089533002320951037

32
Decentralization of Governance and Development Pranab Bardhan A ll around the world in matters of governance, decentralization is the rage. Even apart from the widely debated issues of subsidiarity and devolution in the European Union and states’ rights in the United States, decentraliza- tion has been at the center stage of policy experiments in the last two decades in a large number of developing and transition economies in Latin America, Africa and Asia. The World Bank, for example, has embraced it as one of the major governance reforms on its agenda (for example, World Bank, 2000; Burki, Perry and Dillinger, 1999). Take also the examples of the two largest countries of the world, China and India. Decentralization has been regarded as the major institu- tional framework for the phenomenal industrial growth in the last two decades in China, taking place largely in the nonstate nonprivate sector. India ushered in a landmark constitutional reform in favor of decentralization around the same time it launched a major program of economic reform in the early 1990s. On account of its many failures, the centralized state everywhere has lost a great deal of legitimacy, and decentralization is widely believed to promise a range of benefits. It is often suggested as a way of reducing the role of the state in general, by fragmenting central authority and introducing more intergovernmental com- petition and checks and balances. It is viewed as a way to make government more responsive and efficient. Technological changes have also made it somewhat easier than before to provide public services (like electricity and water supply) relatively efficiently in smaller market areas, and the lower levels of government have now a greater ability to handle certain tasks. In a world of rampant ethnic conflicts and separatist movements, decentralization is also regarded as a way of diffusing social and political tensions and ensuring local cultural and political autonomy. These potential benefits of decentralization have attracted a very diverse range y Pranab Bardhan is Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, California. Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 4 —Fall 2002—Pages 185–205

description

sasa

Transcript of 089533002320951037

Page 1: 089533002320951037

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 4—Fall 2002—Pages 185–205

Decentralization of Governance andDevelopment

Pranab Bardhan

A ll around the world in matters of governance, decentralization is the rage.Even apart from the widely debated issues of subsidiarity and devolution inthe European Union and states’ rights in the United States, decentraliza-

tion has been at the center stage of policy experiments in the last two decades ina large number of developing and transition economies in Latin America, Africaand Asia. The World Bank, for example, has embraced it as one of the majorgovernance reforms on its agenda (for example, World Bank, 2000; Burki, Perryand Dillinger, 1999). Take also the examples of the two largest countries of theworld, China and India. Decentralization has been regarded as the major institu-tional framework for the phenomenal industrial growth in the last two decades inChina, taking place largely in the nonstate nonprivate sector. India ushered in alandmark constitutional reform in favor of decentralization around the same timeit launched a major program of economic reform in the early 1990s.

On account of its many failures, the centralized state everywhere has lost agreat deal of legitimacy, and decentralization is widely believed to promise a rangeof benefits. It is often suggested as a way of reducing the role of the state in general,by fragmenting central authority and introducing more intergovernmental com-petition and checks and balances. It is viewed as a way to make government moreresponsive and efficient. Technological changes have also made it somewhat easierthan before to provide public services (like electricity and water supply) relativelyefficiently in smaller market areas, and the lower levels of government have now agreater ability to handle certain tasks. In a world of rampant ethnic conflicts andseparatist movements, decentralization is also regarded as a way of diffusing socialand political tensions and ensuring local cultural and political autonomy.

These potential benefits of decentralization have attracted a very diverse range

y Pranab Bardhan is Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, California.

Page 2: 089533002320951037

186 Journal of Economic Perspectives

of supporters. For example, free-market economists tend to emphasize the benefitsof reducing the power of the overextended or predatory state. In some interna-tional organizations pushing structural adjustment and transitional reform, decen-tralization has sometimes been used almost as a synonym for privatization; similarly,in the literature on mechanism design, an informationally decentralized system ofindividual decisions coordinated by a price mechanism is pitted against a system ofcentral commands and plans. Even those who are convinced of the pervasiveness ofmarket failures are increasingly turning for their resolution to the government atthe local level, where the transaction costs are relatively low and the informationproblems that can contribute to central government failures are less acute. Theyare joined by a diverse array of social thinkers: postmodernists, multiculturaladvocates, grassroots environmental activists and supporters of the cause of indig-enous peoples and technologies. In the absence of a better unifying name, I woulddescribe this latter group as “anarcho-communitarians.” They are usually bothanti-market and anti-centralized state, and they energetically support assignment ofcontrol to local self-governing communities.

As is usually the case when a subject draws advocates from sharply differentviewpoints, different people mean different things by decentralization. In thispaper, we shall focus on a particular kind of decentralization in developing andtransition economies, the devolution of political decision-making power to local-level, small-scale entities. In countries with a long history of centralized control—asin the old empire states of Russia, China or India—public administrators oftenmean by decentralization the dispersion of some responsibilities to regional branchoffices at the local level of implementation on a particular project. For the purposeof discussion in this paper, we shall distinguish decentralization in the sense ofdevolution of political decision-making power from such mere administrative del-egation of functions of the central government to local branches. We should alsoseparate the political and administrative aspects of decentralization from those offiscal decentralization and, in the latter, the more numerous cases of decentraliza-tion of public expenditure from those involving decentralization of both tax andexpenditure assignments. We shall include cases where local community organiza-tions become formally involved in the implementation of some centrally directedor funded projects. Not all these aspects of decentralization operate simultaneouslyin any particular case, and it is quite possible that a given economy may bedecentralized in some respects, not in others. It should also be clear that the effectsof a policy of deliberate decentralization—which is our concern here—can bequalitatively different from those following from an anarchic erosion of centralcontrol, which can be due either to the collapse of the state, as has happened insome countries in Africa, or lack of administrative or fiscal capacity on the part ofthe central authority leading to abandonment of social protection functions, as hashappened in some transition economies.

The territorial domain of subnational governments, of course, varies enor-mously from country to country. A typical province in India or China is larger inpopulation than most countries in the world, and so federalism in the sense of

Page 3: 089533002320951037

Pranab Bardhan 187

devolution of power to the provincial state governments may still keep power overpeople pretty centralized. Unfortunately, data below the provincial governmentlevel are often very scarce, and most quantitative studies of decentralization—forexample, those based on share of the central government in total expenditure orrevenues—do not pertain to the issues at the local community level (even apartfrom the fact that the share of expenditure or revenues is not a good index ofdecision-making authority). Even at the latter level, the units are diverse, rangingfrom megacities to small villages, and the boundaries are often determined byaccidents of history and geography, not by concerns of decentralization of admin-istration. In this paper, we shall in general confine the analytical focus of decen-tralization to the governing authority at the local community level: say, village,municipality or county levels of administration.

Our discussion begins with a description of why decentralization poses somedifferent issues in the institutional context of developing and transition countriesand, thus, why it may sometimes be hazardous to draw lessons for them from, say,the experiences of U.S. states and city governments. We try to give the flavor ofsome new theoretical models that extend the discussion to political agency prob-lems that may resonate more in the context of developing and transition econo-mies. We then refer to some of the ongoing empirical work in evaluating the impactof decentralization on delivery of public services and local business development.

Decentralization has undoubted merits and strengths. However, the idea ofdecentralization may need some protection against its own enthusiasts, both fromfree market advocates who see it as an opportunity to cripple the state and fromthose anarcho-communitarians who ignore the “community failures” that may be asserious as the market failures or government failures that economists commonlyanalyze.

Departures from the Fiscal Federalism Literature

There is a large literature on decentralization, often referred to as “fiscalfederalism,” mostly relating to the case of the United States.1 The principlesdiscussed in this literature have been fruitfully applied to the national-provincialrelations in developing countries like Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, South Africa,India or China, but in this paper, we shall go beyond this and stress the specialissues that arise in decentralization in developing and transition economies pri-marily because the institutional context, and therefore the structure of incentivesand organization, are in some respects qualitatively different from that in theclassical U.S. case or the recent case of the European Union.

Much of the fiscal federalism literature focuses on the economic efficiency ofintergovernmental competition, which often starts with a market metaphor that is

1 Many of the issues have been well surveyed in the JEP “Symposium on Fiscal Federalism” in the Fall1997 issue.

Page 4: 089533002320951037

188 Journal of Economic Perspectives

rationalized by the well-worn Tiebout (1956) model. In this approach, differentlocal governments offer different public tax-expenditure bundles, and mobileindividuals are supposed to allocate themselves according to their preferences. Theassumptions required for the Tiebout model are, however, much too stringent,particularly for poor countries.2

First, the crucial assumption of population mobility—fully informed citizens“voting with their feet” in response to differential public performance—that en-ables governments in the Tiebout framework to overcome the well-known problemof inducing citizens to reveal their preferences for public goods largely fails in poorcountries. In any case, many of the public goods in question are community- andsite-specific, and it is often possible to exclude nonresidents. Rural communities ofpoor countries, in particular, are often face-to-face, and social norms sharplydistinguish “outsiders” from “insiders,” especially with respect to entitlement tocommunity services.

Secondly, the information and accounting systems and mechanisms of moni-toring public bureaucrats are much weaker in low-income countries. In the stan-dard literature on decentralization and fiscal federalism, the focus is on allocationof funds, and it is implicitly assumed that allocated funds automatically reach theirintended beneficiaries. This assumption needs to be drastically qualified in devel-oping countries, where attention must be paid to special incentives and devices tocheck bureaucratic corruption—and thus the differential efficacy of such mecha-nisms under centralization and decentralization becomes important.

Third, even in the relatively few democratic developing countries, the institu-tions of local democracy and mechanisms of political accountability are often weak.Thus, any discussion of delivery of public services has to grapple with issues ofcapture of governments at different tiers by elite groups more seriously than is thecustom in the traditional decentralization literature.

