-07 179.9 10.95% 8.62% 8.23% 9.01% 9.39% 5.38% - - Lower22-Nov-07 12.5 5.02% 9.35% 8.81% 10.57% 6.78% 10.81% - Lower -07-Oct-08 174.9 47.27% 32.35% 26.48% 34.99% 41.28% 49.22% - - -24-Oct-08 59.7 39.20% 46.64% 41.88% 24.36% 21.19% 11.89% Lower Lower Lower30-Jan-09 180.0 8.40% 12.32% 11.30% 15.13% 15.61% 14.12% - - -02-Feb-09 180.0 9.43% 11.30% 15.07% 15.61% 17.55% 17.43% - - -12-Feb-09 8.5 15.29% 17.55% 11.87% 18.07% 15.86% 15.81% - Lower -

    Volatility is measured as the annualized standard deviation of the log difference in daily exchange rates over a 10 day rollingwindow. Using this calculation to test whether volatility is lowered after the option is exercised yields only moderatelysuccessful results partly because it accounts of movements in the exchange rate before, during and after the contractmaturity.

    16

  • Table 3: Volatility Options Contracts Issued in Colombia - Part 2

    Put OptionsDate Volatility at Maturity Volatility After Success

    (2) (5) (10) 2 days 5 days 10 days 2 days 5 days 10 days17-Dec-04 1.10% 9.97% 10.19% 2.45% 10.91% 22.23% - - -11-Jul-06 18.34% 13.68% 11.11% 14.70% 9.51% 11.27% Lower Lower -31-Jul-06 0.00% 10.43% 14.17% 5.22% 4.09% 9.21% - Lower Lower10-Aug-06 12.84% 8.61% 9.21% 4.83% 2.91% 4.86% Lower Lower Lower30-Oct-06 0.00% 5.47% 4.29% 4.39% 4.09% 4.17% - Lower Lower21-Dec-06 5.33% 5.24% 4.34% 2.76% 1.90% 3.22% Lower Lower Lower30-Mar-07 7.62% 5.39% 6.76% 21.91% 17.03% 11.58% - - -03-May-07 12.24% 7.53% 5.82% 0.05% 7.66% 9.76% Lower - -15-May-07 18.20% 10.86% 11.94% 0.21% 4.14% 9.04% Lower Lower Lower04-Jun-07 0.00% 17.37% 14.65% 0.32% 11.99% 9.40% - Lower Lower20-Sep-07 40.66% 27.97% 20.43% 2.48% 8.03% 14.09% Lower Lower Lower11-Dec-07 4.66% 5.29% 8.25% 1.40% 7.62% 5.44% Lower - Lower15-Jan-08 24.67% 15.47% 12.06% 8.36% 12.47% 18.77% Lower Lower -20-Feb-08 10.41% 9.01% 7.31% 24.88% 12.72% 11.94% - - -25-Mar-08 0.00% 0.00% 12.69% 24.45% 14.70% 11.15% - - Lower04-Jun-08 10.42% 7.63% 6.15% 13.33% 8.88% 10.10% - - -18-Dec-08 11.55% 18.34% 14.09% 12.20% 5.13% 6.61% - Lower Lower17-Mar-09 30.36% 18.51% 16.46% 4.44% 17.57% 21.00% Lower Lower -27-Apr-09 0.00% 8.38% 15.26% 20.20% 24.92% 18.46% - - -03-Jun-09 1.05% 19.55% 17.48% 1.25% 3.42% 14.27% - Lower Lower22-Jul-09 13.85% 10.28% 14.96% 7.38% 14.13% 24.92% Lower - -

    Call OptionsDate Volatility at Maturity Volatility After Success

    (2) (5) (10) 2 days 5 days 10 days 2 days 5 days 10 days29-Jul-02 0.00% 10.43% 10.59% 11.46% 7.07% 6.57% - Lower Lower01-Aug-02 7.41% 7.89% 10.25% 2.60% 6.28% 6.25% Lower Lower Lower02-Oct-02 5.67% 10.59% 11.44% 4.31% 11.33% 9.76% Lower - Lower10-Apr-06 0.00% 10.46% 8.80% 15.29% 7.75% 10.98% - Lower -16-May-06 27.25% 16.50% 16.60% 21.13% 11.51% 13.37% Lower Lower Lower18-May-06 21.13% 19.50% 17.90% 15.17% 8.71% 17.57% Lower Lower Lower23-May-06 22.66% 13.76% 15.92% 17.38% 24.77% 16.62% Lower - -25-May-06 17.38% 15.72% 16.25% 22.08% 19.10% 15.32% - - Lower27-Jun-06 0.00% 9.39% 7.07% 0.84% 20.48% 13.92% - - -26-Jun-07 11.29% 13.89% 14.45% 8.19% 14.58% 10.26% Lower - Lower13-Aug-07 0.00% 18.11% 12.70% 19.09% 32.76% 27.18% - - -22-Nov-07 10.68% 8.03% 10.13% 8.85% 5.52% 10.81% Lower Lower -07-Oct-08 55.54% 40.19% 33.43% 31.23% 47.03% 49.22% Lower - -24-Oct-08 20.84% 28.82% 44.15% 14.50% 10.01% 14.69% Lower Lower Lower30-Jan-09 8.42% 16.65% 14.44% 18.93% 15.11% 14.12% - Lower Lower02-Feb-09 0.00% 16.76% 15.29% 20.85% 17.45% 17.43% - - -12-Feb-09 0.26% 18.14% 17.43% 3.81% 6.17% 15.81% - Lower Lower

