1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009 Worth Publishers...

37
1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009 Worth Publishers Making Decisions

Transcript of 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009 Worth Publishers...

Page 1: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

1 of 37

WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTERchapter:

9

>>

Krugman/Wells

©2009 Worth Publishers

Making Decisions

Page 2: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

2 of 37

WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER

How economists model decision making by individuals and firms

The importance of implicit as well as explicit costs in decision making

The difference between accounting profit and economic profit, and why economic profit is the correct basis for decisions

The difference between “either–or” and “how much” decisions

The principle of marginal analysis What sunk costs are and why they should be ignored How to make decisions in cases where time is a factor

Page 3: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

3 of 37

Opportunity Cost and Decisions

An explicit cost is a cost that involves actually laying out money.

An implicit cost does not require an outlay of money; it is measured by the value, in dollar terms, of the benefits that are forgone.

Page 4: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

4 of 37

Opportunity Cost of an Additional Year of School

Page 5: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

5 of 37

FOR INQUIRING MINDS

Famous College Dropouts What do Bill Gates, Tiger Woods, and Madonna have

in common? None of them have a college degree. Each of them made a rational decision that the

implicit cost of getting a degree would have been too high. By their late teens, each had a very promising career that would have to be put on hold to get a college degree.

It’s a simple matter of economics: the opportunity cost of their time at that stage in their lives is just too high to postpone their careers for a college degree.

Page 6: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

6 of 37

Accounting Profit Versus Economic Profit

The accounting profit of a business is the business’s revenue minus the explicit costs and depreciation.

The economic profit of a business is the business’s revenue minus the opportunity cost of its resources. It is often less than the accounting profit.

Page 7: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

7 of 37

Its all about the numbers…

Page 8: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

8 of 37

Capital

The capital of a business is the value of its assets—equipment, buildings, tools, inventory, and financial assets.

The implicit cost of capital is the opportunity cost of the capital used by a business—the income the owner could have realized from that capital if it had been used in its next best alternative way.

Page 9: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

9 of 37

Profits at Babette’s Cajun Cafe

Page 10: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

10 of 37

►ECONOMICS IN ACTION

Farming in the Shadow of Suburbia In 1880, more than half of New England’s land was farmed; by

2006, the amount was down to 10%. The remaining farms of New England are mainly located close to

large metropolitan areas. Farmers get high prices for their produce from city dwellers who are willing to pay a premium for locally-grown, extremely fresh fruits and vegetables.

Maintaining the land instead of selling it to property developers constitutes a large implicit cost of capital.

About two-thirds of New England’s farms remaining in business earn very little money but nevertheless, they are maintained out of a personal commitment and satisfaction derived from farm life.

Page 11: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

11 of 37

“How Much” Versus “Either–Or” Decisions

Page 12: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

12 of 37

Marginal Cost

The marginal cost of producing a good or service is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of that good or service.

Page 13: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

13 of 37

Constant Marginal Cost

For every additional chicken wing per serving, Babette’s marginal cost is $0.80. Babette’s portion size decision has what economists call constant marginal cost: each chicken wing costs the same amount to produce as the previous one.

Production of a good or service has constant marginal cost when each additional unit costs the same to produce as the previous one.

Page 14: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

14 of 37

76543210

$4.00

3.00

2.00

1.00

Marginal cost (per wing)

Quantity of chicken wings

Marginal cost curve, MC

Marginal Cost

Page 15: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

15 of 37

PITFALLS

Total cost versus marginal cost It can be easy to wrongly conclude that marginal

cost and total cost must always move in the same direction.

What is true is that total cost increases whenever marginal cost is positive, regardless of whether it is increasing or decreasing.

Page 16: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

16 of 37

Marginal Benefit

The marginal benefit of producing a good or service is the additional benefit earned from producing one more unit of that good or service.

Page 17: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

17 of 37

Marginal Cost - Marginal Benefit

The marginal cost curve shows how the cost of producing one more unit depends on the quantity that has already been produced.

