1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens...

30

Transcript of 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens...

Page 1: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and
Page 2: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and
Page 3: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

2

1. Introduction

The extraordinary growth of the Internet in the last few years, from fewer than 5 million

users in 1993 to 62 million in 1997 (Department of Commerce, 1998), has led some to speak of

the birth of a “world without borders,” where free communication, competitive markets, and

extensive comparison shopping are a matter of course (see The Economist, 1997a; Hof, 1998;

Pouliot, 1998). This apparent lack of geography in cyberspace, however, has raised some difficult

issues regarding government policy toward the “new” economy, particularly regarding tax policy.

The sales of products and services over the Internet have grown even faster than the

overall use of the Internet; data from Jupiter Communications suggests online sales have been

rising about 300% per year (Krantz, 1998) and are expected to continue growing at tremendous

rates. Forrester Research predicts that, by the year 2000, total online sales will exceed $200

billion. At the extreme, Nicholas Negroponte, founder of the MIT media laboratory has predicted

that such commerce may exceed $1 trillion by 2000. Although online transactions currently make

up only a very small fraction of total retail sales, predictions such as these have caused state policy

makers to become highly concerned with the fact that most online transactions pay no sales tax.1

If these growth predictions are anywhere close to accurate, tax policy toward Internet commerce

promises to have serious consequences for future state tax policy since the sales tax makes up the

largest single component of state revenues.

Economists have long argued that consumer sensitivity to tax rates will be larger for

people living along geographic borders or in an open economy, more generally, where the costs of

arbitraging tax rates across locations are low, and that this can have important implications for the

1 In general, Internet sales are treated the same as mail-order sales. No sales tax is collected from companies thathave no presence (known as nexus) in the state. Although sales tax is not collected, technically states apply a usetax which requires consumers to pay the equivalent of the state sales tax on their mail-order and Internetpurchases. The supreme court has ruled, however, that under existing law, an out-of-state vendor without nexus ina state cannot be required to collect the use tax for that state even if the customer lives there (National Bellas Hess,386 U.S. 753, 1967; Quill, 504 U.S. 298, 1992). This has meant that use taxes have rather extreme complianceproblems and are little known by most consumers (see Trandel, 1992). Enforcement of the use tax has only beeneffective for goods like automobiles that must be registered in the state of use.

Page 4: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

3

setting of tax policy.2 Empirical work on the responsiveness in border communities to taxes and

other such policies has tended to bear out these predictions by finding large elasticities in such

locations.3

Against this backdrop, then, perhaps the key issue that the Internet poses for tax policy is

not so much its potential to create a world without borders but rather to create a world of only

borders−a world in which everyone is as responsive to local taxation as people who live on

geographic borders. With that perspective, it is clear why state lawmakers and some in the

popular press have decried “the disappearing taxpayer” and have called for reform (see The

Economist, 1997a; 1997b). State Tax Notes has declared the issue of taxes and electronic

commerce “the hottest topic in multistate taxation” (Sheppard, 1998) and the National Governors

Association itself has called for a uniform tax on all Internet and mail-order sales. They argue that

this would protect their revenue base and protect “Main Street” businesses.4

On the other hand, there is also serious opposition to taxes on the Internet. The

opponents have argued that introducing taxes now might seriously impede the Internet’s growth

at a critical stage of early development (see, for example, Stephenson and Zeisser, 1998). The

recent passage of the Internet Tax Freedom Act is certainly one manifestation of this view

although in its final form it does not prohibit uniform sales taxes.5 Other opponents have argued

that compliance with the thousands of local tax rates, or even monitoring those rates, would be

unduly burdensome on out-of-state companies, especially for sellers of information goods that are

delivered online and often do not even have a customer’s mailing address.

2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanburand Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and Neilsen (1997).3 Empirical work on sales taxes and excise taxes in border areas can be found in Mikesell (1970), Fox (1986),Walsh and Jones (1988), or Rappaport (1994). Holmes (1998) gives similar evidence on the effects of right-to-worklaws in border regions.4 To actually impose such a tax, however, would currently violate the Interstate Commerce Clause of theconstitution and would require a specific federal law permitting states to require out-of-state companies withoutnexus in a state, nevertheless, to collect use taxes for that state (see footnote 1). Fox and Murray (1997) give agood discussion of the issues.5 The ITFA establishes a moratorium on new taxes but applying a sales tax to Internet sales would not beconsidered a new tax so long as it applies to retail and out-of-state mail-order sales at the same time.

Page 5: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

4

Despite ongoing policy interest and despite the potential relevance to the broader field of

open economy tax policy, there has been little empirical work on the impact of tax policy on

Internet commerce. Most economic work on the Internet has focused on more basic issues such

as pricing and access.6 Existing discussions of taxes and Internet commerce have either centered

on legal and practical issues (see, for example, Horner and Owens, 1996; Bourgeois and

Blanchette, 1997) or else on the conceptual basis for Internet tax policy (Fox and Murray, 1997;

McLure, 1997). Nor can we take lessons from previous research on mail-order sales which face

exactly the same issues. There is virtually no empirical work on that subject, either. Indeed past

work that has advocated administering taxes on out-of-state mail-order sales, has explicitly

assumed that there are no behavioral impacts (ACIR, 1986).

In this paper, I attempt to provide a rigorous empirical foundation for discussions of

Internet commerce by estimating how such commerce responds to local tax rates. To do so, I

turn to a major recent survey of the online purchase patterns of approximately 25,000 people with

access to the Internet in more than 350 cities and metropolitan areas and match these data to the

tax rates in those communities. The results show that Internet sales are highly sensitive to local

taxation. This is true nationally, within regions, within states, and even within metropolitan areas.