    Volatility is measured as the annualized standard deviation of the log difference in daily exchange rates with a rolling window of 2, 5,and 10 days. Comparing volatility at the time of maturity to 2, 5, and 10 days after maturity yields more successful results. After theoption is exercised, volatility decreases in 52 to 58 percent of all cases.

    17

  • Figure 3: Volatility Put Options Interventions

    Data from Banco Republica de Colombia.

    Figure 4: Volatility Call Options Interventions

    Data from Banco Republica de Colombia.

    18

  • Table 4: Impact of Options Issued on COPUSD

    Dependent Variable: Change in COPUSD (t-1 to t)Calls Puts

    C 12.90** 0.02(2.07) (0.23)

    Amount Issued (Calls) -0.0717**(2.07)

    Amount Issued (Puts) -0.0002(-0.35)

    R2 0.22 0.10N.obs 17 21

    Dependent Variable: Change in COPUSD (t to t+1)

    Calls PutsC -3.12 0.15***

    (0.81) (2.64)Amount Issued (Calls) 0.02

    (0.82)Amount Issued (Puts) -0.0009***

    (2.62)R2 0.04 0.27N.obs 17 21

    The dependent variable is the change in exchange rate value of COPUSD during time of option maturity.It is calculated as the [St/St1] 1. The maturity of put options has a lagged impact on the exchangerate, whereas the maturity of call options has a contemporaneous impact on the exchange rate.

    Table 5: Impact of Options Issued on COPUSD with Dummy

    Dependent Variable: Change in COPUSD (t-1 to t)Calls Puts

    C 12.42* 0.03(1.94) (0.30)

    Amount Issued (Calls) -0.007*(-1.94)

    Amount Issued (Puts) -0.0002(-0.35)

    Dummy -0.003 0.0015(0.63) (0.37)

    R2 0.24 0.01N.obs 17 21

    Dependent Variable: Change in COPUSD (t to t+1)Calls Puts

    C -2.88 0.15**(0.73) (2.43)

    Amount Issued (Calls) 0.016(0.73)

    Amount Issued (Puts) -0.0008**(2.39)

    Dummy 0.0015 - 0.0017(0.62) (0.60)

    R2 0.06 0.28N.obs 17 21

    The dependent variable is the change in exchange rate value of COPUSD during time of option maturity.It is calculated as the [St/St1]1. The maturity of put options has a lagged impact on the exchange rate,whereas the maturity of call options has a contemporaneous impact on the exchange rate. The dummyvariable represents the size of the option relative to the total volume traded in one day. If the exercisedvolume at maturity was greater than 20 percent of total volume, the dummy variable took on the valueof one, otherwise zero. The values in parenthesis are t-statistics, and *, **, *** represent significance of10, 5, and 1 percent.

    19

  • 5 Trading Strategies for the Central Bank

    As seen Figure (1) above, holding only one side of the market, either call or put, would expose the

    central bank to risks associated with a drastic movement in the exchange rate that can be caused by

    speculative attacks or macroeconomic fundamentals. Because the central bank is such a large player in

    the market, hedging one side of the market may introduce adverse signals to traders. The central bank

    has the means to move the market in its favor. Therefore, market participants may be weary to enter

    into contracts with the central bank if there are any incentives for or suspicions of market manipulation.

    Entering into long contracts in either the put or call position will expose the currency market to

    excessive volatility through the hedging behavior of the traders on the opposite side of the contract.

    This is exactly the opposite to the goals of the central bank. It would also create opportunities for large

    market makers to hold short positions and diminish the control of the central bank over expectations of

    market participants.

    A short strangle trading strategy combines the short put option and short call option strategy. The

    short strangle strategy can be a good one for the central bank if there are limited risks of drastic exchange

    rate movements. The strategy allows the central bank to be the main market maker, exert control over

    the currency options market, and ensure liquidity in both the spot and options market.