Fourth, the traditional literature on decentralization, even though not imper-vious to issues of distribution, is usually preoccupied with those of efficiency inpublic provision. When a major goal of decentralization in developing countries isto effectively reach out to the poor (or to diffuse unrest among disadvantagedminority groups), often in remote backward areas, targeting success in povertyalleviation programs is a more important performance criterion than the efficiencyof interregional resource allocation. In the traditional discussion of decentraliza-tion and federalism, the focus is on checks and balances, on how to restrain thecentral government’s power, whereas in many situations in developing countries,the poor and the minorities, oppressed by the local power groups, may be lookingto the central state for protection and relief. Stepan (forthcoming) has made auseful distinction between “coming-together federalism” like the United States,where previously sovereign polities gave up part of their sovereignty for efficiency

2 There are doubts about just how the Tiebout mechanism operates even in relatively mobile societieslike that of the United States. For instance, very few poor people move from state to state in search ofhigher welfare benefits (Hanson and Hartman, 1994).

Page 5: 089533002320951037

Decentralization of Governance and Development 189

gains from resource pooling and a common market, and “holding-together feder-alism” like the multinational democracies of India, Belgium and Spain, where theemphasis is on redistributive or compensating transfers to keep the contendingpolities together. In heterogeneous societies, such redistributive pressures some-times lead fiscal decentralization to allow for state and local borrowing that may belarge enough to cause problems of macroeconomic stabilization, as has happenedin South Africa, Brazil and Argentina.3 Not all state-mandated redistribution,however, is inflationary or unproductive rent creation, as is usually presumed in thetraditional literature. Some redistribution to disadvantaged groups or regions—say in the form of decentralized delivery of health, education or infrastructuralservices—need not be at the expense of efficiency and may even improve thepotential for productive investment, innovation and human resource developmenton the part of communities long bypassed by the elite or the mainstream.

Fifth, the fiscal federalism literature typically assumes that lower levels ofgovernment both collect taxes and spend funds, so localities can be classified as lowtax/low service or high tax/high service. This connection between local revenuesand spending is actually rather tenuous. In most countries, much of the moreelastic (and progressive) sources of tax revenue lie with the central government,and there is a built-in tendency toward vertical fiscal imbalance. Income is oftengeographically concentrated, both because of agglomeration economies and initialendowments of natural resources and infrastructural facilities. Thus, certain localareas will find it much easier to raise significant tax revenue than others. Inaddition, there are limits to interregional tax competition. In many low-incomecountries, the decentralization issues discussed there are primarily about providingcentrally collected tax revenue to lower levels of government, rather than seekingto empower lower levels of government to collect taxes. The focus is on publicexpenditure assignments, unaccompanied by any significant financial devolution.

Sixth, the decentralization literature typically assumes that different levels ofgovernment all have similar levels of technical and administrative capacity. Thisassumption is questionable for all countries. On account of agglomeration econo-mies in attracting qualified people, in most countries, central bureaucracies attractbetter talent. But the problem is especially severe in many developing countries,where the quality of staff in local bureaucracies—including basic tasks like account-ing and record keeping—is very low. Even their more professional and technicalpeople suffer from the disadvantages of isolation, poor training and low interactionwith other professionals. As Bird (1995) puts it, information asymmetry thus worksboth ways: the central government may not know what to do; the local government

3 This paper will not have much to say on the impact of decentralization on macroeconomic stabiliza-tion. For a game-theoretic model of how decentralization or local democratization may increase the levelof central redistribution to prevent spirals of regional revolt and how the macroeconomic consequencesdepend on the initial levels of cultural division and decentralization, see Treisman (1999).

Page 6: 089533002320951037

190 Journal of Economic Perspectives

may not know how to do it.4 Of course, this problem is of differential importancein different services. Providing for street cleaning or garbage collection may notrequire sophisticated expertise, but power production and transmission, bulksupply of clean water and public sanitation do. Decentralization to the local levelwill often work better in the former kind of services than the latter.

In our subsequent discussion, we shall consider the issues of decentralizationin developing countries, keeping in mind these points of difference with thetraditional literature.

Adapting the Theory of Decentralization for Developing Countries

The conventional wisdom in the fiscal federalism literature, as in Oates (1972),is that decentralization is to be preferred when tastes are heterogeneous and thereare no spillovers across jurisdictions. With spillovers and no heterogeneity, a centralgovernment providing a common level of public goods and services for all localitiesis more efficient; with spillovers, decentralization leads to underprovision of localpublic goods, as local decision makers do not take into account benefits going toother districts. The issue of spillovers is relevant to investment in certain areas, likehighway transport and communication, public research and extension and con-trolling pollution or epidemics. It is less relevant when the public goods are morelocal, as in local roads, minor irrigation, village health clinics, sanitation andidentification of beneficiaries of public transfer programs.

Centralization can also exploit economies of scale better in the construction ofoverhead facilities, but these economies of scale are less important in local man-agement and maintenance. In a canal irrigation system—for example, the one inSouth Korea described by Wade (1997)—construction was in the hands of centralauthority, but maintenance was devolved to local communities. Similarly, in pri-mary education, while the local government may run the day-to-day functioning ofschools, the upper-tier government can have the economies of scale in designingcurricula and prescribing and enforcing minimum quality standards. In the publicdelivery of electricity, economies of scale in generation and transmission may bethe responsibility of centralized power plants and grids, while the distribution maybe decentralized to local governments.

The traditional theory of fiscal federalism is now being extended to a politicaleconomy setting, with the introduction of transaction costs in the political marketsor political agency problems between the ruler and the ruled, between the politi-

4 Occasionally, however, the local people come up with ingenious low-cost solutions, whereas centralizedsystems use unnecessarily expensive services of specialized technicians. For some of the basic needs forpoor people, local youths with some minimum training as primary health workers or primary schoolteachers can be adequate. In other, more technical, projects there is a lot of scope for improving accessto engineering, project design and administrative skills. Organizations like AGETIP in Africa or theBrazil-based IBAM have in recent years been helpful in developing local technical capacity.

Page 7: 089533002320951037

Pranab Bardhan 191

cians/bureaucrats and the electorate, and for reasons mentioned above thesetransaction and agency costs may be much more serious in the context of devel-oping countries. It is usually argued that the local government has an informationadvantage over the upper-tier governments. But it may be asked why a centralgovernment cannot procure for itself the same information advantage of proximitythrough local agents. In some countries, the central government uses such repre-sentatives at the local level for this purpose, like the prefets in France and Italy or theintendentes in Chile. It may even be argued that the central government can haveeconomies of scope in the collection of information. But the main reason why inpractice the local government still retains the informational advantage has to dowith political accountability. In democratic countries, the local politicians may havemore incentive to use local information than national or provincial politicians,since the former are answerable to the local electorate while the latter have widerconstituencies, where the local issues may get diluted.

Focusing on accountability, rather than information per se, leads to thinkingabout how the public can monitor and affect elected officials at different levels ofgovernment. Seabright (1996) discusses the problem of political accountabilitytheoretically in terms of allocation of control rights in the context of incompletecontracts, where breaches of contract are observable, though not verifiable inadministrative or judicial review, and are subject to periodic electoral review. Hismodel has both central and local elected officials. In his framework, centralizationallows benefits from policy coordination, which is especially important if there arespillovers across jurisdictions. However, centralization has costs in terms of dimin-ished accountability, in the sense of reduced probability that the welfare of a givenlocality can determine the re-election of the government. Elections are, of course,extremely blunt instruments of political accountability, and other institutionaldevices and unelected community organizations (like nongovernmental organiza-tions) may be deployed to strengthen local accountability.

The mechanism of accountability may also be strengthened by “yardstickcompetition,” where jurisdictions are compared to each other (for example, Besleyand Case, 1995). The effort or competence of public officials is not directlyobservable by citizens, and if poor results occur, public officials can always pleadthat they did the best that was possible under the circumstances. However, if theshocks that create a wedge between effort and outcomes are correlated acrossjurisdictions, then yardstick competition can act as an indicator of relative effort onthe part of agents. As Seabright (1996) points out, this argument of yardstickcompetition under decentralization, which may help voters to know whether theyshould seek to replace their governments, is to be distinguished from his ownargument that decentralization may increase their ability to do so.

The combination of decentralization and yardstick competition allows thepossibility of experimentation in the way a given public service is provided and thendemonstration and learning from other jurisdictions. In China in the early years ofits market reforms, decentralization with jurisdictional competition allowed somecoastal areas to experiment with institutional reform, the success of which showed

Page 8: 089533002320951037

192 Journal of Economic Perspectives

the way for the rest of the country. Economic historians have pointed to thefragmentation and decentralization in early modern Europe, sometimes called“parcelized sovereignty”—see, for example, the discussion in North and Thomas(1973)—as a source of strength, in enabling experimentation and competition,leading to technological and institutional innovations that helped Europe ulti-mately to overtake the more centralized empire states of Asia.

Tommasi and Weinschelbaum (1999) pose the political agency problem interms of the number of principals (relative to agents) in comparing centralizationand decentralization. Citizens are viewed as principals and their elected represen-tatives as agents. The local government has better means (in the form of informa-tion) to be responsive, also better (electoral) incentives. In the case of centraliza-tion, the number of principals is very large, while the number of agents are few,whereas in the case of decentralization, there is one agent per locality. The largerthe number of principals, the more serious is the problem of lack of coordinationin contracting with agents. Decentralization is preferable to centralization when theproblem of interjurisdictional externality is less important than the coordinationeffect.5

Besley and Coate (2000) focus on the importance of political aggregationmechanisms in the trade-off between centralized and decentralized provision oflocal public goods. Under decentralization, locally elected representatives selectpublic goods. Under a centralized system, policy choices are determined by alegislature consisting of elected representatives from each district, so that conflictsof interest between citizens of different jurisdictions play out in the legislature.They then reconsider the traditional questions of the fiscal federalism literature interms of alternative models of legislative behavior, one in which the decisions aretaken by a minimum winning coalition of representatives and the other wherelegislators reach a bargaining solution. They show that the familiar presumptionthat larger spillovers across jurisdictions help the case for centralization is not soclear under such political economy considerations.

