1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually...

13
CAUSALITY BETWEEN GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AND REVENUES: THE ZIMBABWEAN CASE 1980-2004 Talknice Saungweme Great Zimbabwe University,Box 1235 Masvingo, Zimbabwe E-mail: [email protected] ABSTRACT Zimbabwe underwent a series of political, economic and social transformation following the attainment of independence in 1980. Such paradigm shift led to changes in both revenue and expenditure policies and patterns. This study examines the direction of causality between expenditure and revenue of the Zimbabwean government over the period from 1975 to 2004. Both bivariate and multivariate Granger causality models were developed to test the tax-spend hypothesis in the country’s public finance management system. The results of this study support Barro’s (1974) hypothesis that government expenditure causes revenue, and that there exists a stable long-term relationship between total government expenditure and total revenue. KEY WORDS Public expenditure, fiscal deficit, 1.0 Introduction In 1980, the new government of Zimbabwe inherited a dualistic economy in terms of resource distribution and economic opportunity. The new regime endeavoured to meet increasing population demands for social and economic needs by catering for the previously marginalized groups, mostly the black majoritydget. The native black Zimbabweans were deprived access to health, education and other social services by the white minority administration. Such immense social expenditure programmes, coupled with intensive infrastructure development, and massive industrial and agricultural subsidies from the fiscus by the new black government blew up public expenditure. The increase in government expenditure coincided, particularly since 1980, with the notion that government deficit spending stimulates economic growth and creates employment. 1.1 A synopsis of government expenditure and revenue, 1980-2004 The process of national re-building, resource and service re-alignment by the Zimbabwean government soon after 1980 means recurrent expenditures and transfer payments accounted for a large public sector. The increase in public expenditures was further exacerbated by drought in 1982 and civil war which ended in 1987 after the signing of the Unit Accord between ZANU and PF ZAPU. Further, the devaluation of the Zimbabwe dollar after 1991 increased the cost of servicing foreign debt, while higher domestic interest rates also made it more expensive to honour domestic obligations. Interest expenditure absorbed about 19% of total expenditure in 1993/94 1 Central government expenditures in Zimbabwe, as a percentage of GDP, were high in comparison with other countries. While expenditures were in the range of 35% of GDP (at factor cost) when the country attained independence, they rose rapidly thereafter, reaching 52, 5% of GDP in 1986/87. During the last two decades ending 2004, total government expenditure as a ratio of GDP averaged 37%, relative to 20% of tax revenue during the same period . . Political instability in the region, for example in Mozambique, Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) and South Africa and the subsequent intervention by Zimbabwe further constrained the fiscus. 2 1 Country Economic Memorandum.Vol II: Main Report, January 17, 1995, p18 2 The figures were calculated using data from the National Accounts, Central Statistic Office (CSO). Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158 IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected] 28

Transcript of 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually...

Page 1: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

CAUSALITY BETWEEN GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AND REVENUES: THE ZIMBABWEAN CASE 1980-2004

Talknice Saungweme

Great Zimbabwe University,Box 1235 Masvingo, Zimbabwe E-mail: [email protected]

ABSTRACT Zimbabwe underwent a series of political, economic and social transformation following the attainment of independence in 1980. Such paradigm shift led to changes in both revenue and expenditure policies and patterns. This study examines the direction of causality between expenditure and revenue of the Zimbabwean government over the period from 1975 to 2004. Both bivariate and multivariate Granger causality models were developed to test the tax-spend hypothesis in the country’s public finance management system. The results of this study support Barro’s (1974) hypothesis that government expenditure causes revenue, and that there exists a stable long-term relationship between total government expenditure and total revenue.

KEY WORDS Public expenditure, fiscal deficit,

1.0 Introduction In 1980, the new government of Zimbabwe inherited a dualistic economy in terms of resource distribution and economic opportunity. The new regime endeavoured to meet increasing population demands for social and economic needs by catering for the previously marginalized groups, mostly the black majoritydget. The native black Zimbabweans were deprived access to health, education and other social services by the white minority administration. Such immense social expenditure programmes, coupled with intensive infrastructure development, and massive industrial and agricultural subsidies from the fiscus by the new black government blew up public expenditure. The increase in government expenditure coincided, particularly since 1980, with the notion that government deficit spending stimulates economic growth and creates employment.