Controlling for individual characteristics, people who live in high sales tax locations are

significantly more likely to buy over the Internet and I can show that this is unlikely to result from

unobserved heterogeneity across locations. The paper also uses data on computers to compare

the apparent tax responsiveness of both Internet and mail-order sales and finds similar effects for

both of the “non-taxed” channels.

The estimated tax elasticities of Internet commerce with respect to local taxation are quite

large and thus resemble the elasticities found in previous sales tax studies of geographical border

areas. In policy terms, the results suggest that to apply existing sales taxes to Internet purchases

6 Examples of such work include Mackie-Mason and Varian (1995), Downes and Greenstein (1998), and thepapers in McKnight and Bailey (1995).

Page 6: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

5

would reduce the number of online buyers by 20-25% and spending by 25-30%. The large

elasticities estimated here raise important questions about long-run tax policy toward Internet

commerce.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section II describes the data used in the paper and the

general approach. Section III presents the basic evidence that taxes impact online buying

decisions and shows it to be highly robust. Section IV examines the mail-order/Internet

distinction for the case of computer purchases. Section V gives policy simulations of proposed

taxes on Internet commerce as well as some discussion of the longer-run role of sales taxes.

Section VI concludes.

II. Data and Specification

A. Data

A major problem with doing empirical work on Internet commerce has been data.

Aggregate data is not very useful. Observing that Internet sales are high in places with high taxes

may just indicate that places with high taxes have higher incomes, higher computer ownership,

higher education, or any number of factors that are correlated with online buying. Individual data

is extremely important but few consumer surveys even ask about the Internet and if they do, it is

hard to get sufficient sample sizes. In any random sample of the population, less than half the

respondents are likely to have computers, of those, only a fraction have Internet access and only a

small share of those have ever bought something online. To examine the response of such

purchases to local taxation then requires further dividing up the Internet shoppers by geographic

location. It is easy to see why this will tend to yield small samples.

In this paper, I turn to an extensive private survey conducted in late 1997 for Forrester

Inc., a market research company in Cambridge, Massachusetts. The survey was conducted by the

NPD group and is meant to provide a nationally representative portrait of the computer and

technology decisions of more than 110,000 consumers. The survey includes detailed information

Page 7: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

6

about various demographic characteristics such as income, age, gender, education, as well as the

state and metropolitan area of residence.7 The information covers the ownership of computers, as

well. About 45% of the respondents had computers at the time of the survey. Those owners

were then asked whether they had online access and if so, how often they used it and were asked

for their online buying history. In total this yields a sample of about 25,000 online users, sixteen

percent of whom report having purchased something online.

For each individual that has bought something online, the survey asks how much they have

spent (in four groupings: $0-25, $25-100, $100-500, and $500+) for different types of goods such

as books, software, or computers. I use the Forrester imputed values for each spending category

and sum across the types of goods to approximate the total amount spent online. Using this

measure, the average amount spent, conditional on buying, is $322. This is similar to existing

estimates of average online spending such as Krantz (1998). Although the analysis will be done at

the individual level, for expositional purposes, figure 1 shows the share of Internet users that have

purchased something online in each state. There is decided variation across locations.

Matching the purchase data to local sales tax rates requires making some assumptions

because the data do not give the actual town name of the respondent. Even if it did, there are as

many as 6400 different sales tax rates across the United States (see Rappaport, 1994) and

information on them is not kept by the federal government and must be collected at the state and

local level.

I assume, first, that any one living in the primary state of the metropolitan area actually

lives in the primary city itself. In other words, I assume that a person in the Chicago metropolitan

area who lives in Illinois lives in the city of Chicago. This prevents me from distinguishing

between city and suburb within the same state, but is necessary given the nature of the data.

Since, when they differ, the tax rates will almost always be lower in the suburbs, this error in

7 The metropolitan areas are actually defined as the television market the respondent lives in. These are generallylarger than the corresponding SMSA. San Francisco, for example, includes the entire bay area.

Page 8: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

7

measurement will tend to bias the estimated tax elasticities downward.

For practical purposes, I assume, next, that anyone living outside the primary state resides

in the physically closest county to the main city (measured using Rand McNally, 1997). If that

state is one that applies both city and county rates, such as Oklahoma, I assume that they live in

the largest city in that closest county.

In total, this yields 351 different city-state locations. The tax rates for most of these 351

locations were then compiled individually either from direct conversation with the department of

revenue in the state or from documents on the department’s website. For states without

centralized information, I contacted a local chamber of commerce in the city or county. Specific

local information was not necessary for some of the states since several have constant statewide

tax rates and four have no sales tax at all (Montana, New Hampshire, Delaware, and Oregon).

The average sales tax rate in a state (weighted by population) is shown in figure 2.

Table 1 gives summary statistics of the sample of people with online access and then

divided according to whether or not they have ever purchased something online. The two are not

very different in most measures although online buyers appear to be slightly better educated than

other online users, are somewhat more likely to be female, and so on.

B. Model and Specification

The idea of the paper is simple. An individual choosing whether to buy a good at a store

versus online will compare the relative prices. Assuming that he avoids paying use tax on the

online transaction and that local sales taxes do not affect local retail prices (i.e., elastic local

supply), the individual will be more likely to buy online the greater is the relative price ratioP t

PS

I

( )1 +,

where the t is the sales tax, P is price and the subscript S indicates in a retail store and I indicates

Page 9: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

8

an online merchant. 8 I will follow the common assumption in the literature on sales taxes across

regions and assume the relative price, P PS I/ , is constant across regions. Two comparisons of

Internet and retail prices (Goldman Sachs, 1997; Bailey, 1998) suggest that the ratio is close to 1

for many common products so I will assume that for the elasticity calculations.