Political accountability in poor countries is particularly affected by the likeli-hood of corruption or capture by interest groups. While local governments mayhave better local information and accountability pressure, they may be morevulnerable to capture by local elites, who will then receive a disproportionate shareof spending on public goods.6 (This is in contrast to the Seabright (1996) model

5 The idea of fewer principals in smaller jurisdictions having more political control clearly resembles therelationship between group size and free riding in the voluntary provision of a public good firstdiscussed by Olson (1965). As is well known, this relationship can be ambiguous.

6 In the Federalist Papers (no. 10), James Madison comments on the notion that local governments aremore prone to capture by elites and special interests: “The smaller the society, the fewer probably willbe the distinct parties and interests composing it; the fewer the distinct parties and interests, the morefrequently will a majority be found of the same party; and the smaller the number of individualscomposing a majority, and the smaller the compass within which they are placed, the more easily willthey concert and execute their plans of oppression. Extend the sphere and you take in a greater varietyof parties and interests; you make it less probable that a majority of the whole will have a common motive
Page 9: 089533002320951037

Decentralization of Governance and Development 193

where political accountability is always greater at the local level.) On the otherhand, the central bureaucrat who is in charge of the delivery of, say, an infrastruc-tural service like electricity, telecommunications or canal irrigation may be corruptin a way that leads to cost padding, targeting failures and generally an inefficientlylow and inequitable service delivery. The problem for the central government thatemploys the bureaucrat is that it has very little information on the local needs,delivery costs and the amount actually delivered. Thus, many programs in devel-oping countries have a large gap between a commitment of resources at the centrallevel and delivery of services at the local level. For a particularly egregious example,see Reinikka and Svensson (2001), who study the leakage in the flow of educationalfunds from the central government to schools in Uganda in the period 1991–1995.They found that only 13 percent of the total grant transferred from the centralgovernment for nonwage expenditures in schools on items like textbooks, instruc-tional materials and other costs actually reached the schools. The majority ofschools actually received no money at all from the central transfers for nonwageexpenditures.

Bardhan and Mookherjee (2000a) develop an analytical framework that for-malizes the tradeoff between these conflicting aspects of centralized and decen-tralized delivery systems. Decentralization, by shifting control rights from thecentral bureaucrat (who otherwise acts like an unregulated monopolist) to a localgovernment, typically tends to expand service deliveries as authority goes to thosemore responsive to user needs. But with capture of the local government, in thesense of elites receiving a larger weight in the local government’s maximand of aweighted sum of welfare, there is a tendency for the local government to overpro-vide the service to local elites at the expense of the non-elite. The extent of suchinefficient and inequitable cross-subsidization will depend on the extent of localcapture and on the degree of fiscal autonomy of the local government.

On the latter question, we consider three different financing mechanisms forlocal governments: local taxes, user fees and central grants. With local tax financ-ing, there is the risk that the captured local government may resort to a regressivefinancing pattern whereby the non-elite bear the tax burden of providing servicesto the elite. Restrictions on the ability of local governments to levy taxes may thenbe desirable, even at the cost of reducing flexibility of service provision to localneed. User charges may be a useful compromise between the need for matchingprovision to local needs and avoiding an unduly heavy burden on the local poor.Since no user is compelled to use the service, user charges impose a limit on theextent of cross-subsidization foisted on the poor. So with user fees, financingdecentralization unambiguously welfare-dominates centralization as well as localtax-financed decentralization, irrespective of the extent of local capture. Centralgrant financing, on the other hand, may encourage local governments to claim

to invade the rights of other citizens; or if such a common motive exists, it will be more difficult for allwho feel it to discover their own strength and to act in unison with each other.”

Page 10: 089533002320951037

194 Journal of Economic Perspectives

higher local need or cost, leading to a restriction of the level of service delivery; thewelfare implications are ambiguous, depending on a range of relevant political andfinancing parameters.

User charges cannot, however, be used to finance antipoverty programs suchas targeted public distribution of food, education or health services that by theirvery nature are targeted at groups that do not have the ability to pay for the service(or to pay bribes to the central bureaucrats). In such cases, as is shown in Bardhanand Mookherjee (2000b), the extent of capture of local governments relative tothat of the central government is a critical determinant of the welfare impact ofdecentralization. If local governments are equally or less vulnerable to capture thanthe central government, decentralization is then likely to improve both efficiencyand equity. But the opposite may be the case when capture at the local level is muchgreater than at the central level.

Even though the extent of relative capture of governments at different levelsis crucial in understanding the likely impact of decentralization initiatives, therehas been very little work on the subject, either theoretical7 or empirical. The extentof capture of local governments by local elites depends on levels of social andeconomic inequality within communities, traditions of political participation andvoter awareness, fairness and regularity of elections, transparency in local decision-making processes and government accounts, media attention and other factors.These factors vary widely across communities and countries, as documented innumerous case studies (for example, Crook and Manor, 1998; Conning and Ke-vane, 2001). Of course, central governments are also subject to capture andperhaps even to a greater extent than at the local level on account of the largerimportance of campaign funds in national elections and better information aboutcandidates and issues in local elections based on informal sources. On the otherhand, particularly in large heterogeneous societies, the elites are usually moredivided at the national level, with more competing and heterogeneous groupsneutralizing one another. At the local level in situations of high inequality, collu-sion may be easier to organize and enforce in small proximate groups involvingofficials, politicians, contractors and interest groups; risks of being caught andreported are easier to manage, and the multiplex interlocking social and economicrelationships among local influential people may act as formidable barriers to entryinto these cozy rental havens. At the central level in democratic countries, moreinstitutional mechanisms for checks and balances are usually at place: these includevarious constitutional forms of separation of powers and adjudicatory systems insome countries, more regular auditing of public accounts and more vigilance by

7 For one theoretical analysis of the problem, see Bardhan and Mookherjee (2000c). We argue that theoverall comparison of capture at central and local levels in a democracy would depend on the interplayof a large number of underlying institutional factors, such as relative degrees of voter awareness andcohesiveness of special interest groups, the extent of heterogeneity across districts and the nature of thenational electoral system, and so the issue is ultimately context- and system-specific.

Page 11: 089533002320951037

Pranab Bardhan 195

national media. Such mechanisms are often absent or highly ineffective at the locallevel.

Even in undemocratic but largely egalitarian societies, the problem of localcapture may be less acute. It is generally overlooked in the widely noted successstory of decentralized rural-industrial development of China over the last twodecades that the decollectivization of agriculture since 1978 represented one of theworld’s most egalitarian distributions of land cultivation rights (with the size of landcultivated by a household assigned almost always strictly in terms of its demographicsize), and this may have substantially mitigated the problem of capture of localgovernments and other institutions by the oligarchic owners of immobile factors ofproduction (like land), which afflicts other rural economies (for example, India).

When the potential for capture of local governments is serious, decentraliza-tion programs have to focus a great deal of attention to strengthening localaccountability mechanisms. In fact, in policy debates, when we consider the costsand benefits of redistributive policies (like land reforms, public health campaignsor literacy movements), we often ignore their substantial positive spillover effects interms of enlarging the stake of large numbers of the poor in the system andstrengthening the institutions of local democracy. Comparing across the variousstates in India, it is clear that local democracy and institutions of decentralizationare more effective in the states (like Kerala and West Bengal) where land reformsand mass movements for raising political awareness have been more active. The1996 National Election Survey data in India suggest that in West Bengal, 51 percentof the respondent voters expressed a high level of trust in their local government,whereas in the adjoining state of Bihar (where both land reforms and localdemocracy institutions have been very weak), the corresponding figure is 30percent (Mitra and Singh, 1999). Near-universal literacy in Kerala has helpedsustain widespread newspaper readership, which has encouraged a vigilant press onissues like corruption in local governments.

In both Kerala and West Bengal, it has also been observed that theft andcorruption at the local level are more effectively resisted if regular local elections toselect representatives in the local bodies are supplemented by an institutionalizedsystem of periodic public hearings on items of major public expenditure. But eventhat monitoring device is inadequate if the complaints made in public are notacted upon by the ruling party. There is evidence that sometimes the oppositionparties or minority factions stop attending the village council meetings or thepublic hearings, as they perceive that they cannot do much about the rulingparty’s spending of public funds that takes the form of widespread distribution ofpatronage—like “jobs for the boys,” or what Italians call lottizzazione—which some-times consolidates its electoral advantage. It is important to install public accountscommittees at the local legislative level with their leading members taken from theopposition party, as is the case at the central parliamentary committees in India orBritain. In general, the auditing process at the local level is extremely deficient, notalways by design, but by the sheer dearth in the villages of technical capacity foraccounting, record keeping and auditing.

Page 12: 089533002320951037

196 Journal of Economic Perspectives

In sum, in considering the theory of decentralization in developing countries,it is important to move beyond the traditional tradeoff of how centralization isbetter for dealing with spillovers and decentralization is better for dealing withheterogeneity. It is necessary to delve into political economy issues of institutionalprocess and accountability at both the local and central level.

Empirical Evaluation of Decentralized Delivery of Public Services

In this section, we shall indicate some of the attempts that have been made toevaluate empirically the impact of decentralization on the delivery of social servicesin developing countries. Even though decentralization experiments are going on inmany of these countries, hard quantitative evidence on their impact is ratherscarce. There are a number of scattered studies that we will arrange in terms of thenature of empirical methodology followed.

In two successful cases of decentralization in Latin America, there is someevidence available on the “before-after” comparison of service delivery outcomes.One is the widely noted case of participatory budgeting in municipal governmentin the city of Porto Alegre in Brazil; the other is the less well-known but quitedramatic success of the post-1994 decentralization initiative in Bolivia. In PortoAlegre, where assembly meetings of local citizens and neighborhood associations indifferent regions discuss investment priorities, review accounts and elect represen-tatives to a citywide council that allocates available resources across wards, impres-sive results have followed: between 1989 and 1996, access to basic sanitation (waterand sewage) as well as enrollment in elementary or secondary schools nearlydoubled, while increasing revenue collection by 48 percent (Santos, 1998). Al-though it is difficult from this study to isolate the impact of participatory budgetingreforms from those of other ongoing changes, it seems likely that there has been asubstantial impact on the pattern of resource allocation across localities, particu-larly to poor ones, and in the lessening of the misappropriation of resourcescompared to the past and to other areas in Brazil.