    Despite the benefits of this strategy, there are a number of sizable drawbacks of pursuing such the

    short strangle strategy for the central bank specifically. Issuing call and put options exposes the central

    bank to unlimited downside risk with limited gains, as can be seen in Figure (5). Such a strategy would

    need to be dynamically delta hedged to protect the central bank from losses associated with drastic

    movement in the exchange rate. Hedging such a position through an offsetting spot market position

    would force the central bank to contribute to the persistent appreciation or depreciation of the exchange

    rate. The position of the central bank in the spot market to offset the risks of the short options counters

    the goals of the central bank to ensure stable exchange rate values and limit the volatility in the market.

    Authors such as Breuer (1999) have noted that dynamically delta hedging a long option contract

    position can introduce stabilizing forces into currency markets. By dynamically delta hedging a long

    call on USD, the trader will hold an offsetting short position in USD, for example. If the currency

    (COPUSD) depreciates, the trader will sell USD in domestic spot market. By doing so, the supply of

    USD in the spot market rises and therefore introduces appreciationary pressure that can counter the

    depreciation of the COP through the portfolio balance channel. Similarly, by holding a long put position,

    the offsetting spot market position would be long in USD. As the currency depreciates, the long put will

    expire out of the money and not be exercised. The trader will sell USD (or buy COP) in spot market

    to offset his position at maturity of the option contract. The offsetting spot market position contributes

    20

  • Figure 5: Short Strangle Option Strategy

    Short strangle presents an options trading position with unlimited risks and limited gains. The strike price for the short call and short put position equal atK.

    to a counteracting appreciation pressure on the depreciation of the COP.

    Due to the limited risks associated with a long options position, few traders would have the incentives

    to engage in dynamically delta hedging the position. Therefore, despite the fact that the hedging of a

    long position may introduce a stabilizing force into the currency market, the central bank cannot rely

    on market participants to act in such a way.

    The optimal strategy for the central bank will be one that includes both long and short positions

    in call and put options. Taking on both long and short positions in the option contract is considered a

    butterfly spread trading strategy. It is a neutral strategy with limited gains and limited downside risks.

    Call butterfly spreads consist of the trader holding two long and two short positions in the call option.

    Put butterfly spreads consist of the trader holding two long and two short positions in the put option.

    In each, the options with a high and low strike price are purchased, whereas two options in the middle

    strike price are issued. The strike prices for the long position are K1 and K3 in Table (6). The strike

    price (K2) for the short position is the midpoint price between the long strike prices.

    The traditional butterfly strategy has some benefits and drawbacks to reaching the goals of the

    central bank. Dynamic delta hedging of such a strategy is typically unnecessary, since holding a long

    and short position in each contract already hedges the risks to the trader of any movement in value of

    the underlying asset.

    For the central bank to have a strategic position in the spot market that is determined by the

    dynamic delta hedge, which increases information flow, domestic liquidity and which lowers costs of

    intervention, the optimal portfolio position for the central bank will be an alternative to the butterfly

    strategy. Specifically, the optimal strategy will be for the central bank to write or short one call or one

    21

  • Figure 6: Call and Put Butterfly Spreads

    Call and put butterfly spreads present a neutral position with limited risks and limited gains. The middle strike price for the short position is determined asK1+K3

    2.

    put option contract at one strike price, and buy or long two call options or two put options at strike

    prices that are slightly out of the money.

    The alternative strategy that is used to simulate the position of the central bank in the spot market

    is a derivative of the butterfly strategy. The gains and losses will be limited, and the net position of the

    central bank in the spot market will one similar to hedging a long position. The central bank will be

    able to issue contracts in the domestic market, purchase long positions in the global market, and hedge

    its portfolio in the domestic spot market.

    The long positions of the alternative butterfly strategy will hedge the risks associated with the short

    position. By dynamically delta hedging the net portfolio position with an offsetting position in the spot

    market, the central bank will have a position in the spot market that will stabilize the movement of the

    domestic currency, smooth volatility, and influence the expectations of traders in a favorable way so as

    to contribute to the stabilization goals of policymakers.

    By holding and issuing bundles of call and put options at varying strike prices, the central bank

    signals to the market that it is taking two positions. It is betting on the exchange rate to appreciate or

    depreciate, and therefore is protecting itself by nullifying the net impact when the exchange rate moves

    in either direction. The signal to the central bank from the market will come from how many of each

    option will be purchased by market participants. If traders anticipate the currency to depreciate, more

    call options will be purchased to hedge against the movement in the exchange rate. Between the date

    of issue and maturity of the contract, the central bank will hedge its net portfolio position in the spot

    market, which will provide a stabilizing force in the market.