1.1 A synopsis of government expenditure and revenue, 1980-2004

The process of national re-building, resource and service re-alignment by the Zimbabwean government soon after 1980 means recurrent expenditures and transfer payments accounted for a large public sector. The increase in public expenditures was further exacerbated by drought in 1982 and civil war which ended in 1987 after the signing of the Unit Accord between ZANU and PF ZAPU. Further, the devaluation of the Zimbabwe dollar after 1991 increased the cost of servicing foreign debt, while higher domestic interest rates also made it more expensive to honour domestic obligations. Interest expenditure absorbed about 19% of total expenditure in 1993/941

Central government expenditures in Zimbabwe, as a percentage of GDP, were high in comparison with other countries. While expenditures were in the range of 35% of GDP (at factor cost) when the country attained independence, they rose rapidly thereafter, reaching 52, 5% of GDP in 1986/87. During the last two decades ending 2004, total government expenditure as a ratio of GDP averaged 37%, relative to 20% of tax revenue during the same period .

. Political instability in the region, for example in Mozambique, Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) and South Africa and the subsequent intervention by Zimbabwe further constrained the fiscus.

2

1 Country Economic Memorandum.Vol II: Main Report, January 17, 1995, p18 2 The figures were calculated using data from the National Accounts, Central Statistic Office (CSO).

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

28

Page 2: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

As table 1 below shows, public expenditures in Zimbabwe accounted for a higher proportion of GDP, way above the average for all regions in the world. The only countries which come close to the levels of expenditures in Zimbabwe are Botswana and Namibia. However, both these countries had higher proportions of revenues-to-GDP, implying small fiscal deficits, which led to expenditure sustainability.

Table 1: International Comparisons of Expenditures

Region Percentage of GDP Country Percentage of GDP

East Asia 22.9 Botswana 34.2

South Asia 23.5 South Africa 31.6

SSA 26.3 Namibia 35.4

Latin America 20.4 Malaysia 26.7

Middle east 29.7 Thailand 16.3

All countries 20.8 Mauritius 22.2

Zimbabwe 37 Zimbabwe 37

Source: World Development Report, 1995.3

Like most developing countries, taxes in Zimbabwe constituted the bulk of internal revenue source. The country had tax/GDP ratio of about 30% in the fiscal year 1990/91

4

Since the inception of the economic reform programs in 1991, there was a noted steady decline in revenues. The marginal individual income rate of 45% and the corporate tax rate of 40% were a serious dis-incentive to savings and investment and were encouraging extensive tax evasion and avoidance.

. The main sources of revenue to the government were taxes on incomes and profits (both individual and company taxes); taxes on goods and services (VAT, customs duty, excise duties etc) and revenue from investments and properties (interest and dividends). International economic sanctions and poor industrial performance adversely affected the inflow of international aid (and grants). The insulating effects of the external sanctions were compounded by poor revenue performance by companies (due to losses) and domestic foreign trade regulations introduced after 2000 to manage the balance of payments crisis.

5

In addition to the rate changes, the bulk of wage and salary incomes subject to personal income tax have not kept pace with inflation, and business incomes have been held back by the combined effects of drought, high interest rates and increased international competition in domestic and external markets.

3 Data refer to average expenditures as a percentage of GDP. Regional data show average expenditures covering the period 1985 to 1990; individual country data are for 1993 4 International Financial Statistics Yearbooks (2005) 5 Budget Statement (2003/4)

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

29

Page 3: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

2.0 Theoretical Literature Review

2.1The schools of thought

In theory there are three main hypotheses on the causal relationship between government expenditure and government revenues. The first of these is the fiscal synchronization hypothesis where government expenditure and government revenues are said to be determined simultaneously. The Public Finance literature investigates the fiscal synchronization hypothesis. It takes the view that in a representative democracy, budgetary decisions on taxation and allocation are made simultaneously by the executive and legislative branches of government.6

Endogenous growth models such as those of Barro (1990) and King and Rebelo (1990), on the other hand, predict that distortionary taxation and productive expenditures will affect the long run growth rate.