In Bolivia in 1994, the number of municipalities as well as the share of nationaltax revenue allocated to municipalities doubled, along with devolution to themunicipalities of administrative authority, investment responsibility and title tolocal infrastructural facilities. This change has been associated with a massive shiftof public resources in favor of the smaller and poorer municipalities and fromlarge-scale production to social sectors. Faguet (2001) finds that public investmentin education, water and sanitation rose significantly in three-quarters of all munic-ipalities, and investments responded to measures of local need; for example, theexpansion in public education spending was larger on average in municipalitieswith a lower literacy rate or with fewer private schools. Faguet’s analysis is in termsof levels of public spending, rather than outcome variables like school enrollmentsor school performance or access to water and sanitation services. In the studies ofPorto Alegre or Bolivia, not much information is available on the allocation of

Page 13: 089533002320951037

Decentralization of Governance and Development 197

resources within a community across households in different socioeconomicclasses. This means that issues like cost-effectiveness of programs, targeting perfor-mance or the extent of capture of local governments cannot be addressed. Withouthousehold-level data on access to public services, these crucial aspects of the impactof decentralization cannot be properly assessed.

There is hardly any household-level analysis in the literature of the compara-tive effects of centralized versus decentralized delivery. One detailed study oftargeting performance of a decentralized program using household-level informa-tion in a developing country is that of Galasso and Ravallion (2001) studying adecentralized food-for-education program in Bangladesh. In this central govern-ment program, in which two million children participated in 1995–1996, theidentification of beneficiary households within a selected community was madetypically by a local school management committee consisting of parents, teachers,education specialists and school donors. Galasso and Ravallion use data from a1995–1996 Household Expenditure Survey to assess the targeting performance ofthe program. They find that the program was mildly pro-poor; that is, taking allvillages, a somewhat larger fraction of the poor received benefits from the programthan did the nonpoor. They also find some evidence of local capture. For example,within the set of participating villages, targeting performance was worse in com-munities with larger land inequality or in remote locations. But the targetingimproved as the program expanded, suggesting that the program shifted thebalance of power in favor of the poor. It is also clearly the case that the level oftargeting within communities was superior to that achieved across communities bycentral allocation, thus offering little support for the view that the central govern-ment is more accountable to the poor than local communities.

This finding is in some contrast to the experience of the widely acclaimedantipoverty transfer program of Progresa in Mexico. The program follows a two-stagetargeting process. Coady (2001) finds that most of Progresa’s targeting effectivenessis achieved at the first stage when poor localities are selected, rather than in thesecond stage when households are selected within localities, not on the basis ofidentification of beneficiaries by local communities as in the food-for-educationprogram in Bangladesh, but on the basis of information collected from a censusundertaken for this purpose.

Alderman (1998) examines, on the basis of a household survey conducted in1996, a targeted social assistance program (Ndihme Ekonomika) in Albania that wasdecentralized in 1995. He finds that there have been modest gains in targetingefficiency and cost-effectiveness following decentralization, that local authoritiesuse some additional information in allocating program benefits among householdsand that the central allocation of social assistance funds to local authorities isad hoc and not strongly correlated with the level of poverty in the local commu-nities. He does not find evidence that the decentralization initiative caused thewell-off members of the community to capture the benefits of the program.

There is some quantitative evidence on the impact of mandated representa-tions of historically disadvantaged groups like women in leadership positions in

Page 14: 089533002320951037

198 Journal of Economic Perspectives

local governance in India. Since 1998, one-third of all positions of chief of thevillage councils in India have been reserved for women: only women may becandidates for the position of chief in a reserved village council, and the councilselects the latter randomly. Taking advantage of this random assignment (and thusavoiding an econometric problem in usual cross-section studies on this type ofquestion that communities that are more likely to take women’s needs into accountmay also be more willing to let them be in leadership positions), Chattopadhyayand Duflo (2001) have measured the impact of this political reservation policy onoutcomes of decentralization with data collected from a survey of all investments inlocal public goods made by village councils in one district in West Bengal. They findthat the women leaders of village councils invest more in infrastructure that isdirectly relevant to the needs of rural women, like drinking water, fuel and roads,and that village women are more likely to participate in the policymaking processif the leader of their village council is a woman. However, without direct evidenceon the nature of women’s preferences relative to men’s and since women’s reser-vation in the leadership positions in local government was not linked to thedistribution of women in the village, this study does not quite address how localdemocracy affects the ability of underrepresented groups in the village to imple-ment their desired outcomes.

Foster and Rosenzweig (2001) use a panel dataset of villages across India toexamine the consequences of democratization and fiscal decentralization. Theyfind that an increase in the demographic weight of the landless households in avillage under democratic decentralization has a positive effect on allocation ofpublic resources to road construction (which, according to them, primarily benefitsthe landless workers) and a negative effect on that to irrigation facilities (whichprimarily benefit the landed). But their dataset does not contain the many severeinstitutional lapses in the implementation of decentralization across India, partic-ularly in manipulations of the local electoral process and in the range of authorityand finances devolved to local governments, making democratic decentralizationnot yet a reality in most parts of India. It is not clear, for example, how much of aleeway elected local village councils have in matters of allocation to projects likeroad construction, which are often centrally sponsored and quite bureaucraticallycontrolled from above. At most the local government gets involved only in thedecision where to locate the road and to identify the beneficiary workers.

Some case studies also exist on the effects of decentralization in different partsof the world, which provide some descriptive and suggestive correlations, but notenough to clinch any hypothesis. Azfar, Kahkonen and Meagher (2000) surveyhouseholds and government officials at municipal and provincial levels in thePhilippines with respect to the stated public investment priorities in a given locality.Stated priorities of officials at the municipal level turned out to match weakly thoseof local residents, while those of officials at the provincial level did not, suggestingthat decentralization may improve the quality of information officials use in publicinvestment decisions. There is also some evidence in the survey of more perceivedcorruption at the central level than at the local level. A similar survey was carried

Page 15: 089533002320951037

Pranab Bardhan 199

out by Azfar, Kahkonen and Meagher in Uganda with qualitatively similar results.They also find in Uganda a greater reliance on community leaders for newsconcerning local corruption and local elections than for national news, which theyinterpret as evidence of greater potential for local capture.

In the 1990s, Nicaragua started a program of transferring key managementtasks in public schools from central authorities to local councils involving parents.An evaluation of this program by King and Ozler (1998) on the basis of school andhousehold surveys and student achievement tests suggests that de facto autonomyhas not yet been given to many of the councils, but where it has been, there is asignificant positive effect on student performance.

The World Development Report 1994 on Infrastructure cited several cases ofquality improvement and cost savings in infrastructure projects after local commu-nities were given part of the responsibility in management. A review of World Bankdata for 42 developing countries found that where road maintenance was decen-tralized, backlogs were lower and the condition of roads better. Data for a group ofdeveloping countries revealed that per capita costs of water in World Bank–fundedwater projects were four times higher in centralized than in fully decentralizedsystems. A study of 121 completed rural water supply projects, financed by variousagencies, showed that projects with high participation in project selection anddesign were much more likely to have the water supply maintained in goodcondition than would be the case with more centralized decision-making.

Wade’s (1997) contrasting account of the operations of irrigation bureaucracyin South Korea and in south India brings out the importance of local accountabilityin delivery of infrastructural services. The Indian canal systems are large, central-ized hierarchies in charge of all functions, operations and maintenance as well asdesign and construction. Their ways of operation—including the promotion andtransfer rules for officials, rules designed to minimize identification between theirrigation patrollers and the local farmers, and the frequent use of low-trustmanagement and supervision methods—and source of finance (most of the irriga-tion department’s budget comes in the form of a grant from the state treasury) areinsensitive to the need for developing local trust and cooperation. In Korea, on theother hand, there are, according to this account, functionally separate organiza-tions in the canal systems. The implementation and routine maintenance tasks (asopposed to policymaking and technical design work) are delegated to the Farm-land Improvement Associations, one per catchment area, which are staffed by localpart-time farmers selected by the village chiefs, knowledgeable about changinglocal conditions, dependent for their salary and operational budget largely on theuser fees paid by the farmers and continually drawing upon local trust relation-ships. Korea at the time of the study did not have a democratic political regime ora free press, but farmers were better informed about and had better access to thelocal irrigation organization. This example shows that there is no one-to-onerelationship between the strength of democracy at the national political level andthat of institutions of accountability at the local level.

A similar story on accountability can be told in the field of education and

Page 16: 089533002320951037

200 Journal of Economic Perspectives

health, comparing north India with some authoritarian countries. Institutions oflocal accountability are rather weak in large parts of north India, and it is commonto observe, for example, the serious problem of absenteeism of salaried teachers invillage public schools and of doctors in rural public health clinics.8 The villagers areusually aware of the problem but do not have the institutional means of correctingit, as the state-funded teachers and doctors are not answerable to the villagers in theinsufficiently decentralized system. On the other hand, in nondemocratic China,the local Communist Party officials have sometimes been quite responsive to localneeds (at least as long as they are not conflicting with the party’s program), as thecomparative study of two villages in China and India by Dreze and Saran (1995)show in the context of China’s far better performance in the provision of primaryeducation at the local level. Similar accounts are available of more effective publicpressure in rural basic education and health services in Cuba compared with someof the more democratic regimes in Latin America. There are, of course, manyauthoritarian countries where local accountability is completely absent and thesituation is much worse than in north India.

Taken as a group, these studies suggest generally positive effects of decentral-ization, but it is hard to draw conclusive lessons. Many of the studies are largelydescriptive, not analytical, and often suggest correlations rather than causal pro-cesses. Most of them are not based on household survey data, making the compar-ative impact of centralized versus decentralized programs on different socioeco-nomic groups of households difficult to assess.