I will use two related specifications for the individual’s choices about Internet commerce

each of which will include the tax rate and a number of economic and demographic controls such

as income, age, and education. For the probability of having bought something online, I will use a

probit model. For the amount that an individual reports having spent online, I will use a Tobit

model (censored because a large number of people report no spending).

3. Results

The initial results from estimating the probit regression of the {0,1} response of having

ever bought online (conditional on having Internet access) are presented in column 1 of table 2.

The coefficients listed give the estimated marginal effects of the covariates on the probability of

buying online. The mean probability of buying conditional on having online access is estimated to

be 20.3%. The explanatory variables other than the sales tax term include income, education,

age, race, gender, marital status, and dummies for the presence of children under 18 in the

respondent’s household, whether the respondent operates their own business, uses a computer at

work, or owned a computer in the previous year. The standard errors are corrected for the fact

that tax rates do not vary at the individual level but only by city and state.

The results show that the sales tax does appear to have a significant impact on the decision

to buy online and has the predicted sign. The magnitude suggests that at the mean of the

covariates, raising the sales tax by .01 increases the probability of buying online by about .005.

Since the mean probability of purchase is approximately .20, the estimated elasticity of online

8 The impact of local taxes on local prices has been examined by Poterba (1996) who finds no effect on pre-taxprices and by Besley and Case (1998) who find that higher taxes actually raise pre-tax prices.

Page 10: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

9

buying with respect to the tax price (one plus the tax rate) is 2.3. The other coefficients are

significant and have predictable signs. Higher income, more education, and using a computer at

work make a person more likely to have bought online. Being older, male, or married make a

person less likely.

Column 2, presents the Tobit version of the same specification where the dependent

variable is the amount the individual has spent online. Again, there is evidence of a significant

effect of tax rates on Internet commerce. At the mean, the elasticity of spending with respect to

one plus the tax rate is 3.6.

Both of these estimates may suffer from an obvious potential source of bias. They show

that, controlling for observables, people who live in high sales tax locations tend to buy more over

the Internet. It is clearly possible that places with high levels of “technological sophistication”

where people are disproportionately likely to have bought online may primarily be urban areas like

New York and San Francisco which also happen to have high sales tax rates, leading to a spurious

correlation. In theory, the relationship could even be created by city level policies. If a city raised

its sales tax in order to pay for Internet infrastructure to make online use easier, this would

certainly make high sales taxes look influential for online buying but for a different reason. I will

attempt to deal with potential unobserved heterogeneity bias in a number of ways but it is

important to note that the bias need not go in this direction. Other factors may bias the results in

the opposite way. The results in table 1, for example, condition on having online access. If the

only people with online access in a technologically “backward” locations (that also tend to have

low tax rates) are the diehard Internet users who frequently buy, this will bias the coefficient

downward.

To deal with the unobserved city characteristics, I first present (columns 3 and 4) the same

probit and Tobit regressions but restrict the sample to include only the top 30 metropolitan areas

with the idea that these may be more comparable locations and will help eliminate any bias caused

from comparison to rural and small town locations. This restriction reduces the sample by more

Page 11: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

10

than 40%. The coefficients on the sales tax, however, are not significantly different than in the

full sample and the point estimates are larger. They still show that taxes appear to have a

significant effect on Internet purchases. The elasticities here are 2.9 on buying and 3.4 on

spending. Obviously this does not rule out the spurious correlation, but does suggest that

whatever the correlation between technological sophistication and tax rates, it must be just as true

among the top 30 cities as it is between large metropolitan areas and more rural areas.

Next, in table 3, I use the variation in tax rates across geographic areas to further narrow

the comparison groups. Column 1 and 2 include region dummies and asks whether individuals

with the same observable characteristics and living in the same region are more likely to buy

online in a city with a higher tax rate. In both the probit and Tobit regressions, taxes have a

significant impact within regions. The elasticities at the mean are 2.4 and 3.5. Column 3 and 4

include state dummies and ask whether people with the same observables living in the same state

are more likely to buy online where the sales tax is higher. Here the coefficients are particularly

large and significant suggesting that taxes matter within a given state. The elasticities at the mean

are 8.4 and 11.7.

More importantly, however, columns 5 and 6 then include dummies for the metropolitan

area itself and asks whether people with identical observables living in the same metropolitan area

but in different states (where sales taxes can differ) are more likely to buy online if their part of

town has higher tax rates. Of the 207 metropolitan areas in the sample, 71 have people living

across state boundaries. New York, Philadelphia, and Washington D.C. are the most prominent

examples but there are many others. The coefficient on local taxation in both specifications

remains large and significant. The elasticities at the mean are 3.6 and 4.8 in the two equations.

All of the results that follow will include these metropolitan area dummies to give the best

controls.

To show these within metropolitan area results more clearly, columns 7 and 8 look at such

city level variation in the most prominent metropolitan areas that cross state boundaries and have

Page 12: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

11

significant sales tax variation. Of the top-30 greater metropolitan areas, there are four with 15%

or more of the population living outside the primary state and also have differences in sales tax

rates across the communities of more than half a percentage point. Those four are New York

(NY, CT, and NJ), Philadelphia (PA, NJ, and DE), Washington, D.C. (DC, VA, and MD), and

Boston (MA, NH, and VT). The results show that people with the same observables living in the

metropolitan area but living in the part of town with higher taxes are significantly more likely to

buy over the Internet in these four cities. The elasticities are even larger here than in the economy

wide specifications. The elasticity of buying is more than 7 and the elasticity of spending is more

than 8.