According to Vamvoukas (1997), this suggests that there is a feedback causal relationship between expenditure and revenue. In this hypothesis the public is said to determine the levels of government spending and taxation by weighing the benefits of government services to their costs. Meltzer and Richard (1991) have advanced arguments in favour of this theory for the US.

The second hypothesis is mainly known as the tax-and-spend hypothesis. This approach stresses that any expenditure budget must be expanded in line with taxation and therefore that expenditure must follow revenue. Thus the amount of tax revenues available will determine the level of government spending. The view here is that if taxes are raised they will propel a growth in government spending. Friedman (1978) searched for intertemporal causal relations between revenues and expenditures. In his “tax-spend hypothesis’, he argued that the rise in taxes lead to an increase in government expenditures and consequently worsens the budgetary balance. In this model, lowering taxes is a necessary condition to bring development of budget deficit under control.

Drawing on the Fiscal Illusion Arguments, Buchannan and Wagner (1977) agree that taxes influences expenditure but that the causal relationship is negative. Thus, in the Buchanan- Wagner framework, government grows because when spending is financed by other than direct taxes, people falsely perceive its price to be less than what it really is. If the government is to finance this deficit entirely through direct taxes, demand for restraining the expenditures would be called for by the society.

Other researchers such as Manage and Marlow (1986) found a unidirectional causality running from federal receipts to expenditures. Blackley also showed that increasing revenue leads to increased expenditures. However, they criticized the Reagan administration’s deficit reduction packages which emphasized the tax increase over deficit reduction pointing out that these packages where designed to reallocate the combination of various revenue sources without concentrating on aggregate spending levels.

The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979), this view is based on their observation that any large-scale exogenous disturbances like wars and other unstable political conditions or natural disasters, will induce an increase in government spending and therefore an increase in tax revenues. The solution suggested here to problems of budget deficits is that government spending should be reduced.

7

6 See Wildawsky, 1988 or Musgrave, 1966 7 The implications of endogenous growth models for fiscal policy have been partially examined by Barro (1990), Ram (1968).

In this regard, Robert Barro’s view of government spending, taxation and debt financing offer an important challenge to the previous views. In contrast to Friedman, he does not see increased taxation as

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

30

Page 4: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

a causal mechanism in the growth of government; rather he sees the situation in reverse. Barro (1979) with his Intertemporal Tax Smoothing model conclude that expenditures cause taxes. Similar conclusions were reached by Peacock and Wiseman (1979).

Zagler and Darnecker (2003) argued that fiscal policy, in essence is a short-run issue, which has macroeconomic consequences. In the short run, fiscal policy can be considered expansionary(contractionary) when public expenditures exceed (fall short of) public revenues and the resulting deficit exhibits can be considered growth enhancing , then a government deficit exhibits an indirect effect on long term economic growth. In a Ricardian world, however, where agents view the deficit as taxes delayed, there should be no difference between tax and deficit finance of government expenditures, as long as the structure remains unchanged in the future. On the other hand, if the economy is non-Ricardian then, public deficits can change the private incentives to accumulation and thus directly influence the rate of the economy.

Finally, in the neoclassical growth model of Solow (1956), together with its many subsequent extensions, the long run growth rate is driven by population growth and the rate of technical progress. Distortionary taxation or productive government expenditures may affect the incentive to invest in human and physical capital, but in the long run this affects only the equilibrium factor ratio, not the growth rate, although in general there will be transitional growth effect.

Other researchers have developed the hypothesis that there is no causal relationship between

government expenditure and revenue, while the Institutional Separation hypothesis by Baghetsani and

McNown (1994) emphasized that expenditure and revenue decisions are made independently.