Decentralization and Local Business Development

Most of the cases of decentralization in developing countries examined in thetheoretical and empirical literature relate to delivery of social services. But in recentyears, there has been an extension of the traditional literature on federalism to thecase of the role of local government in promoting local business development,particularly in the context of transition economies, especially China, and this haspotential implications for developing countries where so far public delivery issueshave been more prominent.

In Qian and Weingast (1997) and Qian and Roland (1998), for example,decentralization of information and authority and interjurisdictional competitionin China have been considered as commitment devices on the part of the centralor provincial government to provide market incentives, both the “positive” incen-tive rewarding economic success at the local level and the “negative” incentive interms of punishing economic failure. The local government-run township andvillage enterprises that served as the engine of growth in China in the last twodecades have been cited as a major example of the outcome of a successful

8 See, for example, PROBE (1999) on the basis of an intensive survey of 234 randomly selected villagesin north India carried out in 1996.

Page 17: 089533002320951037

Decentralization of Governance and Development 201

“market-preserving federalism.” In terms of positive market incentives, the town-ship and village enterprises had full control over their assets and were largely leftalone (as a residual claimant) to “get rich gloriously,” and the limited knowledge ofthe upper-tier governments about the extra-budget and off-budget accounts of localgovernments acted as check on the upper-tier interventionism. In contrast, aneconometric study of the fiscal relations between local and regional governments inRussia by Zhuravskaya (2000) on the basis of a panel dataset for 35 large cities showsthat local governments could retain only about 10 percent of their revenues at themargin, thus providing only weak incentives to foster local business developmentand thus to increase their tax base. In terms of the “negative” incentive, Chineseupper-tier governments, by denying bailout to many failing township and villageenterprises, enforced a dynamic commitment. Having no access to state banks andfacing mobility of capital across jurisdictions raised the opportunity costs of localgovernments for rescuing inefficient firms, thus leading to the endogenous emer-gence of a hard budget constraint.

Without denying the importance of these market incentives, it is possible toargue, however, that the case of market-preserving federalism is institutionallyunderspecified in these studies. Depending on the political-institutional complexin different countries, the same market incentives may have different efficacy. AsRodden and Rose-Ackerman (1997) have pointed out in a critique of market-preserving federalism, whether political leaders of a local government respond tohighly mobile investors or instead pay more attention to the demands of strongdistributive coalitions dominated by owners of less mobile factors depends on theinstitutional milieu. Owners of capital vary widely in the specificity of their assets,and institutional incentives facing political leaders may vary even for the samejurisdictional competitive pressure. Even in a democracy, not to speak of authori-tarian systems, electoral competition does not necessarily punish local leaders whofail to respond to exit threats of mobile asset owners and are instead moreresponsive to coalition building and the voice of well-organized lobbies. We havepointed out earlier the problem of local capture by the oligarchic owners ofimmobile factors of production, like land in rural India, and how in the Chinesecase, the lack of such strong rural lobbies (owing largely to the egalitarian landdistribution) may have made a difference in the local governments’ vigorouspursuit of rural industrialization.9 In Russia, many have pointed out that over muchof the 1990s, local governments have shown features of being captured by erstwhilerent-holders and old firms, which sometimes blocked the rise of new firms thatcould compete away their rents.10 Of course, even in China by some accounts (for

9 Even in India, in areas where land distribution is relatively egalitarian and local democracy is moresolidaristic, as in Kerala, there are now some instances of municipal governments taking a leading role,in collaboration with bankers and social groups, in local business development. For some examples, seeDas (2000).

10 The explanation of China’s relative success attributed to political centralization in Blanchard andShleifer (2000) does not seem very plausible. A strong central political authority can punish local
Page 18: 089533002320951037

202 Journal of Economic Perspectives

example, Shirk, 1993), local officials have often used their financial authority underdecentralization to build political machines, collecting rents in exchange of selec-tive benefits and patronage distribution, and federalism may not always have beenthat market preserving.

It seems jurisdictional competition is not enough to explain the emergence ofendogenous hard budget constraints for local governments without a lot morespecification of the local political process. Even ignoring the lobbies of landoligarchies, if a local business fails, threatening the livelihood of thousands of poorpeople, the local government (or if the latter is bankrupt, upper-tier governments)will have difficulty ignoring the political pressure that will be generated in favor ofbailing them out. Wildasin (1997) has rightly pointed out that federal grants tolocal governments may be less “soft” in the small jurisdictions as opposed to thelarge (which are “too big to fail”), but even small jurisdictions may have keypoliticians representing (or lobbying for) them—and in any case, it is cheaper tocome to their rescue.

Conclusion

It is quite plausible to argue that in the matter of service deliveries as well as inlocal business development, control rights in governance structures should beassigned to people who have the requisite information and incentives and at thesame time will bear responsibility for the (political and economic) consequences oftheir decisions. In many situations, this insight calls for more devolution of powerto local authorities and communities.

But at the same time, it is important to keep in mind that structures of localaccountability are not in place in many developing countries, and local govern-ments are often at the mercy of local power elites who may frustrate the goal ofachieving public delivery to the general populace of social services, infrastructuralfacilities and conditions conducive to local business development. This means thatdecentralization, to be really effective, has to accompany serious attempts to changethe existing structures of power within communities and to improve the opportu-nities for participation and voice and engaging the hitherto disadvantaged ordisenfranchised in the political process. After all, the logic behind decentralizationis not just about weakening the central authority, nor is it about preferring localelites to central authority, but it is fundamentally about making governance at thelocal level more responsive to the felt needs of the large majority of the population.To facilitate this, the state, far from retreating into the minimalist role of classicalliberalism, may sometimes have to play certain activist roles: enabling (if only as acatalyst) mobilization of people in local participatory development; neutralizing

governments (reducing the risk of their capture and the scope of their rent seeking), but one needs aplausible story of a benevolent nonrentier central authority to go with it.

Page 19: 089533002320951037

Pranab Bardhan 203

the power of local oligarchs; providing supralocal support in the form of pump-priming local finance; supplying technical and professional services toward build-ing local capacity; acting as a watchdog for service quality standards, evaluation andauditing; investing in larger infrastructure; and providing some coordination in theface of externalities across localities.

The literature on decentralization in the context of development is still in itsinfancy. On the theoretical side, perhaps the key challenge is to find better ways tomodel the complex organizational and incentive problems that are involved, in asituation with pervasive problems of monitoring and enforcement. On the empir-ical side, there is a great deal of scope for rigorous work in evaluating the impactof ongoing decentralization initiatives, using detailed household and communitysurveys, comparing it with the experience with centralization or some other coun-terfactual. In such empirical work, one has to be particularly wary of severaleconometric problems. One issue is that some of the data involved in evaluatingcommunity participation and project performance may be subjective. For instance,some investigators start with the prior belief that participation is good, whichcreates a “halo effect” in their observations. A second problem is one of simulta-neity: better beneficiary participation may cause improved project performance,but improved project performance often also encourages higher participation.11

Finally, there is the commonly encountered endogeneity problem. Before beingtoo quick to claim that decentralization brought about certain outcomes, it is worthconsidering that decentralization may have resulted from ongoing political andeconomic changes that also affected these same outcomes. Separating decentral-ization from its political and economic causes, so that decentralization is not just aproxy for an ill-defined broad package of social and economic reforms, is a delicatetask.

y I am grateful to Brad De Long, Timothy Taylor and Michael Waldman for editorialsuggestions and to Dilip Mookherjee for substantive discussion (and joint research) on issuesrelating to this paper.

11 For an attempt to take this latter set of econometric problems into account in an evaluation of 121rural water projects, see Isham, Narayan and Pritchett (1995).

Page 20: 089533002320951037

204 Journal of Economic Perspectives

References

Alderman, Harold. 1998. “Social Assistance inAlbania: Decentralization and Targeted Trans-fers.” LSMS Working Paper No. 134, WorldBank.

Azfar, Omar, Satu Kahkonen and PatrickMeagher. 2000. “Conditions for Effective Decen-tralized Governance: A Synthesis of ResearchFindings.” IRIS Center Working Paper, Univer-sity of Maryland.

Bardhan, Pranab and Dilip Mookherjee.2000a. “Corruption and Decentralization ofInfrastructure Delivery in Developing Coun-tries.” Working Paper, University of California,Berkeley.

Bardhan, Pranab and Dilip Mookherjee.2000b. “Decentralizing Anti-Poverty ProgramDelivery in Developing Countries.” Working Pa-per, University of California, Berkeley.

Bardhan, Pranab and Dilip Mookherjee.2000c. “Capture and Governance at Local andNational Levels.” American Economic Review. 90:2,pp. 135–39.

Besley, Timothy and Anne Case. 1995. “In-cumbent Behavior: Vote-Seeking, Tax-Settingand Yardstick Competition.” American EconomicReview. 85:1, pp. 25–45.

Besley, Timothy and Stephen Coate. 2000.“Centralized Versus Decentralized Provision ofLocal Public Goods: A Political Economy Analy-sis.” Unpublished Paper, London School ofEconomics.

Bird, Richard M. 1995. “Decentralizing Infra-structure: For Good or For Ill?” in DecentralizingInfrastructure: Advantages and Limitations. Anto-nio Estache, ed. Washington, D.C.: World BankDiscussion Papers 290, pp. 22–51.

Blanchard, Olivier and Andrei Shleifer. 2000.“Federalism With and Without Political Central-ization: China Versus Russia.” NBER WorkingPaper No. 7616.

Burki, Shahid Javed, Guillermo E. Perry andWilliam R. Dillinger. 1999. Beyond the Center: De-centralizing the State. Washington D.C.: WorldBank.

Chattopadhyay, Raghabendra and Esther Du-flo. 2001. “Women as Policy Makers: EvidenceFrom a India-Wide Randomized Policy Experi-ment.” Unpublished Paper, Massachusetts Insti-tute of Technology.