    22

  • 6 Analytical Approach

    In the following section, we will address the analytical approach used to determine how options contacts

    may be used by central banks for intervention into currency markets. First, we will present the Garman-

    Kohlhagen option pricing model, the alternative butterfly strategy and dynamic delta hedging. Next,

    we will address the simulation of exchange rate movements used for analysis, as well as the derivation of

    option prices and hedging positions based on the simulated exchange rates. The main objective of the

    research is to test whether an alternative butterfly strategy with dynamic delta hedging can be a viable

    strategy for central bank currency market intervention. The goal is to understand whether dynamic

    delta hedging under this scenario is stabilizing and whether this strategy can provide the central bank

    with a low cost, targeted intervention plan.

    6.1 Alternative Butterfly Strategy with Dynamic Delta Hedging

    The Garman-Kohlhagen option pricing model is a derivative of the Black-Scholes option valuation model.

    The valuation of call options can be defined by the following:

    vcall = erSt

    lnStK +(r r +

    2

    2

    )

    2

    (1)The valuation of a put option is defined as:

    vput = erSt

    lnStK +(r r +

    2

    2

    )

    2

    (2)where = T t, or time to maturity, is the standard normal distribution function, is the volatility

    of the underlying asset, r and r are the domestic and foreign risk free interest rates, St is the spot rate,

    and K is the strike price. In the analysis presented in this segment of research, the purchaser of the call

    (put) option, or the agent that is long in the option, has the right but not the obligation to buy (sell)

    one unit of foreign currency or USD. The issuer, which will be the central bank, has the obligation to

    sell (buy) one USD to the call (put) holder upon maturity if the option is exercised. All options in this

    research are European options, and therefore cannot be exercised until maturity.

    Dynamic delta hedging allows the issuer of the option to take an offsetting position in the spot

    market to cover their risk. The delta of the option is the responsiveness of the option value to changes

    in the value of the underlying asset and is the basis for risk management using dynamic delta hedging.

    The call and put deltas the derivative of the option value with respect to the spot exchange rate, and

    23

  • can be presented as follows:

    vcall = er(x+

    2) (3)

    vput = er

    ((x+

    2) 1

    )(4)

    where x =lnStK +

    (rr+22

    )

    2

    and 0 vcall 1 for call deltas and 1 vput 0 for put deltas.

    For traders in the short option position, the trader would take a long position in the spot market

    for the underlying asset by delta units. For small changes in the underlying, the value of the hedge

    will change by an equal amount in the opposite direction. The trader incrementally adjusts his position

    throughout the time to maturity. In reality, traders hedge their entire portfolios, not single options

    contracts. Therefore, the trader takes into consideration their net position when determining the dynamic

    hedge (Chen, 1998, DeRosa, 2011).

    As discussed by a number of authors mentioned above, dynamic delta hedging of a short option

    position by the central bank may create additional destabilization in currency markets. These approaches

    consider only the scenario under which the central bank issues only calls or only put options, where in

    fact the hedging position would exacerbate the movement in the exchange rate. By positioning itself in

    the alternative butterfly strategy, the central bank can strategically hedge its net position in a way that

    would counteract the persistent appreciation or depreciation of the currency.

    If we consider an example where there has been persistent appreciation over the last 10, 20 or 30

    days, the central bank can hold and issue a bundle of calls and puts. The put options will be exercised,

    while the call options will expire out of the money. By hedging the net position, the central bank

    would be buying USD in the spot market to hedge both the call and put option position. Through

    the portfolio balance channel, it would therefore introduce depreciationary pressure to counteract the

    persistent appreciation.

    In contrast, if there is a persistent depreciation over the last 10, 20 or 30 days, the call options will be

    exercised, while the put options will expire out of the money. By hedging the net portfolio position, the

    central bank would be selling USD in the spot market for both the call and put option position. Through

    the portfolio balance channel, it would therefore introduce appreciationary pressure to counteract the

    persistent depreciation.

    The stabilization effect of holding and issuing a tailored bundle of call and put options is twofold.

    First, as discussed in Machnes (2006) and Sarwar (2003), the amount of calls and puts that are traded

    will effect the movement of the exchange rate and future volatility. Specifically, Machnes finds that

    trading of calls (puts) corresponds to greater depreciation (appreciation) pressure from one day to the

    next. Secondly, the dynamic delta hedging of a tailored net position will contribute to a position in the

    24

  • spot market that counters the persistent movement of the exchange rate.