Taken together, the results in table 3 suggest that at any level of analysis, retail sales taxes

do matter for Internet commerce. It may still be true, of course, that these results reflect a

correlation between taxes and unobserved variables. These results suggest, however, that such

correlation must be just as high or even higher within regions, states, and metropolitan areas. In

other words, the correlation between unobserved technological sophistication or Internet

infrastructure and the sales tax rate within the New York City area (NY vs. CT, say) must be

greater than the correlation between New York City and Bowling Green, Kentucky which has the

same tax rate as CT.

In Table 4, I present further evidence on the subject of unobservables. First, column 1

adds the top marginal income tax rate in the state to see if that appears to influence the online

buying probability. There is little reason to expect that it should influence online buying. If it

seems to matter and reduces the effect of the sales tax, this might cast doubt on the causal

interpretation of the sales tax coefficient. The results show, however, that the sales tax coefficient

is unchanged (elasticity is still 3.9) and that there is no significant effect of income tax rates.

Next, each respondent with online access reports their frequency of going online. If the

tax coefficient in the online purchase regressions arises from unobserved technological

sophistication or Internet infrastructure, controlling for online usage should tend to reduce or

Page 13: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

12

eliminate the tax coefficient on purchasing. Column 2 shows that online use (in days per month)

does have a large, significant effect on the probability of buying online. It does not, however,

reduce or eliminate the tax coefficient. That coefficient remains large and significant with an

elasticity of buying of almost 4.

On top of that, column 3 deals with the unobserved heterogeneity point directly by

examining the respondent’s online frequency of use as the dependent variable and asks whether

use is higher in locations where there are high taxes. There is no reason to expect that high local

retail sales taxes should have an effect on the frequency of online use (as opposed to online

purchases). Any positive relationship here would strongly suggest that tax rates are correlated

with technological sophistication, Internet infrastructure, or the like. The results, however, show

no such effect. The coefficient on taxes is insignificant and extremely small. People in a city at

the lowest decile of sales tax (.04725) use the Internet approximately .003 days per month less

frequently than people in the top decile of sales tax (.08). The mean frequency of use is 16.7 days

per month so the effect is really quite small. Even if the coefficient were the highest value in the

95% confidence interval, the increase would still be less than half a day per month. These results

suggest that people in high tax locations are no more likely to use the Internet, only to buy things

over the Internet (even controlling for how much they use the Internet).

Column 4 examines how many computers the respondent reports having ever owned.

Again, if there is unobserved technological sophistication correlated with tax rates, people in

places with high rates will buy more over the Internet but are also likely to have owned more

computers over time than people in places with low rates. The results show, however, that the

point estimate is very small, not significant and the sign is actually negative. The average person

with online access has owned 1.97 computers in their lifetime. Moving from the bottom decile of

tax rates to the top decile reduces the number of computers at the mean by .03.

Next, column 5 uses the respondents self evaluation from one to ten of the statement “I

like technology.” This is an arbitrary ranking but, again, there is no evidence that people living in

Page 14: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

13

high tax locations like technology more than people in low tax locations. The point estimate is

negative though small and insignificant.

The evidence, then, is somewhat robust that Internet commerce is sensitive to local tax

rates and there is little evidence that the effect is spurious. The elasticity of online purchases

when including the controls for metropolitan area are comfortably above 3 with the elasticity of

spending of almost 4. Some specifications suggest even larger effects. These elasticities are quite

close to similar elasticities estimated for the tax responsiveness of sales in border communities and

open economies in the research mentioned above. The elasticities there are often close to 5 or 6.

Implicit in the discussion has been the view that consumers are deciding between retail purchases

and Internet purchases. If Internet purchases are instead coming out of mail-order sales, the

implications for policy making may be different. Since mail-order faces no sales tax, however, it

is difficult to see why Internet sales would be higher in places with high sales taxes. For one

particular good, however, I am able to consider the mail-order context simultaneously.

4. Retail, Mail-Order, and the Internet.

The treatment of Internet sales is, as stated previously, exactly the same as that of mail-

order companies so it is natural to wonder why states have expended so much effort recently to

allow the taxation of Internet commerce instead of devoting considerably more attention to the

currently much larger sales of mail-order. According to the Census of Retail, mail-order company

sales amounted to $48.8 billion in 1997 and this is likely to be an under-estimate for reasons

described in ACIR (1986). Such a number well exceeds the current size of Internet purchases.

There are likely to be two reasons for this behavior. The first is that, in some sense, the

battle over mail-order sales has already been lost. The supreme court has ruled that states cannot

require out-of-state companies to collect use tax without congressional legislation permitting it.

Major proposals to pass such legislation in the 1980s such as ACIR (1986) were defeated. The

mail-order business is now well established and has a major lobby in its own right. In this sense

Page 15: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

14

the Internet is more pressing precisely because it is not yet well established.

A second reason the states may be less concerned with mail-order, however, is that the

growth of mail-order relative to retail sales has slowed considerably in recent years. The mail-

order share of total retail sales, as reported in the Monthly Retail Sales, grew at an annual rate of

almost 9% from 1985 to 1992 (Bureau of the Census, various). ACIR (1986) suggests that this

growth followed years of growth in the late 1970s and early 1980s of comparable annual rates.