Production of a good or service has increasing marginal cost when each additional unit costs more to produce than the previous one.

The marginal benefit of a good or service is the additional benefit derived from producing one more unit of that good or service.

The marginal benefit curve shows how the benefit from producing one more unit depends on the quantity that has already been produced.

Page 18: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

18 of 37

Decreasing Marginal Benefit

Each additional lawn mowed produces less benefit than the previous lawn with decreasing marginal benefit, each additional unit produces less benefit than the unit before.

There is decreasing marginal benefit from an activity when each additional unit of the activity produces less benefit than the previous unit.

Page 19: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

19 of 37

76543210

Marginal benefit curve, MB

Marginal cost (per wing)

Quantity of chicken wings

Marginal Benefit

Page 20: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

20 of 37

Felix’s Net Gain from Mowing Lawns

Page 21: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

21 of 37

Marginal Analysis

The optimal quantity is the quantity that generates the maximum possible total net gain.

The principle of marginal analysis says that the optimal quantity is the quantity at which marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost.

Page 22: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

22 of 37

Babette’s Net Gain from Increasing Portion Size

Page 23: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

23 of 37

Babette’s Optimal Portion Size

76543210

$4.00

3.00

2.00

1.00

Marginal benefit (marginal cost per wing)

Quantity of chicken wings

Optimal point

MC

MB

Optimal quantity

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Total net gain

(profit per serving)

Net gain(per wing)

Quantity of chicken wings

$0

3.50

5.20

5.90

6.30

6.40

6.30

6.10

$3.50

1.70

0.70

0.40

0.10

–0.10

–0.20

Page 24: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

24 of 37

PITFALLS

Muddled at the margin The idea of setting marginal benefit equal to

marginal cost sometimes confuses people.

The point is to maximize the total net gain from an activity. If the marginal benefit from the activity is greater than the marginal cost, doing a bit less will increase the total net gain.

So only when the marginal benefit and marginal cost are equal is the difference between total benefit and total cost at a maximum.

Page 25: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

25 of 37

►ECONOMICS IN ACTION

The Cost of a Life What’s the marginal benefit to society of saving a human

life? In the real world, resources are scarce, so we must decide how much to spend on saving lives since we cannot spend infinite amounts.

The UK government once estimated that improving rail safety would cost an additional $4.5 million per life saved. But if that amount was worth spending, then the implication was that the British government was spending far too little on traffic safety.

That’s because the estimated marginal cost per life saved through highway improvements was only $1.5 million, making it a much better deal than saving lives through greater rail safety.

Page 26: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

26 of 37

Sunk Cost

A sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred and is non-recoverable. A sunk cost should be ignored in decisions about future actions.

Sunk costs should be ignored in making decisions about future actions. Because they have already been incurred and are non-recoverable, they have no effect on future costs and benefits.

“There’s no use crying over spilled milk.”

Page 27: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

27 of 37

►ECONOMICS IN ACTION

A Billion Here, a Billion There… If there's any industry that exemplifies the principle that sunk costs

don’t matter, it has to be the biotech industry. These firms use cutting-edge bioengineering techniques to combat disease.

It takes about seven to eight years, on average, to develop and bring a new drug to the market. There is also a huge failure rate along the way, as only one in five drugs tested on humans ever gets to the market.

Xoma company has suffered setbacks on several drugs addressing diseases as varied as acne and complications from organ transplants. Since 1981, it has never earned a profit on one of its own drugs and has burned through more than $700 million dollars.

Xoma keeps going because it possesses a very promising technology and because shrewd investors understand the principle of sunk costs.

Page 28: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

28 of 37

The Concept of Present Value

When someone borrows money for a year, the interest rate is the price, calculated as a percentage of the amount borrowed, charged by the lender.

The interest rate can be used to compare the value of a dollar realized today with the value of a dollar realized later, because it correctly measures the cost of delaying a dollar of benefit (and the benefit of delaying a dollar of cost).