Coady, David. 2001. “An Evaluation of theDistributional Power of Progresa’s Cash Trans-fers in Mexico.” International Food Policy Re-search Institute Working Paper.

Conning, Jonathan and Michael Kevane. 2001.

“Community Based Targeting Mechanisms forSocial Safety Nets.” World Bank.

Crook, Richard and James Manor. 1998. De-mocracy and Decentralization in South Asia and WestAfrica. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Das, M. K. 2000. “Kerala’s Decentralised Plan-ning: Floundering Experiment.” Economic andPolitical Weekly. December 2, 35.

Dreze, Jean and Mrinalini Saran. 1995. “Pri-mary Education and Economic Development inChina and India: Overview and Two Case Stud-ies,” in Choice, Welfare, and Development: AFestschrift in Honour of Amartya K. Sen. K. Basu etal., eds. Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 182–241.

Estache, Antonio, ed. 1995. Decentralizing In-frastructure: Advantages and Limitations. Washing-ton, D.C.: World Bank Discussion Papers 290.

Faguet, Jean-Paul. 2001. “Does Decentraliza-tion Increase Government Responsiveness to Lo-cal Needs? Decentralization and Public Invest-ment in Bolivia.” Centre for EconomicPerformance Working Paper, London School ofEconomics.

Foster, Andrew D. and Mark R. Rosenzweig.2001. “Democratization, Decentralization andthe Distribution of Local Public Goods in a PoorRural Economy.” Unpublished Paper, Universityof Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

Galasso, Emanuela and Martin Ravallion.2001. “Decentralized Targeting of an Anti-Poverty Program.” Development ResearchGroup Working Paper, World Bank.

Hanson, Russell L. and John T. Hartman.1994. “Do Welfare Magnets Attract?” Institutefor Research on Poverty, University Wisconsin-Madison.

Isham, Jonathan, Deepa Narayan and LantPritchett. 1995. “Does Participation ImprovePerformance? Establishing Causality with Sub-jective Data.” World Bank Economic Review. 9:2,pp. 175–200.

King, Elizabeth and Berk Ozler. 1998. “What’sDecentralization Got to do with Learning? TheCase of Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Reform.”Development Research Group Working Paper,World Bank.

Mitra, Subrata K. and V. B. Singh. 1999. De-mocracy and Social Change in India: A Cross-Sectional Analysis of the National Electorate. NewDelhi: Sage Publications.

North, Douglass C. and Robert Paul Thomas.1973. The Rise of the Western World. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

Page 21: 089533002320951037

Decentralization of Governance and Development 205

Oates, Wallace. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. NewYork: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of CollectiveAction. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard UniversityPress.

PROBE. 1999. Public Report on Basic Educationfor India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Qian, Yingyi and Gerard Roland. 1998. “Fed-eralism and the Soft Budget Constraint.” Ameri-can Economic Review. 88:5, pp. 1143–162.

Qian, Yingyi and Barry R. Weingast. 1997.“Federalism as a Commitment to PreservingMarket Incentives.” Journal of Economic Perspec-tives. Fall, 11:4, pp. 83–92.

Reinikka, Ritva and Jakob Svensson. 2001.“Explaining Leakage of Public Funds.” Develop-ment Research Group Working Paper, WorldBank.

Rodden, Jonathan and Susan Rose-Ackerman.1997. “Does Federalism Preserve Markets?” Vir-ginia Law Review. 83:7, pp. 1521–572.

Santos, Boaventura de Sousa. 1998. “Partici-patory Budgeting in Porto Alegre: Toward a Re-distributive Democracy.” Politics and Society. 26:4,pp. 461–510.

Seabright, Paul. 1996. “Accountability and De-centralization in Government: An IncompleteContracts Model.” European Economic Review.40:1, pp. 61–89.

Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Eco-

nomic Reform in China. Berkeley: University ofCalifornia Press.

Stepan, Alfred and Juan J. Linz. Forthcoming.Federalism, Democracy, and Nation.

Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory ofLocal Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy.64:5, pp. 416–24.

Tommasi, Mariano and Federico Weinschel-baum. 1999. “A Principal-Agent Building Blockfor the Study of Decentralization and Integra-tion.” Mimeo, Universidad de San Andres.

Treisman, Daniel. 1999. “Political Decentral-ization and Economic Reform: A Game-TheoreticAnalysis.” American Journal of Political Science.April, 43:2, pp. 488–517.

Wade, Robert. 1997. “How InfrastructureAgencies Motivate Staff: Canal Irrigation in In-dia and the Republic of Korea,” in InfrastructureStrategies in East Asia. A. Mody, ed. Washington,D.C.: EDI, World Bank, pp. 109–30.

Wildasin, David E. 1997. “Externalities andBailouts: Hard and Soft Budget Constraints inInter-Governmental Fiscal Relations.” WorldBank Policy Research Paper No. 1843.

World Bank. 2000. Entering the Twenty-First Cen-tury. Oxford and New York: Oxford UniversityPress.

Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina V. 2000. “Incentives toProvide Local Public Goods: Fiscal Federalism,Russian Style.” Journal of Public Economics. June,76:3, pp. 337–68.

Page 22: 089533002320951037

This article has been cited by:

1. Xiaobo Lü. 2015. Intergovernmental transfers and local education provision — Evaluating China's8-7 National Plan for Poverty Reduction. China Economic Review 33, 200-211. [CrossRef]

2. Mohammed Rajeh, John E. Tookey, James Olabode Bamidele Rotimi. 2015. Estimating transactioncosts in the New Zealand construction procurement. Engineering, Construction and ArchitecturalManagement 22, 242-267. [CrossRef]

3. Kshitij Chaudhary. 2015. The effect of political decentralisation and affirmative action onMultidimensional Poverty Index: evidence from Indian States. Journal of Social and EconomicDevelopment . [CrossRef]

4. Ryan Sheely. 2015. Mobilization, Participatory Planning Institutions, and Elite Capture: Evidencefrom a Field Experiment in Rural Kenya. World Development 67, 251-266. [CrossRef]

5. Muhammad Shakil Ahmad, Noraini Bt. Abu Talib. 2015. Empowering local communities:decentralization, empowerment and community driven development. Quality & Quantity 49, 827-838.[CrossRef]

6. Cheng Yuan, Lei Zhang. 2015. Public Education Spending and Private Substitution in Urban China.Journal of Development Economics . [CrossRef]

7. Shuhai Zhang, Gert de Roo, Terry van Dijk. 2015. Urban Land Changes as the Interaction BetweenSelf-Organization and Institutions. Planning Practice & Research 1-19. [CrossRef]

8. Geoffrey J. Syme, V. Ratna Reddy, Ram RanjanJustice and Equity in Watershed Development inAndhra Pradesh 317-352. [CrossRef]

9. T. Kilic, E. Whitney, P. Winters. 2015. Decentralised Beneficiary Targeting in Large-ScaleDevelopment Programmes: Insights from the Malawi Farm Input Subsidy Programme. Journal ofAfrican Economies 24, 26-56. [CrossRef]

10. Kenneth S. Chan, Xianxiang Xu, Yuanhua Gao. 2015. The China Growth Miracle: The Role of theFormal and the Informal Institutions. The World Economy 38:10.1111/twec.2015.38.issue-1, 63-90.[CrossRef]

11. John William Hatfield. 2015. Federalism, Taxation, and Economic Growth. Journal of UrbanEconomics . [CrossRef]

12. Emilie Caldeira, Martial Foucault, Gregoire Rota-Graziosi. 2014. Decentralization in Africa and thenature of local governments’ competition: evidence from Benin. International Tax and Public Finance. [CrossRef]

13. Veronica Herrera, Alison E. Post. 2014. Can Developing Countries Both Decentralize and DepoliticizeUrban Water Services? Evaluating the Legacy of the 1990s Reform Wave. World Development 64,621-641. [CrossRef]

14. Andreas P. Kyriacou, Noemí Morral-Palacín. 2014. Secessionism and the Quality of Government:Evidence from a Sample of OECD Countries. Territory, Politics, Governance 1-18. [CrossRef]

15. Thomas Dufhues, Insa Theesfeld, Gertrud Buchenrieder. 2014. The Political Economy ofDecentralization in Thailand: How Past and Present Decentralization Affects rural Actors’Participation. European Journal of Development Research . [CrossRef]

16. Azmat Gani, Frank Scrimgeour. 2014. Modeling governance and water pollution using theinstitutional ecological economic framework. Economic Modelling 42, 363-372. [CrossRef]

17. U. Kelekar, G. Llanto. 2014. Evidence of horizontal and vertical interactions in health care spendingin the Philippines. Health Policy and Planning . [CrossRef]

18. Lucie Gadenne, Monica Singhal. 2014. Decentralization in Developing Economies. Annual Review ofEconomics 6, 581-604. [CrossRef]

Page 23: 089533002320951037

19. Sun Xiulin, Zhou Feizhou. 2014. Land Finance and the Tax-sharing System: An EmpiricalInterpretation. Social Sciences in China 35, 47-64. [CrossRef]

20. Angelo Paletta. 2014. Improving Students’ Learning Through School Autonomy: Evidence From theInternational Civic and Citizenship Survey. Journal of School Choice 8, 381-409. [CrossRef]

21. Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir, Krisztina Kis-Katos, Günther G. Schulze. 2014. AdministrativeOverspending in Indonesian Districts: The Role of Local Politics. World Development 59, 166-183.[CrossRef]

22. Guy Grossman, W. Walker Hanlon. 2014. Do Better Monitoring Institutions Increase LeadershipQuality in Community Organizations? Evidence from Uganda. American Journal of Political Science58:10.1111/ajps.2014.58.issue-3, 669-686. [CrossRef]

23. Monica Yanez-Pagans, Gustavo Machicado-Salas. 2014. Bureaucratic Delay, Local-Level Monitoring,and Delivery of Small Infrastructure Projects: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Bolivia. WorldDevelopment 59, 394-407. [CrossRef]