    6.2 Simulation of Options Strategy

    To understand the potential for central banks to use options as a currency market intervention tool, we

    approach the analysis in three steps. Based on data from Colombia for COPUSD spot rates, we first

    simulate exchange rate movements using first a random process and then an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process

    with GARCH volatility. The second simulation allows for price volatility to remain non-constant and

    ensure positive exchange rate values. Next, we use data from Colombia for the domestic interest rate,

    an estimation for volatility, and US three month t-bill rates for the foreign interest rate to calculate call

    and put prices and the corresponding deltas with the simulated exchange rate values. Lastly, using the

    simulated time series, we calculate the dynamic delta hedging position, or spot market position during

    the period when the option is issued to date of maturity, for the central bank when it issues only calls,

    only puts, or a bundle of both calls and puts, or a alternative butterfly strategy.

    6.2.1 Simulating Exchange Rates

    Since Colombia has been intervening on a daily basis in its currency markets since 2010, to appropriately

    analyze the potential for using an options-based intervention strategy without bias in the data, we

    employ a simulated time series to calculate options prices and the dynamic delta hedging position for

    the central bank. We simulate the exchange rate using first a random process with 90 repetitions and

    then the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process with GARCH volatility for 200 repetitions each with a time period

    of 30 days.

    In the random process simulation of exchange rates, we create two scenarios that represent persistent

    appreciation and persistent depreciation of the COPUSD. We use a uniformly distributed psuedorandom

    generation of exchange rates based on the value of COPUSD on October 20, 2012. This process controls

    the simulation environment to test the option pricing and dynamic delta hedging position when the

    exchange rate is moving strongly in one direction. It provides a clear picture of how the strategic

    hedging behavior of the central bank may introduce stabilizing pressure into currency markets.

    Simulating the exchange rate movement using an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process with GARCH volatility

    is an optimal approach because it allows for non-constant volatility while ensuring positive exchange

    rate values. The Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process is a stochastic process that is stationary, Gaussian and

    Markovian. Therefore, time shifts leave joint probabilities unchanged, the vector of values if multivariate

    normally distributed, and the future is determined only by the present and not past values (Finch,

    2004). The process is also mean-reverting and has been used to model interest rates, exchange rates and

    25

  • commodity prices in financial mathematics.

    The Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process must first satisfy the following linear stochastic difference equation:

    dXt = (Xt )dt+ dWt (5)

    where Wt is a Brownian motion so that t 0. In the asymptotically stationary case, , , are constants

    which yield the following moments:

    E(Xt | X0) = + (c )et (6)

    Cov(Xs, Xt) =2

    2

    (e|st| e(s+t)

    )(7)

    To follow a Brownian motion, = c = 0, = 1 and tends to zero. Here, the variance, is positive

    and constant. To simulate exchange rate movements, it is preferable for the variance or volatility to be

    non-constant. Therefore, to alter the process, is determined with a GARCH(1,1) process.

    Modeling volatility based on GARCH(p,q) model is typical in the financial mathematics literature,

    and is used extensively by professionals and academics alike. Modeling stochastic volatility using the

    GARCH process assumes that the randomness of the variance process varies with the variance of the

    model, allowing volatility to be non-constant. The standard GARCH(p,q) model is defined as:

    2 = 0 + 12t1 + ...+ q

    2tq + 1

    2t1 + ...+ p

    2tp

    2 = 0 +

    qi=1

    i2ti +

    pi=1

    i2ti (8)

    The structure of the volatility model can be defined as

    xt = t() + t (9)

    t = t()zt (10)

    where

    2() = E (xt t())2 | Ft1 (11)

    where Ft1 is the information set available at time t, t() is the dynamics of the conditional mean set

    by an ARMA(p,q) process, t is the residual term, and is the vector of unknown parameters (Jondeau,

    Poon and Rockinger, 2007). Volatility in this model is an exact function of a set of given variables.

    Specifically, for the process presented below the known variables used to calculate volatility are past

    26

  • values of the COPUSD exchange rate.

    After simulating 200 processes, we calculate the average difference in exchange rates over thirty days

    for each process. Based on the average change in exchange rates over thirty days, we segment the

    processes into two groups for additional analysis. The first group experienced on average a negative

    change in exchange rates, or a period of appreciation of the COPUSD. The second group experienced

    on average a positive change in exchange rates, or a period of depreciation of the COPUSD. The groups

    will be referred to below as appreciation-periods and depreciation-periods to distinguish between the

    prior movements of the exchange rate.

    The reason for segmentation into two groups is to account for the appropriate distribution of calls

    and puts issued in the alternative butterfly strategy bundle. During periods of appreciation, a put-

    call ratio below one would ensures the central banks dynamic delta hedging strategy will introduce

    depreciationary pressure into the market through net purchase of USD over the period to maturity. In

    addition, with more calls exercised at maturity, this will also contribute to counteracting the appreciation

    (Machnes, 2006). During depreciationary periods, a put-call ratio greater than one will yield pressure

    from the central bank that may counter the rise in COPUSD and introduce more stability into the

    market. Segmenting the simulated processes into two groups makes this analysis much easier to conduct

    and interpret.