2.2 Empirical Literature Review (from Developing countries)

Daniel K. Moalise8 used two models (bidirectional and a multivariate model) to assess the link between government spending and revenue. Both models proved that there is a unidirectional causal link running from revenue to spending in the case of Botswana, thus supporting the tax-and-spend hypothesis of Friedman and Buchanan-Wagner. In his paper, “Government revenue and expenditures in Guinea-Bissau: Causality and Cointegration”, Francisco G. Carneiro assessed the intertemporal relationship between government expenditures and revenues for the case of Guinea-Bissau – a low income country under stress that has struggled to achieve fiscal discipline. The results suggested that while government expenditures and revenues exhibit a stable relationship in the long run, there exists unilateral causality from expenditures to revenues in Guinea-Bissau. In Pakistan, the results by Haider Hussain9

8 Department of Economics, Fordham University, 2004 9 http://www.spdc-pak.com

supported Barro’s hypothesis that government expenditure causes revenues.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

31

Page 5: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

3.0 Model specification This study used a modified model by Daniel K. Moalusi (2004)10

111

0 µβα +++= ∑∑=

−=

n

ijti

n

iitit GETRaGE

. It is pertinent to point out that Moalusi had adopted the model which was first used by Darrat for the case of Turkey. The following forms of bivariate models were estimated:

…………………………………………1

2..................................................................1 1

21 ∑ ∑= =

−− +++=n

i

n

ijtiitit GETRaTR µδλ

Where GE is total government expenditure, and TR is total tax revenue; µ1 and µ2 are white noise error terms. The paper tested the hypotheses Ho: ∑ ia = 0 and Ho: ∑ iδ = 0, respectively, for both the equations. If both the hypotheses are subject to rejection, then we can conclude the presence of feedback effect between GE and TR. If only one of the hypotheses is subject to rejection, we can construe the unidirectional causality from that variable to the independent variable of the equation. Furthermore, we also anticipate that ∑ ia <1, ∑ iβ <1, ∑ iλ <1 and ∑ iδ <1.

The multivariate models that were estimated were defined as follows:

3........................................................

4

14

3

13

2

12

1

110 t

n

iit

n

iiti

n

iiti

n

iitit IYTRGEGE εβββββ +++++= ∑∑∑∑

=−

=−

=−

=−

4....................................................2

1

3

1

4

1432

1

110 t

m

k

m

k

m

kktiikti

m

kktit IYGETRTR

ktµααααα +++++= ∑ ∑ ∑∑

= = =−−

=−

Where Y represents GDP and I interest rates in both equations while εt and μt are white noise error terms. For equation 3, the null hypothesis to be tested is that TR does not Granger cause GE. This null would be rejected if the Σβ2i were significantly different from zero as a group. For equation 4, the null hypothesis to be tested is that GE does not Granger cause TR. This null will be rejected if the summation of Σα2i were significantly different from zero as a group.

Equations (5) and (6) were estimated following the existence of a long-term relationship between revenue (TR) and expenditure (GE):

5..............................................................................................11

titi

q

iit

q

iit GETRTR εσαφ +∆+∆+=∆ −

=−

=∑∑

6..............................................................................................111

tt

q

iiit

q

iit GETRGE µϕβφ +∆+∆+=∆ −

=−

=∑∑

4.0 Estimation and Interpretation of Results

Most tests and regressions were done using the E- Views 3.1 statistical package. The Augments Dickey-Fuller (ADF) model was used to test for stationarity of variables under consideration. The results for unit root tests are presented in the following table.

10 Department of Economics, Fordham University, 2004

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

32

Page 6: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

Table 2: Stationarity Results in levels using the ADF Test

Variable K ADF Statistic

(With intercept)

5% Critical Value

F-Statistic DW Conclusion

LGE 3 0.9737 -2.9798 10.3625 2.046 Non-stationary

LTR 3 0.7639 -2.9798 17.5517 2.0014 Non-stationary

LRGDP 0 2.3819 (no intercept) -1.9530 - 1.460 Stationary

LINT 2 0.04480 -2.9750 2.50 1.8997 Non-stationary

*L denotes the natural logarithm

The summary of unit roots results in table 2 above indicates that the natural logarithm of government expenditure (LGE), total revenue (LTR) and interest rates (LINT) are non-stationary in levels. The natural logarithm of Real Gross Domestic Product (LRGDP), on the other hand, is the only variable that is stationary in levels, I (0). However, the rejection of the null hypothesis that β = 0 for the other variables means that the variables are all non-stationary and may have atleast one unit root.