From 1992 to 1998, however, the growth rate has been only about 0.5% per year. Mail-order’s

share of sales seems to have reached a plateau, lessening the urgency on the part of departments

of revenue around the country. Certainly Internet sales will also slow down eventually but the

question is after how long? With growth rates of 300% per year and the predictions of continued

massive growth, the Internet may easily become significantly more important that mail-order is

now. That has made it a primary area of concern.

A key issue in this context is whether the tax sensitivity of Internet commerce is similar to

that of mail-order sales. Unfortunately, to my knowledge, there is no empirical work examining

this question. This is likely due to a lack of data. Using the Forrester data, however, I can relate

the tax sensitivities of mail-order and Internet sales for at least one product type. In addition to

the online sales information used above, the Forrester data provide detailed information about

computer purchases (this is the data used in Goolsbee and Klenow, 1998) and this information

includes where computer owners bought their machines. The choices include a variety of types of

retail establishments, “online,” and “direct from the manufacturer.” In 1997, there were almost

40,000 computer owners in the sample. I classify “direct from the manufacturer” as mail-order

though that may include some Internet purchases in recent years. With this classification, 79% of

people bought their current computer in a store, about 19% through mail-order, and almost 2%

online.

Using these data, I ask whether, conditional on having a computer, individuals more likely

to have bought either online or through mail-order in places where there are high sales taxes.

Page 16: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

15

This is, in a sense, a two-step decision where at the top level the individual decides whether to

buy a computer and next decides where to buy the computer. To estimate this lower level

decision, I use a logit model where the dependent variable is zero if the computer was bought at a

retail store and one if it was bought online or through mail-order. The explanatory variables are

the same as in the specifications above and they include the metropolitan area dummies. The

results listed in column 1 of Table 5 show that the coefficient on local taxation is positive and

significant, suggesting that people with a computer and the same observables who live in the same

metropolitan area are more likely to have bought their computer in a retail store the lower is the

local tax rate. The magnitude of the coefficient suggests that lowering the sales tax by .05 (an

exercise that will be of particular interest in the next section) would lower the probability of

buying “remotely” through mail-order or the Internet from .222 to .178, a decrease of almost

20%.

In columns 2a and 2b, I estimate a multinomial logit model that separates the mail-order

and Internet buyers. Here the baseline is buying from a retail store and the individual can choose

either mail-order or online purchase as an alternative. I restrict the coefficients on the non-tax

terms to be the same for mail-order and for online sales to make the tax coefficients comparable

but the results were the same allowing the covariates to impact the choices differently. Although

the number of Internet purchasers is much smaller and thus the standard error is larger, the

coefficients on mail-order and online purchases are both large and positive and they are not

significantly different. The point estimates of the Internet are even larger than on mail-order. At

existing tax rates, the mean probability of having bought in a store is .817, through mail-order is

.169, and online is .014. Lowering the sales tax by .05 raises the retail probability to .858, lowers

the mail-order probability by more than 20% to .133 and the online probability more than 35% to

.009. Although this is evidence only on one product, it does suggest that similar tax

considerations are at work with mail-order sales as they are with online sales and raises the issue

of whether applying taxes to the Internet would merely shift sales toward mail-order purchases.

Page 17: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

16

5. Policy Implications

A. Impacts of major proposals

At this point, given the estimates presented in the previous section, it is natural to ask

what would happen to Internet commerce if the United States were to start taxing it effectively

such as having the firms collect the tax. The two most relevant existing policy proposals are the

proposal by the NGA to apply a consistent 5% rate to all Internet and mail-order sales and the

more general proposal to let each local area simply apply existing sales taxes to all Internet

commerce.9 In general this latter policy implies a somewhat higher tax rate since the average tax

rate in the sample, when weighted by population, is 6.33%.

The results above use the sales tax on retail sales to explain Internet sales. To calculate

the impact of applying sales taxes to the Internet is a slightly different question. I have been

interpreting the tax sensitivity of online commerce as being caused by the price differential

between it and retail. In that sense, applying a 5% tax to Internet sales is equivalent to reducing

the tax on retail sales by 5%. All that matters is the relative tax treatment.

Consider, then, the two proposals (applying a 5% rate and applying existing rates). On

average, as would be expected given the large elasticities, applying a sales tax to Internet

commerce significantly reduces online commerce. If a five percent tax rate were applied to online

sales (calculated here as reducing the retail sales tax by 5%), the number of online customers

would be 18% lower (using the specifications that include metropolitan area dummies) and total

sales 23% smaller. The alternative proposal of applying existing tax rates to commerce would

eliminate even more Internet commerce. It would reduce the number of buyers by 24% and

spending by 30%. Responses in some of the specifications were even larger.

Any such calculation is, necessarily, partial equilibrium in nature. It is identified off of the

cross-sectional variation in tax rates which may not be the same as the effect generated by an

9 In practice, obviously, use taxes already exist so the issue would be the same as applying an enforceable use tax.

Page 18: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

17

aggregate shock to the tax rate in all locations. An upward sloping supply curve of Internet firms

might lead to price changes, for example, which blunt the effects of tax changes on quantities (see

Goolsbee, 1998 for a discussion in the investment context). That said, the results do suggest that

Internet commerce is particularly sensitive to local taxation.

Since the Internet is such a small part of existing retail sales, however, the results

document that the taxation of Internet commerce matters much more for the Internet commerce

than it does for tax revenue at the present time. Even a 30% drop in Internet sales has a very

small impact on retail sales or total sales tax revenue in a state. One result of that fact is that

protecting Internet commerce from taxation, for whatever reason, is unlikely to be very costly

though that will change if the Internet continues growing at current rates.