24. Tanya Jakimow. 2014. DECENTRALISED GOVERNANCE AS SITES FOR SELF-FORMATION: A COMPARISON OF PRACTICES OF WELFARE DISTRIBUTION INTELANGANA, INDIA, AND CENTRAL LOMBOK, INDONESIA. International Journal of AsianStudies 11, 161-185. [CrossRef]

25. Jennifer Alix-Garcia, Benjamin Cerf Harris. 2014. Inequality, Community Participation, and theAllocation of Collective Profits. Economics & Politics 26:10.1111/ecpo.2014.26.issue-2, 285-308.[CrossRef]

26. Eric A. Coleman, Scott S. Liebertz. 2014. Property Rights and Forest Commons. Journal of PolicyAnalysis and Management 33:10.1002/pam.2014.33.issue-3, 649-668. [CrossRef]

27. Katherine A. Snyder, Eva Ludi, Beth Cullen, Josephine Tucker, Alemayehu B. Zeleke, AlanDuncan. 2014. PARTICIPATION AND PERFORMANCE: DECENTRALISED PLANNINGAND IMPLEMENTATION IN ETHIOPIA. Public Administration and Development 34:10.1002/pad.v34.2, 83-95. [CrossRef]

28. Jennifer T. Lai, Erin P. K. So, Isabel K. M. Yan. 2014. Intergovernmental Fiscal Arrangements andProvincial Consumption Risk Sharing in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 50, 45-58.[CrossRef]

29. Jetske A. Bouma, K.J. Joy, Suhas Paranjape, Erik Ansink. 2014. The Influence of LegitimacyPerceptions on Cooperation – A Framed Field Experiment. World Development 57, 127-137.[CrossRef]

30. Agnese Sacchi, Simone Salotti. 2014. A Comprehensive Analysis of Expenditure Decentralization andof the Composition of Local Public Spending. Regional Studies 1-17. [CrossRef]

31. Gordon C. Shen, Victoria Y. Fan. 2014. China's provincial diplomacy to Africa: applications to healthcooperation. Contemporary Politics 20, 182-208. [CrossRef]

32. Benjamin Chemouni. 2014. Explaining the design of the Rwandan decentralization: elite vulnerabilityand the territorial repartition of power. Journal of Eastern African Studies 8, 246-262. [CrossRef]

33. Andreas P. Kyriacou, Oriol Roca-Sagalés. 2014. Regional Disparities and Government Quality:Redistributive Conflict Crowds Out Good Government. Spatial Economic Analysis 9, 183-201.[CrossRef]

34. Myra Pong. 2014. State-Dominated Civil Society and Migrant Children's Education in Beijing. IDSBulletin 45:10.1111/idsb.2014.45.issue-2-3, 70-82. [CrossRef]

35. Chu Thai Hoanh, Diana Suhardiman, Le Tuan Anh. 2014. Irrigation development in the VietnameseMekong Delta: Towards polycentric water governance?. International Journal of Water Governance 2,61-82. [CrossRef]

Page 24: 089533002320951037

36. Lauren Duquette-Rury. 2014. Collective Remittances and Transnational Coproduction: the 3 × 1Program for Migrants and Household Access to Public Goods in Mexico. Studies in ComparativeInternational Development 49, 112-139. [CrossRef]

37. Ren Mu, Xiaobo Zhang. 2014. Do elected leaders in a limited democracy have real power? Evidencefrom rural China. Journal of Development Economics 107, 17-27. [CrossRef]

38. Jean-Paul Faguet. 2014. Decentralization and Governance. World Development 53, 2-13. [CrossRef]39. Mayling Birney. 2014. Decentralization and Veiled Corruption under China’s “Rule of Mandates”.

World Development 53, 55-67. [CrossRef]40. Herland Tejerina, Marie-Christine Closon, Pierre De Paepe, Christian Darras, Patrick Van Dessel,

Jean-Pierre Unger. 2014. Forty years of USAID health cooperation in Bolivia. A lose-lose game?. TheInternational Journal of Health Planning and Management 29:10.1002/hpm.v29.1, 90-107. [CrossRef]

41. Lauren Persha, Krister Andersson. 2014. Elite capture risk and mitigation in decentralized forestgovernance regimes. Global Environmental Change 24, 265-276. [CrossRef]

42. Marcela González Rivas. 2014. Decentralization, community participation, and improvement of wateraccess in Mexico. Community Development 45, 2-16. [CrossRef]

43. Yang Song. 2013. Rising Chinese regional income inequality: The role of fiscal decentralization. ChinaEconomic Review 27, 294-309. [CrossRef]

44. W. F. Vasquez. 2013. A Hedonic Valuation of Residential Water Services. Applied Economic Perspectivesand Policy 35, 661-678. [CrossRef]

45. Syed Ainuddin, Daniel P. Aldrich, Jayant K. Routray, Shabana Ainuddin, Abida Achkazai. 2013.The need for local involvement: Decentralization of disaster management institutions in Baluchistan,Pakistan. International Journal of Disaster Risk Reduction 6, 50-58. [CrossRef]

46. Cristina Boţa-Avram. 2013. Linking Governance to Efficacy of Corporate Boards: A GlobalPerspective. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 99, 1073-1081. [CrossRef]

47. William F. Vásquez, Dina Franceschi. 2013. System Reliability and Water Service Decentralization:Investigating Household Preferences in Nicaragua. Water Resources Management 27, 4913-4926.[CrossRef]

48. Cristina Boţa-Avram. 2013. Empirical Analysis of Effects of Country-level Governance to Strengthof Investor Protection. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 99, 1063-1072. [CrossRef]

49. Seong-Jin Choi, Nan Jia, Jiangyong Lu. 2013. The Structure of Political Institutions and Effectivenessof Corporate Political Lobbying. Organization Science 141223041331004. [CrossRef]

50. Jan Fałkowski. 2013. Political accountability and governance in rural areas: Some evidence from thePilot Programme LEADER+ in Poland. Journal of Rural Studies 32, 70-79. [CrossRef]

51. NORMAN GEMMELL, RICHARD KNELLER, ISMAEL SANZ. 2013. FISCALDECENTRALIZATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: SPENDING VERSUS REVENUEDECENTRALIZATION. Economic Inquiry 51:10.1111/ecin.2013.51.issue-4, 1915-1931.[CrossRef]

52. Norman V. Loayza, Jamele Rigolini, Oscar Calvo-González. 2013. More Than You Can Handle:Decentralization and Spending Ability of Peruvian Municipalities. Economics & Politics n/a-n/a.[CrossRef]

53. William F. Vásquez. 2013. An economic valuation of water connections under different approaches ofservice governance. Water Resources and Economics 2-3, 17-29. [CrossRef]

54. Mark Lubell, Jurian Edelenbos. 2013. Integrated Water Resources Management: A ComparativeLaboratory for Water Governance. International Journal of Water Governance 1, 177-196. [CrossRef]

Page 25: 089533002320951037

55. David K. Leonard, Gerald Bloom, Kara Hanson, Juan O’Farrell, Neil Spicer. 2013. InstitutionalSolutions to the Asymmetric Information Problem in Health and Development Services for the Poor.World Development 48, 71-87. [CrossRef]

56. Azmat Gani, Almukhtar Saif Al-Abri. 2013. Indicators of business environment, institutional qualityand foreign direct investment in Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries. International Review ofApplied Economics 27, 515-530. [CrossRef]

57. City–State Relationships and City Charters 7-22. [CrossRef]58. W.H. Erik de Man. 2013. Thinking Outside the Disciplinary Box in Coping with Dilemmas in

Geoinformation Management for Public Policy. Transactions in GIS 17:10.1111/tgis.2013.17.issue-3,452-462. [CrossRef]

59. Antonio M. Bento. 2013. Equity Impacts of Environmental Policy. Annual Review of ResourceEconomics 5, 181-196. [CrossRef]

60. Stefan Brehm. 2013. Fiscal Incentives, Public Spending, and Productivity – County-Level Evidencefrom a Chinese Province. World Development 46, 92-103. [CrossRef]

61. Chengfang Liu, Linxiu Zhang, Jikun Huang, Renfu Luo, Hongmei Yi, Yaojiang Shi, Scott Rozelle.2013. Project design, village governance and infrastructure quality in rural China. China AgriculturalEconomic Review 5, 248-280. [CrossRef]

62. Caleb Gallemore, Darla K. Munroe. 2013. Centralization in the global avoided deforestationcollaboration network. Global Environmental Change . [CrossRef]

63. Liam Wren-Lewis. 2013. Commitment in utility regulation: A model of reputation and policyapplications. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 89, 210-231. [CrossRef]

64. Yinghua Jin, Leng Ling, Hongfeng Peng, Pingping Song. 2013. Fiscal Decentralization andHorizontal Fiscal Inequality in China. Chinese Economy 46, 6-22. [CrossRef]

65. Insa Theesfeld, Christian Schleyer. 2013. Germany's Light Version of Integrated Water ResourcesManagement. Environmental Policy and Governance 23:10.1002/eet.v23.2, 130-144. [CrossRef]

66. Li Han. 2013. Is centralized teacher deployment more equitable? Evidence from rural China. ChinaEconomic Review 24, 65-76. [CrossRef]

67. Ling Wu. 2013. Decentralization and hukou reforms in China. Policy and Society 32, 33-42. [CrossRef]68. Jelle Hoff, Mieke Cardol, Roland Friele. 2013. Why Does Citizens' Knowledge of New Policy

Vary Between Municipalities? The Case of the Social Support Act. Local Government Studies 1-17.[CrossRef]

69. Paul Niehaus,, Antonia Atanassova,, Marianne Bertrand,, Sendhil Mullainathan. 2013. Targeting withAgents. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 5:1, 206-238. [Abstract] [View PDF article][PDF with links]