Table 3: Summary of the Bivariate and Multivariate Granger Causality Tests for Expenditures

and Revenue: 1975 to 2004

Null Hypothesis F-Statistic Probability Conclusion

Bivariate Models:

Dependent variable: LGE

TR does not Granger Cause GE 1478.24 0.00000 Do not reject

LTR does not Granger Cause LGE 7.06722 0.00405 Do not reject

Dependent variable: LTR

GE does not Granger Cause TR 2.00006 0.15819 Reject

LGE does not Granger Cause LTR 2.54120 0.10066 Reject

Variable

∆LTR does not Granger Cause ∆LGE 7.48931 0.00331 Do not reject

∆LGE does not Granger Cause ∆LTR 0.83568 0.44688 Reject

Multivariate Models:

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

33

Page 7: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

Dependent variable: LGE

LTR does not Granger Cause LGE 7.067 22 0.00405 Do not reject

LINTR does not Granger Cause LGE 2.57502 0.49792 Reject

LGDP does not Granger Cause LGE 28.0700 0.22707 Reject

Dependent variable: LTR

LGE does not granger cause LTR 2.54120 0.10066 Reject

LINTR does not granger cause LTR 0.00667 0.99336 Reject

RGDP does not granger cause LTR 9.23381 0.41407 Reject

The results from table 3 show that for the bivariate model, we fail to reject the null hypothesis that total government revenue (TR) does not Granger cause government expenditure (GE).11

Variable

However, we reject the null hypothesis that government expenditure does not Granger cause total government revenue. This means that causality runs from spending to revenue and thus supports a spend-and-tax hypothesis. Also from table 3, we do not reject the null hypothesis that changes in the natural logarithm of total revenue do not granger cause changes in the natural logarithm of government spending. Instead, we conclude that changes in government expenditures are causing changes in total revenue. Results from the bivariate model could have some bias due to omission of variables. Thus from these empirical results we conclude that the relationship between government spending and revenue is unidirectional, running from government spending to revenue. These findings support the spend-and-tax hypothesis in Zimbabwe. This implies that growth in government expenditure in Zimbabwe has influenced greatly the way the government generates its revenue, following the prediction by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979). Table 4: Stationarity Results in first difference using the ADF test

K ADF Statistic

With intercept

5% Critical

Value

F-Statistic DW Conclusion

∆LGE 3 3.923623 -2.9850 8.311956 2.114748 Stationary I(1)

∆LTR 3 2.991128 -2.9850 2.140067 1.668467 Stationary I(1)

11 The results from Table 3 are based on a specification of two lags. The lag length was determined using the Akaike Information Criterion.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

34

Page 8: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

The results of table 4 above makes it necessary to test whether the variables of interest are cointegrated, and thus establish the existence of a long-run relationship. The results of the Johansen cointegration test are given in table 5 below: Table 5: Johansen test for the number of cointegration vectors

Eigen value Likelihood Ratio 5% Critical Value

1% Critical Value

Hypothesized No. of CE(s)

0.507336 27.56312 25.32 30.45 None *

0.268698 8.449063 12.25 16.26 At most 1

Basing on the likelihood ratio (LR) test statistic we reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration among the variables and, hence, conclude that there is one cointegration vector at 5% level of significance. This justifies the use of an error correction term to capture the long run equilibrium relationship, and the differenced term captures the short run dynamics, between government spending and revenues.

In this respect the error correction models estimated in this study were generated as below, with the results of the resultant ECM models in table 6 and 7:

8.047997-LGE*0.311887+LTR*1=ECM25.80424-LTR*3.206294+LGE*1=ECM

2

1

Table 6: Error correction model regression results (Dependent Variable: DLGE) Variable Coefficient Standard error t-value t-prob

Constant -0.003941 0.056552 -0.069693 0.9450

DLTR 0.870149 0.130275 6.679326 0.0000

ECM1(-1) 0.024188 0.006065 3.988128 0.0062

R2 = 0.831352 Adjusted R2 = 0.818379 RSS = 0.808002 F-statistic = 64.08371

DW = 2.364617 Log likelihood = 10.76784 Prob (F-statistic) = 0.000000

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

35

Page 9: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

Table 7: Error correction model regression results (Dependent Variable: DLTR)