    6.2.2 Calculating Options Bundle and Dynamic Delta Hedging Position

    To calculate the dynamic delta hedging position and option prices, we first start with deriving the

    volatility that will be used for analysis. In this model, we use the standard deviation of the log difference

    of the exchange rate over ten days.2 The next step is to determine the strike prices that will be used to

    calculate the option prices. The set of strike prices in the results presented below are defined as follows,

    where St represents the spot market exchange rate at time t:

    Kt,1 = 0.9975 St

    Kt,3 = 1.0025 St

    Kt,2 =Kt,1+Kt,3

    2

    After the volatility and strike prices are determined, we determine the call and put prices, as well

    as the deltas of each using the Colombia risk free interest rate, the US risk free interest rate, and the

    simulated exchange rate series discussed above. The time to maturity for all contracts is 30 days.

    To determine the dynamic delta hedging position of the central bank, we calculate for each option

    the total shares purchased on a daily basis, the daily interest and cumulative costs, and the end of

    2Volatility measured over a 5, 10 and 20 day period were estimated with little difference in analysis.

    27

  • period cumulative costs, payoffs and profits. The daily total shares purchased are the daily option delta

    multiplied by the option contract size, which is assumed to be USD$ 10,000.

    The cumulative costs at t = 1 are the total shares of USD purchased in the domestic currency or

    SharesUSD,t. For t > 1, cumulative costs are calculated as:

    CostCum,t = CostCum,t1 + CostInt,t1 + SharesUSD,t

    The interest costs are determined as:

    CostInt,t =(er

    (t+1)365

    t365 1

    )CostCum,t

    The end of period cumulative cost for the long position is calculated as:

    CostCum,T = CostCum,t=T + TST

    The end of period cumulative cost for the short position is calculated as:

    CostCum,T = CostCum,t=T TST

    where is the number of shares per contract, or US$ 10,000. The end of period payoff for call options

    is:

    Payoffcalls = max(ST K, 0)

    and for put options:

    Payoffputs = max(K ST , 0)

    For the long position, the net gains are equal to the payoff at the end of the period, and the net losses are

    equal to the cumulative delta hedging costs over the 30 days plus the premium paid for the contract. For

    the short position, the net gains are equal to the premium, and the net losses are equal to the cumulative

    delta hedging costs over the 30 days plus the payoffs. Table (6) presents a summary of calculations.

    Theoretically, the profit or loss for the issuer when dynamically delta hedging should be zero.

    7 Currency Options as a Central Bank Intervention Tool

    The goals of research are to analyze whether the net dynamic delta hedging position for an alternative

    butterfly strategy for a bundle of call and put options is smaller than holding a one-sided position, to

    understand if such a hedging strategy may introduce pressure into the market to counteract the current

    movement of the exchange rate and to determine whether the costs to issue such a portfolio position

    while hedging are lower than the costs of daily currency market interventions. It is assumed that one

    contract is for $ 10,000 USD, and that the central bank issues a total of 10,000 contracts at one time.

    28

  • Table 6: Summary of Dynamic Delta Hedging Cost Calculations

    End of Period (T = 30)Long Call Position Short Call Position Long Put Position Short Put Position

    Cumulative Hedging Costs CostCum,t=T +TST CostCum,t=TTST CostCum,t=T +TST CostCum,t=T TST

    Payoff max(ST K, 0) max(ST K, 0) max(K ST , 0) max(K ST , 0)

    Premium CallPrice CallPrice PutPrice PutPrice

    Net Gains Payoff Premium Payoff Premium

    Net Losses Hedge Costs + Pre-mium

    Hedge Costs + Payoff Hedge Costs + Pre-mium

    Hedge Costs + Payoff

    Cost calculations to the central bank to dynamically delta hedge its net portfolio position over an option contract period of 30 days. STrepresents the spot exchange rate at maturity, or t = T . represents the contract size which is US$ 10,000. CostCum,t=T represents thecumulative dynamic delta hedging cost on the last day of the contract or t = T . T is the delta of the option contract at t = T where T = 30.

    To understand the potential for using currency options as a central bank tool for intervention into

    foreign exchange markets, we start first with the simulated exchange rates for COPUSD over 90 repeti-

    tions under scenarios with persistent appreciation and persistent depreciation. Figure (7) illustrates the

    simulation. Using these simulations introduces a controlled environment under which we can first test

    the alternative butterfly strategy with dynamic delta hedging.

    Figure 7: Series of Simulated Exchange Rates

    Exchange rates are simulated as a random distribution to represent periods of appreciation and depreciation. The start value of simulation is based on 10day average COPUSD exchange rates ending in October 20, 2012.