B. Long-run Policymaking

Even for current tax policy, however, the results pose a paradox for taxes and the Internet.

From one perspective, there is clear evidence that a price differential is generating shifting across

distribution channels which will tend to generate a deadweight loss. In the spirit of Cortlett and

Hague’s (1954) conclusion that we should tax substitutes similarly, eliminating the differential

taxation would seem to be welfare improving (see also the discussion in McLure, 1997). This

point has certainly been made about mail-order sales (ACIR, 1986).

At the same time, however, the same large responses suggest that to apply taxes now

would reduce Internet commerce substantially and several arguments may weigh against doing so,

at least in the short run.10 First, as the results on computers demonstrated, mail-order and

Internet sales appear to be equally responsive, at least for computers. Given that out-of-state

mail-order sales are generally untaxed, it is important to find out whether Internet sales would

otherwise have been bought through the mail. If they are, applying taxes to the Internet without

10 A more detailed discussion and evaluation of many different arguments for and against taxing Internetcommerce is the subject of ongoing research in Goolsbee and Zittrain (1998).

Page 19: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

18

applying taxes to mail-order will reduce consumer welfare without generating any revenue. In the

case of computers and probably a number of other goods, this issue is clearly relevant and it

highlights the importance of not setting Internet tax policy unilaterally.

Second, there may be serious problems with enforcing a tax on Internet sales. Even if

congress decides that states can require out-of-state vendors to collect use tax on sales, the

Internet will face a number of problems that mail-order companies do not. Increasingly, for

example, Internet sales are information goods such as software that can be directly downloaded

with no mailing address. In such a circumstance, calculating the relevant tax rate and enforcing it

may be expensive (see The Economist, 1997b).

Finally, there are some externality based stories that may support lower tax rates. If there

are network externalities associated with the Internet or there are information uncertainties about

using credit cards online, an infant industry protection type argument might suggest a moratorium

on taxes until the Internet is better established. The fact that the Internet is currently such a small

segment of retail sales means that the revenue cost of providing this protection in the short-run is

small. Relatedly, even if maximizing revenue is the only goal of state governments, the existence

of network externalities in Internet commerce may suggest that taxes should be low or even

negative early on to increase the size of the Internet in the future. Ron Wyden, a co-sponsor of

the Internet Tax Freedom Act, seems to have had an argument like this in mind when he explained

the need for federal action by saying “the crazy quilt of state and local taxes could do irreparable

harm to the Internet, killing the goose that could lay billions of dollars in golden eggs.” (Wyden,

1997). In addition, work by Trandel (1992) suggests that having low tax rates in outlying

geographic areas can reduce the market power of city retailers and force down markups which

improves consumer welfare. This same argument may be true for applying low tax rates for

Internet retailers.

5. Conclusion

Page 20: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

19

This paper presents an empirical analysis of how local taxation affects individual’s

decisions to buy things over the Internet. Using an extensive data source of approximately 25,000

people with online access, this paper has shown that such taxes play an influential role in online

commerce. Controlling for individual characteristics, people living in places with higher tax rates

are significantly more likely to buy things over the Internet. This is true within regions, within

states, and even within cities. The effect remains when controlling for individual use of the

Internet. People living in high tax locations are no more likely to use the Internet, to have owned

several computers, or to like technology than people in low tax cities. The relationship between

taxes and Internet sales is, therefore, unlikely to be caused by unobservable correlation between

tax rates and unobserved technological sophistication across locations. Using data on computer

purchases, the data also suggest that the tax impact on Internet purchases may be somewhat

similar to the tax impact on mail-order sales.

The magnitudes on Internet sales are quite large and suggest that applying existing sales

taxes to the Internet might reduce the number of online buyers by 25% and online spending by

30% or more. Since Internet sales currently make up such a small fraction of total retail sales,

however, the revenue loss from not applying such taxes is rather small so the cost of protecting

the Internet in the short-run is small. If the growth rate of the Internet continues at current rates,

however, this could change.

In total, the results give empirical support to the idea that local taxes can play an

important role for individuals living in a “world without borders” and they motivate further

empirical work on the role of taxes in an open economy such as the Internet.

Page 21: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

20

Average Probability of Online Purchasefor Internet Users

0.23 to 0.292 (8)0.213 to 0.23 (10)0.196 to 0.213 (11)0.171 to 0.196 (7)0.117 to 0.171 (12)

FIGURE 1

Page 22: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

21

Average Sales Tax Ratein Percent

6.9 to8.4 (12)6.2 to6.9 (10)6.1 to6.2 (1)5.1 to6.1 (15)0 to5.1 (10)

FIGURE 2

Page 23: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

22

TABLE 1: SUMMARY STATISTICSAll Online Users Buyers Non-Buyers

n

(1+t)

Income

Education

Age

Asian

Nonwhite minority

Children

Single

Female

Run own Business

Computer at work

Own comp last year

26219

1.066(.0168)

61.1(41.1)14.9(2.2)40.1

(12.4).021

(.142).145

(.352).408

(.491).399

(.490).556

(.497).172

(.378).786

(.410).751

(.432)

5544

1.067(.0163)

65.3(42.2)15.2(2.2)39.3

(11.9).026

(.159).137

(.344).360

(.480).433

(.496).648

(.478).213

(.410).838

(.369).839

(.368)

20675

1.066(.0169)

59.9(40.8)14.8(2.3)40.4

(12.6).019

(.137).147

(.354).421

(.494).390

(.488).531

(.499).161

(.368).772

(.420).728

(.445)

Page 24: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

23

TABLE 2: BASIC RESULTS(1) (2) (3)