The present value of $1 realized one year from now is equal to $1/(1 + r): the amount of money you must lend out today in order to have $1 in one year. It is the value to you today of $1 realized one year from now.

Page 29: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

29 of 37

Present Value

Let’s call $V the amount of money you need to lend today, at an interest rate of r in order to have $1 in two years.

So if you lend $V today, you will receive $V(1 + r) in one year.

And if you re-lend that sum for yet another year, you will receive $V × (1 + r) × (1 + r) = $V × (1 + r)2 at the end of the second year.

At the end of two years, $V will be worth $V × (1 + r)2; If r = 0.10, then this becomes $V × (1.10)2 = $V × (1.21).

Page 30: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

30 of 37

Present Value

What is $1 realized two years in the future worth today?

In order for the amount lent today, $V, to be worth $1 two years from now, it must satisfy this formula:

$V × (1 + r)2 = $1

If r = 0.10, $V = $1/(1 + r)2 = $1/1.21 = $0.83

The present value formula is equal to $1/(1 + r) N

Page 31: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

31 of 37

Net Present Value

The net present value of a project is the present value of current and future benefits minus the present value of current and future costs.

Page 32: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

32 of 37

►ECONOMICS IN ACTION

How Big Is That Jackpot, Anyway? On March 6, 2007, Mega Millions set the record for the

largest jackpot ever in North America, for a payout of $390 million. The $390 million was available only if you chose to take your winnings in the form of an “annuity” consisting of an annual payment for the next 26 years. If you wanted the cash up front, the jackpot was only $233 million and change.

If the winner took the annuity, the lottery would have invested the money in U.S. government bonds and using the prevailing interest rates at the time, the present value of a $390 million spread over 26 years was just about $233 million.

So why didn’t they just call it a $233 million jackpot? Well, $390 million sounds more impressive! But it was really the same thing.

Page 33: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

33 of 37

SUMMARY

1. All economic decisions involve the allocation of scarce resources. Some decisions are “either–or” decisions, other decisions are “how much” decisions.

2. The cost of using a resource for a particular activity is the opportunity cost of that resource. Some opportunity costs are explicit costs; they involve a direct payment of cash. Other opportunity costs, however, are implicit costs; they involve no outlay of money but represent the inflows of cash that are forgone. Companies use capital and their owners’ time. So companies should base decisions on economic profit, which takes into account implicit costs such as the opportunity cost of the owners’ time and the implicit cost of capital.

Page 34: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

34 of 37

SUMMARY

3. A “how much” decision is made using marginal analysis, which involves comparing the benefit to the cost of doing an additional unit of an activity. The marginal cost of producing a good or service is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of that good or service. The marginal benefit of producing a good or service is the additional benefit earned by producing one more unit.

4. In the case of constant marginal cost, each additional unit costs the same amount to produce as the unit before; this is represented by a horizontal marginal cost curve. With increasing marginal cost, each unit costs more to produce than the unit before. In the case of decreasing marginal benefit, each additional unit produces a smaller benefit than the unit before.

Page 35: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

35 of 37

SUMMARY

5. According to the principle of marginal analysis, the optimal quantity—the quantity that generates the

maximum possible total net gain—is the quantity at which marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost.

6. A cost that has already been incurred and that is nonrecoverable is a sunk cost. Sunk costs should be ignored in decisions about future actions—they have no effect on future benefits and costs.

Page 36: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

36 of 37

SUMMARY

7. To evaluate a project in which costs or benefits are realized in the future, you must first transform them into their present values using the interest rate, r. The present value of $1 realized one year from now is $1/(1 + r), the amount of money you must lend out today to have $1 one year from now. Once this transformation is done, you should choose the project with the highest net present value.

Page 37: 1 of 37 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.

37 of 37

The End of Chapter 9

Coming attraction:Chapter 10:

The Rational Customer