    Figures (8) and (9) calculate the dynamic delta hedging position and daily cumulative costs of hedging

    during a period of depreciation. The daily shares purchased represent the actual amount of USD the

    central bank is buying or selling in the spot market based on the net portfolio position and is determined

    29

  • by the deltas of each option contract in the portfolio. The cumulative daily hedging costs include the

    interest costs and costs of purchasing shares of the foreign currency in the spot market.

    There are three scenarios depicted in each figure. The first is a call butterfly strategy, where the

    central bank is holding (long) and issuing (short) only call options. The initial spot market position is

    substantial, requiring the central bank to sell approximately $ 60 million USD in the spot market in

    one day. Throughout the period to maturity, the net portfolio position will require the central bank to

    continue selling USD in the spot market to dynamically delta hedge its options portfolio. By doing so,

    it will in turn introduce a counteracting pressure to the persistent depreciation. Under a put butterfly

    position, the central bank initially conducts large purchase of USD in the spot market and subsequently

    sells off its initial spot market position throughout the period to maturity.

    The net dynamic delta hedging position of both strategies allows the central bank to have a smaller

    initial position in the spot market, but it continues to sell USD over the period to maturity. Through

    dynamically delta hedging its net portfolio position, the central bank has a clear strategic approach to

    its spot market position, one that also introduces a stabilizing force into currency markets through the

    portfolio balance channel. Altering the put-call ratio to represent more call options, as seen in Figure

    (9), strengthens the position of the central bank on the initial day of the contract, but does not change

    the spot market position throughout the period to maturity.

    Figures (10) and (11) calculate the dynamic delta hedging position and daily cumulative costs of

    hedging during a period of appreciation. Once again, three scenarios are presented in each figure.

    The first call butterfly strategy, shows initial spot market position that requires the central bank to

    sell approximately $ 60 million USD in one day. This can be potentially destabilizing to the market.

    Throughout the period to maturity, the net portfolio position will require the central bank to buy USD

    in the spot market to dynamically delta hedge its position. The daily purchases of USD may in turn

    introduce a counteracting pressure to the persistent appreciation through the portfolio balance channel

    by driving up the value of USD relative to the domestic currency.

    In the put butterfly position, the central bank initially conducts large purchase of USD in the spot

    market and continues purchasing USD throughout the period to maturity. The net position of both

    strategies allows the central bank to continue to sell USD over the period to maturity. Altering the

    put-call ratio to represent more call options, as seen in Figure (11), forces the central bank to sell USD

    in the spot market on the initial day of the contract, but to continue purchasing USD throughout the

    period to maturity.

    The total cumulative costs represent the end of contract period costs of dynamic delta hedging

    that accumulated from daily hedging. The outstanding position of the central bank from its hedging

    30

  • Figure 8: Depreciation Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Put/Call: 1

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 90 series of 31 days. The exchange rate is steadily depreciating over the period to maturity. The put/callratio is 1. As can be seen, holding a position in both a call and put strategy is the least disruptive to the spot market.

    31

  • Figure 9: Depreciation Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Put/Call: 0.25

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 90 series of 31 days. The exchange rate is steadily depreciating over the period to maturity. The put/callratio is 0.25. As can be seen, holding a position in both a call and put strategy is the least disruptive to the spot market.

    32

  • Figure 10: Appreciation Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Put/Call: 1

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 90 series of 31 days. The exchange rate is steadily appreciating over the period to maturity. The put/callratio is 1. As can be seen, holding a position in both a call and put strategy is the least disruptive to the spot market.

    33

  • Figure 11: Appreciation Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Put/Call: 4

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 90 series of 31 days. The exchange rate is steadily appreciating over the period to maturity. The put/callratio is 4. As can be seen, holding a position in both a call and put strategy is the least disruptive to the spot market.

    34

  • operations and its options contracts will be determined by the hedging costs, payoffs and premiums,

    presented in Table (7). If the central bank holds and issues the equivalence of US$ 100 million in option

    contracts through the alternative butterfly strategy, its costs to dynamically delta hedge the position

    will accumulate to less than US$ 1 million. Compared to the costs in terms of reserve accumulation

    to buy and sell USD on the spot market daily, as Colombia has done, these costs are very small. The

    net costs of the overall portfolio position are even smaller. Therefore, in terms of costs of intervention,

    clearly the options-based strategy is better than daily discretionary interventions.

    Table 7: End of Period Dynamic Delta Costs, Payoffs and Premiums

    Average Across Series (USD)

    Appreciation Depreciation

    Delta Hedging Costs 642,100 851,290Call Payoff 0 2,335,900Put Payoff 1,858,300 0Premium 337,770 323,850

    Net Costs (Calls) -48,215 -19,059Net Costs (Puts) -56,404 -27,068Net Costs (All) -52,310 -23,064

    Total cumulative costs represent the end of contract period cumulative costs of dynamic delta hedging that accumulatedfrom daily hedging. Total dynamic delta hedging costs represent the end of period cumulative costs and payoffs if thecontract was exercised. Each contract size in US$ 10,000, and there were 10,000 contracts issued.