Variable

Coefficient Standard error t-value t-prob

Constant -0.026858 0.051394 -0.522592 0.6057

DLGE 0.726080 0.108706 6.679326 0.0000

ECM2(-1) 0.032567 0.016749 1.944355 0.0627

R2 = 0.850061 Adjusted R2 = 0.838527 RSS = 0.674222 F-statistic = 73.70203

DW = 2.129421 Log likelihood = 13.39242 Prob (F-statistic) = 0.000000

The results in tables 6 and 7 above are in conformity with the Granger causality results obtained earlier, that is, there is a positive relationship between government expenditure and revenues. The variables have expected signs and are statistically significant at 5% level of significance. The constant term, however, in both cases is statistically insignificant at 5% level of significance. The negative sign can be interpreted to mean that when all other variables remain unchanged total government spending (or revenue) is expected to fall.

The coefficient of the ecm1t-1 indicates that 2% of previous disequilibria are corrected for in the current period while that for ecm2t-1 indicates that about 3% of previous disequilibria are corrected for in the current period. It, therefore, implies that any deviations/error from the long run equilibrium path can be corrected accordingly at a very slower rate. The coefficients carry the expected positive sign and are statistically significant at 5%. The hypothesis that there is a cointegration relationship is therefore reinforced. Further, the models have a good fit as explained by the R2 and the F- statistics. An R2 of 83% and 85%, respectively, provides a convincing proof that the models fit the data set fairly well. That is to say 83% of the variations in GE are explained by TR, the remainder (17%) is captured by the error term.

5.0 Conclusions and Policy Implications The results of this research support Barro’s (1974) hypothesis that government expenditure causes revenue, and that there exists a stable long-term relationship between government expenditure and revenue. That is, the government seems to spend first and then raise revenue and/or request/receive grants to finance its expenditure, rather than adopting the approach of raising funds first to finance spending later. This result that total revenue does not cause government expenditure can best and only be explained by the political economy of Zimbabwe where the main expenditures are the outlays chiefly determined politically by bureaucratic influence (defence, debt servicing, general administration). Although debt servicing is a liability transfer from previous periods, it is included here too because the debts taken have not been reflected in increased development and other investment expenditure over the years. Henceforth, the hypothesis that government spending granger causes total revenue suggests that spending decisions have a life of their own, and eventually lead to tax changes. Here, the government decides on the “appropriate” spending level, and taxes adjust to cover the cost.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

36

Page 10: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

The policy recommendation for Zimbabwe can be summarized as follows:

In order to achieve fiscal sustainability the government expenditure should be re-examined with the view to assess (i) their contribution to an efficient allocation of resources within the economy and (ii) their potential to finance growth enhancing spending categories (such as, for example, those considered in the framework of endogenous growth models – i.e., infrastructure, research and development, education, and health). A reduction in the size of large consumption outlays and their shifting towards development and other investment expenditures will facilitate this economy to move towards Pareto optimal solutions. In addition, the presence of and dependence on the political factors in determining the preferences for expenditures can interrupt any economic step taken to correct the revenue-expenditure gap.

In a second moment, the government should seek ways to re-order the intertemporal relationship between expenditure and revenue in a way consistent with the country’s revenue mobilization potential. This could pave the way for a sound medium term budgeting framework and help the government to control its expenditures rather than increasing its fiscal revenues, thus re-establishing fiscal discipline without jeopardizing the accumulation of factors affecting the country’s long-term growth potential. In addition, in determining the new outlays, economic efficiency should be preferred over political determination.

Moreover, as is the focal point of this study, results suggest that besides the tax & tariff reform programme of the government which emerged and was enhanced during the 1990s, we strongly need an expenditure reform curriculum in which comprehensive cost benefit analyses should be conducted for government expenditures together with the analyses of adopting optimal approach for gradual shifting and reformation. This whole scenario should be scrutinized in a general equilibrium framework so that the effect and distributional consequences of any expenditure could be spread over the entire economy.

REFERENCES

• Anderson, William, Myles S. Wallace, and John T. Warner, “Government Spending and Taxation: What Causes What?” Southern Economic Journal 56, 24-31.139-143.

• Ahiakpor, J. C. W., and S. Amirkhalkhali. (1989). “On the difficulty of eliminating deficits with higher taxes: Some Canadian evidence.” Southern Economic Journal 56: 24-31.