Top 30 Metro(4)

Top 30 MetroMethod

(1+t)

Income

Education

Age

Asian

Nonwhite minority

Children

Single

Female

Run own Business

Computer at work

Own comp last year

σ

N

Probit

.4554(.1546)

.0005(.0001).0052

(.0013)-.0022(.0002).0102

(.0161)-.0068(.0091)-.0378(.0059).0364

(.0067).0731

(.0056).0563

(.0073).0273

(.0072).0970

(.0066)

24499

Tobit

1366.12(363.60)

1.76(.17)18.25(2.94)-5.30(.55)60.19

(39.12)-9.80

(17.40)-87.51(13.59)113.64(14.71)203.52(12.62)155.06(15.16)90.70

(16.45)228.12(15.49)

671.11(7.66)

24697

Probit

.6046(.1751)

.0006(.0001).0040

(.0017)-.0023(.0003).0198

(.0191)-.0040(.0128)-.0521(.0075).0437

(.0092).0766

(.0078).0542

(.0096).0359

(.0094).0858

(.0092)

13930

Tobit

1287.82(477.04)

1.96(.22)17.73(4.14)-5.72(.76)80.67

(47.01)-7.78

(22.84)-116.57(19.04)123.41(20.37)223.22(17.48)148.32(20.75)110.83(23.79)211.63(21.39)

703.11(10.45)

13930Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. The method of estimation is listed at the top of each column. Thedependent variable in columns (1) and (3) is whether the individual reports having bought something online. Thedependent variable in columns (2) and (4) is the amount that the individual has spent online as defined in the text. The sample in the last two columns is restricted to people in the top 30 largest greater metropolitan areas in thedata.

Page 25: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

24

TABLE 3: RESULTS WITHIN REGIONS, STATES, AND METROPOLITAN AREAS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Top 4

(8)

Top 4

Method

(1+t)

Demog:Dums:

N

Probit

.4586(.1554)

11 varsRegion

24135

Tobit

1284.9(415.9)

11 varsRegion

24135

Probit

1.6041(.6258)

11 varsState

24135

Tobit

4268.0(1525.9)

11 varsState

24135

Probit

.7097(.3059)

11 varsMetro

24117

Tobit

1548.7(786.0)

11 varsMetro

24117

Probit

1.5933(.2811)

11 varsMetro

3706

Tobit

3148.7(1256.5)

11 varsMetro

3706

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. The method of estimation is listed at the top of each column. Thedependent variable in columns (1), (3), (5), and (7) is whether the individual reports having bought somethingonline. The dependent variable in columns (2), (4), (6) and (8) is the amount that the individual has spent onlineas defined in the text. Each column includes dummy variables as indicated at the base of the column. Columns (7)and (8) restrict the sample to respondents in the New York City, Philadelphia, Boston, and Washington, D.C.,areas.

Page 26: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

25

TABLE 4: ADVANCED RESULTS: CONTROLLING FOR UNOBSERVABLES(1)

Income Tax

(2)

Buy Online

(3)

Frequencyof use

(4)

# of Comps(Ever)

(5)

“LikeTechnology”

Method

(1+t)

Freq. of Use

tINC

DemographicsDummies

NR2

Probit

.7866(.2814)

.2014(.2277)

11 varsMetro

23202--

Probit

.7338(.2705)

.0086(.0003)

11 varsMetro

24117--

OLS

.1013(7.510)

11 varsMetro

24683.063

OLS

-.8575(.8057)

11 varsMetro

23969.368

OLS

-1.626(1.500)

11 varsMetro

24423.118

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. The method of estimation is listed at the top of each column. Thedependent variable in columns (1) and (2) is whether the individual reports having bought something online. Thedependent variable in column (3) is the frequency of going online in days per month. The dependent variable incolumn (4) is the number of computers the respondent reports ever having owned. The dependent variable incolumn (5) is the ranking from one to ten that the respondent gives to the statement “I like technology.”

Page 27: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

26

TABLE 5: RETAIL, MAIL-ORDER, AND INTERNET FOR COMPUTERS

(1)

All Remote Sales

(2a)

Mail-Order

(2b)

Internet

Mail & Internet Together

(1+t)

DemographicsDummies

n

5.787(1.835)

11 varsmetro37994

6.123(1.994)

11 varsmetro37994

10.647(7.016)

11 varsmetro37994

Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. The sample in both regressions is restricted to computer owners. Column(1) estimates a logit model where the dependent variable is a zero if the individual bought their computer in a retailstore and one if they bought it either from mail-order or online. Column (2a) and (2b) are from a multinomiallogit regression where the dependent variable is zero if the individual bought their computer in a store, one if theybought through mail-order and 2 if they bought online. The coefficients on the other variables are restricted to bethe same for the two alternatives to retail.

Page 28: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

27

References

Advisory Council on Intergovernmental Relations (1986), State and Local Taxation of Out-of-State Mail Order Sales, Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C.

Bailey, Joseph (1998), "Electronic Commerce: Prices and Consumer Issues for Three Products:Books, Compact Discs, and Software," Organization for Economic Cooperation andDevelopment, OCDE/GD(98)4.

Besley, Tim and Harvey Rosen (1997), “Sales Taxes and Prices: An Empirical Analysis” Centerfor Economic and Policy Studies Working Paper 38.

Bourgeois, Pierre, and Luc Buchette (1997), “The Internet, Electronic Commerce, and Taxes--Some Reflections: Part 1,” Canadian Tax Journal, 45, 1127-1149.

Braid, R. (1987), “The Spatial Incidence of Retail Sales Taxes,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,102, 881-891.