    Next we use the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process with GARCH volatility to simulate the COPUSD ex-

    change rate over thirty days. In addition to all 200 scenarios, we also use the first three series to analyze

    a short sample of the data. The simulated values of exchange rates for each of the three series is also

    captured in Figure (12). As seen in the figure, there are some drastic outliers that will drive extreme

    hedging positions for the central bank. We want to consider all scenarios that the central bank may

    face.

    In Figure (13), the dynamic delta hedging position of the central bank is depicted in terms of the

    total daily shares of USD purchased in the spot market and the daily hedging costs. Here, the dynamic

    delta hedging position is shown for all 200 simulations of the COPUSD. Once again, the initial position

    in the spot market at the start of the contract is smaller when the central bank is holding a net position

    in both calls and puts. The cumulative daily hedging costs are limited as well, with an upper bound of

    $ 40 million USD per day, and lower bound of $ 45 million USD per day, which is comparable to the

    daily discretionary purchases of the Colombian central bank in 2012.

    In Figure (14), the simulated series are segmented into two groups, one where the COPUSD is on

    average appreciating and one where the COPUSD is on average depreciating over the period to maturity.

    The differences in the daily shares purchased if the central bank holds only calls, only puts, or both is

    limited to the initial spot market position at the beginning of the contract. Otherwise, the currency

    35

  • Figure 12: OH-GARCH Simulated Exchange Rates

    Exchange rates are simulated with a GARCH volatility process with an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process to keep price volatility non-constant but exchange ratespositive. The start value of simulation is based on 10 day average COPUSD exchange rates ending in October 20, 2012.

    Figure 13: OH-GARCH Series Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 200 series of 31 days. The series include periods of both appreciation and depreciation. The put/callratio is 1.

    36

  • market pressures exerted through the central banks strategic trading in the spot market is consistent

    across all three strategies.

    Figure 14: OH-GARCH Series Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Shares Purchased

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 200 series of 31 days and then segmented into series include periods of appreciation and depreciation.The put/call ratio is 1.

    To breakdown the analysis of the 200 simulations and present a clear picture of the hedging position of the

    central bank using the simulated exchange rates, Figure (15) depicts the hedging position using the three scenarios

    presented in Figure (12). Because each series has a non-constant volatility, the daily shares of USD purchased in

    the spot market varies depending on whether the COPUSD is appreciating or depreciating. From Figures (8) to

    (11), we know that the dynamic delta hedging position of the central bank will be one that will introduce

    counterbalancing pressure on the exchange rate. Once again, the daily hedging costs are lower when the

    central bank holds positions in both calls and puts.

    The end of period cumulative hedging costs, payoffs and premiums are depicted for the three series in

    each group as well as for all 200 simulations in Table (8). Each contract size is US$ 10,000 with 10,000

    contracts issued. Across all groups, it is evident that the costs to the central bank for issuing bundles of

    calls and puts while dynamically delta hedging the position is much lower than a daily intervention of US$

    20 million. The central bank will be able to hold a strategically determined position in the spot market

    that is driven by the responsiveness of the option price to the underlying asset value that is of comparable

    37

  • Figure 15: OH-GARCH Series Dynamic Delta Hedging Outcomes - Short Sample

    The dynamic delta hedging position is calculated for 3 series of 31 days. The series include periods of both appreciation and depreciation. The put/call ratiois 1.

    38

  • size to the current strategy of daily discretionary interventions. The difference is that the option strategy

    comes at a lower cost in terms of reserve accumulation, and the spot market position of the central bank

    is determined and changed depending on market dynamics.

    Table 8: OH-GARCH End of Period Dynamic Delta Costs, Payoffs and Premiums

    Average Across Series (USD)

    Series (200) Appreciation Depreciation

    Delta Hedging Costs -409,150 -402,900 -415,790Call Payoff 281,990 19,185 557,710Put Payoff 308,800 586,820 13,506Premium 331,720 333,510 329,820

    Net Costs (Calls) 389,311 395,580 382,660Net Costs (Puts) 381,202 387,450 374,570Net Costs (All) 385,257 391,515 378,615

    Short Sample

    Series (1) Series (2) Series (3)

    Delta Hedging Costs -16,590 -227,150 -296,920Call Payoff 1,794,100 0 0Put Payoff 0 342,000 454,000Premium 1,991,200 1,989,000 1,998,800

    Net Costs (Calls) 555,380 50,290 174,340Net