• Baghestani, H., and R. McNown. (1994). “Do revenues or expenditures respond to budgetary disequilibria?” Southern Economic Journal 60:311-22.

• Bhat, K. Sham, V. Nirmala and B. Kamaiah. (1993). "Causality between Tax Revenue and Expenditure of Indian States", The Indian Economic Journal, Vol. 40, No. 4, pp.109-17.

• Blackley, R. Paul (1986). "Causality between Revenues and Expenditures and the Size of • Federal Budget", Public Finance Quarterly, Vol.14, No. 2, pp. 139-56. • Banarjee, A., Dolado, J. J., Galbraith, J. W. and Hendry, D. F. (1993).Cointegration, Error

Correction and the Econometric Analysis of Non-Stationary Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

• Barro, R. J. (1979). “On the determination of the public debt”. Journal of Political Economy 81:940-71.

• Buchanan, J. M., and R. W. Wagner. (1977). “Democracy in deficit”: The political legacy of Lord Keynes. New York: Academic Press.

• Cheng, Benjamin S. 1999 "Causality between Taxes and Expenditures: Evidence from • Latic American Countries", Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 184-192.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

37

Page 11: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

• Central Statistical Office (2003), National Accounts 1985-2003. • Central Statistical Office, Rhodesian National Accounts. • Darrat, A. (1998). “Tax and spend, or spend and tax? An inquiry into the Turkish budgetary

process.” Southern Economic Journal 64 (4): 940-56. • Daniel K. Moalusi (2004). “Causal Link between Government Spending and Revenue: A Case

Study of Botswana”. Department of Economics Fordham University. • Dhanasekaran, K. (2001), “Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure and Causality: the • Experience of India”, India Economic Review, 2, 359-379. • Dickey, David A., William R. Bell, and Robert B. Miller, “Unit roots in Time Series Models:

Tests and Implications.” The American Statistician, February 1986, 12-26. • Dickey, D. A., Jansen, D. W. and Thornton, D. C. (1991). “A Primer on Cointegration with an

Application to Money and Income”, Review Federal Reserve Bank of ST. Louis, 73 (2), 58-78. • Enders, W., and P.L. Siklos, P.L. (2001). “Cointegration and threshold adjustment.” Journal of

Business and Economic Statistics 19: 166-176. • Engle R. & Granger C. (1987). “Co-Integration and Error Correction: Representation,

Estimation, and Testing”, Econometrica, 55(2): 251-276. • Engle, Robert F. and C. W. J. Granger, “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation,

Estimation, and Testing.” Econometrica, March 1987, 251-76. • GOZ, Budget Statements (2000, 2001, 2002, 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006, 2007), Government

printers, Harare. • Gujarati D. N. (1995). “Basic Econometrics”, third edition, McGraw Hill, New York. • Francisco G. Carneiro ”Government Revenues and Expenditures in Guinea-Bissau: • Causality and Cointegration” . Africa Region Working Paper Series No. 65 January 2004. • Friedman M. (1978), “The Limitations of Tax Limitations”, Policy Review, summer: 7-14. • Friedman M. (1982). “Supply side policies: where do we go from here in supply-side economics

in the 80’s; conference proceedings.” Westport, CT. • Gebhard Kirchgässner, “Causality between Expenditures and Revenues: • Empirical Evidence from Switzerland. • Haider Hussain, “On the Causal Relationship between Government Expenditure and Tax

Revenue in Pakistan” http://www.spdc-pak.com • Hall, S. G. and Henry, S. S. B. (1989). “Macroeconomic Modeling”. Amsterdam (The

Netherlands): Elsevier Science Publishers. • Hondroyiannis, G., and E. Papapetrou. (1996). “An examination of the causal relationship

between government spending and revenue: A cointegration analysis.z’ Public Choice 89 (3-4): 363-74.

• Hoover, K. D., and S. M. Sheffrin. (1992). “Causation, spending, and taxes: Sand in the sandbox or tax collector for the welfare state?” American Economic Review 82 (1): 225-48.