Bureau of the Census (various issues), Monthly Retail Sales, Government Printing Office,Washington, D.C.

Cortlett, W. and D. Hague (1954), “Complentarity and the Excess Burden of Taxation,” Reviewof Economic Studies 21: 21-30.

Department of Commerce (1998), The Emerging Digital Economy. (G.P.O.; Washington, D.C.).

Downes, Tom and Shane Greenstein (1998), “Universal Access and Local Commercial InternetMarkets,” Mimeo, Northwestern University.

Economist, The (1997a), “The Disappearing Taxpayer,” p. 15, May 31st.

Economist, The (1997b), “Taxes Slip Through the Net,” p. 22, May 31st.

Fox, William (1986), “Tax Structure and the Location of Economic Activity Along StateBorders,” National Tax Journal, 14, 362-374.

Fox, William and Matthew Murray (1997), “The Sales Tax and Electronic Commerce: What’sNew?” National Tax Journal, 50(3), 573-592.

Galbraith, John and Murray Kaiserman (1997), “Taxation, Smuggling, and Demand for Cigarettesin Canada: Evidence from Time-Series Data.” Journal of Health Economics, 16, 287-301.

Goldman Sachs, “Cyber Commerce: Internet Tsunami,” August.

Page 29: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

28

Goolsbee, Austan (1998), “Investment Tax Incentives, Prices, and The Supply Of CapitalGoods,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1): 121-148.

Goolsbee, Austan and Peter Klenow (1998), “Evidence on Learning and Network Externalities inthe Diffusion of Home Computers,” Mimeo, University of Chicago, GSB.

Goolsbee, Austan and Jonathan Zittrain (1998), “Should We Tax Internet Commerce?” Mimeo inprogress, Berkman Center for Internet and Society, Harvard Law School.

Gordon, Roger (1983), “An Optimal Taxation Approach to Fiscal Federalism,” Quarterly Journalof Economics, 98, 567-586.

Gordon, Roger and Soren Nielsen (1997), “Tax Evasion in an Open Economy: Value-Added vs.Income Taxation,” Journal of Public Economics, 66, 173-197.

Greenstein, Shane (1998), “Universal Service in the Digital Age: The Commercialization andGeography of U.S. Internet Access,” NBER Working Paper # 6453.

Hof, Richard (1998), “The Net is Open for Business -- Big Time,” BusinessWeek, p. 108, August,31.

Holmes, Thomas (1998), “The Effect of State Policies on the Location of Manufacturing:Evidence from State Borders,” Journal of Political Economy, 106(4) 667-705.

Horner, Frances, and Jeffrey Owens (1996), “Tax and the Web: New Technology, Old Problems,”International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation Bulletin, Nov/Dec, 516-523.

Kanbur, Ravi and Michael Keen (1993), “Jeux Sans Frontieres: Tax Competition and TaxCoordination when Countries Differ in Size,” American Economic Review, 83, 877-892.

Krantz, Michael (1998), “Click Till You Drop,” Time, July 20.

Mackie-Mason, Jeffrey, and Hal Varian (1995),"Pricing the Internet" in Public Access to theInternet, Brian Kahin and James Keller, eds. (MIT Press; Cambridge).

McKnight, Lee and Joeseph Bailey (1997), Internet Economics. (MIT Press, Cambridge)

McLure, Charles (1997), “Electronic Commerce, State Sales Taxation, and IntergovernmentalFiscal Relations,” National Tax Journal, 50(4), 731-750.

Mikesell, John “Central Cities and Sales Tax Rate Differentials: The Border City Problem,”National Tax Journal, 23(2) 206-213.

Mintz, Jack and H. Tulkens (1986), “Commodity Tax Competition Between Member States of a

Page 30: 1. Introduction · 2 Such theoretical discussions can be found in Gordon (1983), Mintz and Tulkens (1986), Braid (1987), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1992; 1994) and Gordon and

29

Federation: Equilibrium and Efficiency,” Journal of Public Economics, 29, 133-172.

Poterba, James (1996), “Retail Price Reactions to Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes,”National Tax Journal, 49, pp. 165-176.

Pouliot, Colleen (1998), Senior Vice President and General Counsel, Adobe Systems Inc.,testimony before Commerce Committee, U.S. House of Representatives, July 29th.

Rand McNally (1997), Road Atlas: United States, Canada, Mexico, Deluxe 1997 edition, RandMcNally, Skokie, Illinois.

Rappaport, Neal (1994), Applied Econometric Essays on Sales Taxes and Computer PriceIndices, Ph.D. Dissertation, M.I.T.

Sheppard, Doug (1998), “Representatives Of Cities, Software Publishers Square Off On Internet Taxation.” State Tax Notes 15 (941).

Stephenson, Jack, and Michael Zeisser (1998), “Don’t Tax the Internet--Yet,” Wall StreetJournal, June 6, 1998.

Trandel, Gregory (1992), “Evading the Use of Tax on Cross-Border Sales: Pricing and WelfareEffects,” Journal of Public Economics, 35, 333-354.

Trandel, Gregory (1994), “Interstate Commodity Tax Differentials and the Distribution ofResidents,” Journal of Public Economics, 53(3), 435-457

Walsh, M, and J. Jones (1988), “More Evidence on the ‘Border Tax’ Effect: The Case of WestVirginia,” National Tax Journal, 14 362-374.

Wyden, Ron (1997), Statement on the Internet Tax Freedom Act. Homepage of the United StatesSenate, http://www.senate.gov/~wyden/leg/cybstate.htm, access date, November 10, 1998.