• International Financial Statistics Yearbooks (various years). • International Monetary Fund Yearbooks IMF, Washington (various years). • Islam, M. Q. (2001). “Structural break, unit root, and the causality between government

expenditures and revenues.” Applied Economics Letters 8:565-67. • Johansen, S., and K. Juselius. (1990). “Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on

cointegration: With applications to the demand for money.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics (May): 169-210.

• Jones J.D. and Joulfaian D. (1991). “Federal Government Expenditure and MacKinnon, J. G. 1991. “Critical Values for Co-integration Tests in R. F. Engle and C. W.”

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

38

Page 12: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

• Ludvigson, S. (1996), “The Macroeconomic Effects of Government Debt in a Stochastic Growth Model”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 25-45.

• Macroeconomic Framework, (1997), Government of Zimbabwe • Maddala, G. S, and I. M. Kim. (1998). “Unit roots, cointegration, and structural change.

Cambridge”, University Press, Cambridge. • Manage, Neela and Michael L. Marlow, ‘The Causal Relation between Federal Expenditures and

Receipts.” Southern Economic Journal, January 1986, 617-29. • Manning, L. M. and Adriacanos, D. (1993). "Dollar Movements and Inflation: a Cointegration

Analysis", Applied Economics, 25, 1483-1488. • Meltzer A. H and Richard S. (1991). “A Rational Size of Government”. Journal of Political

Economy 89 (5), 914-27. • Miller, S. M., and F. S. Russek. (1989). “Co-integration and error-correction models: The

temporal causality between government taxes and spending.” Southern Economic Journal 57:221-29.

• Musgrave, R. 1966. “Principles of budget determination. In Public finance”: Selected readings, edited by H. Cameron and W. Henderson. New York: Random House.

• Owoye, O. (1995) "The Causal Relationship between Taxes and Expenditures in the G7 • Countries: Co-integration and Error Correction Models", Applied Economic Letters, 2, pp. 19-

22. • Peacock, A. T., and J. Wiseman. (1979). “Approaches to the analysis of government expenditure

growth.” Public Finance Quarterly 7:3-23. • “Revenue in the early years of the Republic: Evidence from 1792-1860.” Journal of

Macroeconomics, 13(1), 133-155. • Ram, R. (1988). “Additional evidence on causality between government revenue and

government Expenditure”. Southern Economic Journal 54:763-69. • Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe. Quarterly Economic and Statistical Reviews (various issues).

Singh, B and B. S Sahni (1986). “Patterns and directions of causality between government expenditure and national income in the United States”,. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 2(2): 630- 44.

• Solow (1956). “A Contribution to the theory of Economic Growth”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 65-94.

• The Herald, “Budget Statement, 2007”, 1 December 2006, Harare, Government of Zimbabwe. • Thomas, R. L. (1993). Introductory Econometrics: Theory and Applications. Second edition.

Longman. • Vamvoukas G. (1997). “Budget expenditures and Revenues: An Application of the Error

Correction Modeling”. Public Finance 1997, 52(1), • Von Furstenberg, George, R. Jeffery Green, and Jin-Ho Jeong, “Tax and Spend, or Spend and

Tax?” The Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1986, 179-88. • Wagner, Richard E, “Revenue structure , Fiscal illusion, and budgetary Choice”, public Choice,

Spring, 1976, 30-61. • Wildavsky, A. (1988). “The new politics of the budgetary process”. Glenview, IL: Scott,

Foresman. • World Bank. (1996). “World Development Report 1996: From Plan to Market”. New York:

Oxford University Press. • World Bank (2003). World Development Indicators, 2001. Washington, DC. • Zagler, M. and G. Dürnecker (2003), “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth”, Journal of • Economic Surveys, 17, 397-422.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

39

Page 13: 1.0 Introduction · 2013. 12. 18. · The third hypothesis is that government spending actually leads revenue. Advanced by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) and others like Barro (1979),

• Zimbabwe Framework for Economic Reform Programme ESAP (1991-1995), Government of Zimbabwe.

• Zimbabwe Programme for Economic and Social Transformation (ZIMPREST:1995- 2000), Government of Zimbabwe.

Talknice Saungweme., Int. J. Eco. Res., 2013, v4i6, 28 - 40 ISSN: 2229-6158

IJER | NOV - DEC 2013 Available [email protected]

40