70. Malini Nair, N. H. Ravindranath, Nitasha Sharma, Ruth Kattumuri, Madhushree Munshi. 2013.Poverty index as a tool for adaptation intervention to climate change in northeast India. Climate andDevelopment 1-19. [CrossRef]

71. John William Hatfield, Katrina Kosec. 2013. Federal competition and economic growth. Journal ofPublic Economics 97, 144-159. [CrossRef]

72. Mark Minnery, Eliana Jimenez-Soto, Sonja Firth, Kim-Huong Nguyen, Andrew Hodge. 2013.Disparities in child mortality trends in two new states of India. BMC Public Health 13, 779. [CrossRef]

73. Johanna Speer. 2012. Participatory Governance Reform: A Good Strategy for Increasing GovernmentResponsiveness and Improving Public Services?. World Development 40, 2379-2398. [CrossRef]

Page 26: 089533002320951037

74. Christian Leßmann, Gunther Markwardt. 2012. Föderalismus und Entwicklungsländer:Ist Dezentralisierung ein geeignetes Instrument der Entwicklungspolitik?. Perspektiven derWirtschaftspolitik 13:10.1111/pers.2012.13.issue-4, 337-356. [CrossRef]

75. Upasna Sharma, Anna Scolobig, Anthony Patt. 2012. The effects of decentralization on theproduction and use of risk assessment: insights from landslide management in India and Italy. NaturalHazards 64, 1357-1371. [CrossRef]

76. Radu Ban, Saumitra Jha, Vijayendra Rao. 2012. Who has voice in a deliberative democracy? Evidencefrom transcripts of village parliaments in south India. Journal of Development Economics 99, 428-438.[CrossRef]

77. K. Casey, R. Glennerster, E. Miguel. 2012. Reshaping Institutions: Evidence on Aid Impacts Usinga Preanalysis Plan. The Quarterly Journal of Economics . [CrossRef]

78. Christian Lessmann, Gunther Markwardt. 2012. Aid, Growth and Devolution. World Development40, 1723-1749. [CrossRef]

79. Shih-Ying Wu, Mei-Jane Teng. 2012. Fiscal decentralization and multinational firms’ ownership:evidence from China. Economics of Governance 13, 237-262. [CrossRef]

80. Alain de Janvry, Frederico Finan, Elisabeth Sadoulet. 2012. Local Electoral Incentives andDecentralized Program Performance. Review of Economics and Statistics 94, 672-685. [CrossRef]

81. Mahdi Kolahi, Tetsuro Sakai, Kazuyuki Moriya, Majid F. Makhdoum. 2012. Challenges to the FutureDevelopment of Iran’s Protected Areas System. Environmental Management . [CrossRef]

82. Piyawadee Rohitarachoon, Farhad Hossain. 2012. Decentralized Recruitment and Selection inThailand: Friend or Foe to Local Public Administration?. International Journal of PublicAdministration 35, 553-561. [CrossRef]

83. Joseph J. Capuno, Marian Panganiban. 2012. The ties that do not bind: party affiliations and thedelivery of devolved health services in the Philippines. Philippine Political Science Journal 33, 63-80.[CrossRef]

84. Nidhi Khattri, Cristina Ling, Shreyasi Jha. 2012. The effects of school-based management in thePhilippines: an initial assessment using administrative data. Journal of Development Effectiveness 4,277-295. [CrossRef]

85. Antonio Lecuna. 2012. CORRUPTION AND SIZE DECENTRALIZATION. Journal of AppliedEconomics 15, 139-168. [CrossRef]

86. Kaliappa Kalirajan, Keijiro Otsuka. 2012. Fiscal Decentralization and Development Outcomes in India:An Exploratory Analysis. World Development . [CrossRef]

87. Roger C.K. Chan 陈陈陈, Shi Xian 陈陈. 2012. Assessing the incentives in regional city-to-citycooperation: A case study of Jiangyin-Jingjiang Industrial Park of Jiangsu Province in the YangtzeRiver Delta region1 陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈-陈陈陈陈陈陈陈陈. Asia Pacific Viewpoint 53:10.1111/apv.2012.53.issue-1, 56-69. [CrossRef]

88. José Edgardo Abaya Gomez, Krishna Viuya Buenaventura. 2012. Fields of Gold: Empowering LocalOfficials to Catalyse Rural-to-urban Development in Tarlac Province, The Philippines. Space andPolity 16, 29-47. [CrossRef]

89. Latika Chaudhary, Aldo Musacchio, Steven Nafziger, Se Yan. 2012. Big BRICs, weak foundations:The beginning of public elementary education in Brazil, Russia, India, and China. Explorations inEconomic History 49, 221-240. [CrossRef]

90. Asha Ghosh, Lalitha Kamath. 2012. Decentralisation and Local Government Innovation in ProvidingUrban Services for the Poor in South and South-east Asia. Space and Polity 16, 49-71. [CrossRef]

91. E. Caldeira. 2012. Does the System of Allocation of Intergovernmental Transfers in Senegal EliminatePolitically Motivated Targeting?. Journal of African Economies 21, 167-191. [CrossRef]

Page 27: 089533002320951037

92. Tewodaj Mogues, Samuel Benin. 2012. Do External Grants to District Governments Discourage OwnRevenue Generation? A Look at Local Public Finance Dynamics in Ghana. World Development .[CrossRef]

93. Arun Agarwal, Nicolas Perrin, Ashwini Chhatre, Catherine S. Benson, Minna Kononen. 2012.Climate policy processes, local institutions, and adaptation actions: mechanisms of translation andinfluence. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Climate Change n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]

94. Noore Alam Siddiquee, Dian Nastiti, Nur Ana Sejati. 2012. Regional Autonomy and Local ResourceMobilization in Eastern Indonesia: Problems and Pitfalls of Fiscal Decentralization. Asian Affairs: AnAmerican Review 39, 44-68. [CrossRef]

95. Ruixue Jia, Pinghan LiangDecentralization and Military Coups 149-170. [CrossRef]96. References 249-265. [CrossRef]97. Chenggang Xu. 2011. The Fundamental Institutions of China's Reforms and Development. Journal

of Economic Literature 49:4, 1076-1151. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]98. Giorgia Giovannetti, Arjan de Haan, Rachel Sabates-Wheeler, Marco Sanfilippo. 2011. Successes

in social protection: what lessons can be learned?. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revuecanadienne d'études du développement 32, 439-453. [CrossRef]

99. Mahtab Ahmad, M. M. Ahmad. 2011. Do public representatives in local governments know about“disability rights” in Pakistan? An awareness assessment case from Southern Punjab. Innovation: TheEuropean Journal of Social Science Research 24, 409-426. [CrossRef]

100. Acheampong Yaw Amoateng, Ishmael Kalule-Sabiti. 2011. Local governance and spatial distributionof resources: The need to harness traditional leadership for service delivery in South Africa.International Journal of African Renaissance Studies - Multi-, Inter- and Transdisciplinarity 6, 36-54.[CrossRef]

101. Katsushi S Imai, Takahiro Sato. 2011. Decentralization, Democracy and Allocation of PovertyAlleviation Programmes in Rural India. European Journal of Development Research . [CrossRef]

102. Benjamin A. Olken,, Monica Singhal. 2011. Informal Taxation. American Economic Journal: AppliedEconomics 3:4, 1-28. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]

103. Doug Porter, Matt Andrews, Joel A. Turkewitz, Clay G. Wescott. 2011. Managing Public Financeand Procurement in Fragile and Conflicted Settings. International Public Management Journal 14,369-394. [CrossRef]

104. William F. Vásquez, Dina Franceschi, Gert T. Van Hecken. 2011. Household preferences for municipalwater services in Nicaragua. Environment and Development Economics 1-21. [CrossRef]

105. John M. Anderies, Marco A. Janssen. 2011. The fragility of robust social-ecological systems. GlobalEnvironmental Change . [CrossRef]

106. Ragnhild L. Muriaas. 2011. Traditional Institutions and Decentralisation: A Typology of Co‐Existence in Sub‐Saharan Africa. Forum for Development Studies 38, 87-107. [CrossRef]

107. Melani Claire Cammett, Lauren M. MacLean. 2011. Introduction: the Political Consequences ofNon-state Social Welfare in the Global South. Studies in Comparative International Development 46,1-21. [CrossRef]

108. HONGMEI YI, DENISE HARE, LINXIU ZHANG. 2011. DOES THE PROVISION OF PUBLICGOODS CORRESPOND TO LOCAL DEMAND?. Contemporary Economic Policy 29:10.1111/coep.2011.29.issue-1, 115-137. [CrossRef]

109. Kristin Komives. 2011. Institutionalizing Social Accountability? Participation and the PRS Process inBolivia, Honduras and Nicaragua. European Journal of Development Research 23:2, 302. [CrossRef]

110. Patrick Huntjens, Claudia Pahl-Wostl, John Grin. 2010. Climate change adaptation in European riverbasins. Regional Environmental Change 10, 263-284. [CrossRef]

Page 28: 089533002320951037

111. Dolly Daftary. 2010. Elected Leaders, Community and Development: Evidence on Distribution andAgency from a Case in India. Journal of Development Studies 46, 1692-1707. [CrossRef]

112. Enru Wang. 2010. Fiscal Decentralization and Revenue/Expenditure Disparities in China. EurasianGeography and Economics 51, 744-766. [CrossRef]

113. Waheduzzaman. 2010. Value of people's participation for good governance in developing countries.Transforming Government: People, Process and Policy 4, 386-402. [CrossRef]

114. Y.-L. Cheung, P. R. Rau, A. Stouraitis. 2010. Helping Hand or Grabbing Hand? Central vs. LocalGovernment Shareholders in Chinese Listed Firms. Review of Finance 14, 669-694. [CrossRef]

115. Christopher Rees, Farhad Hossain. 2010. Perspectives on Decentralization and Local Governance inDeveloping and Transitional Countries. International Journal of Public Administration 33, 581-587.[CrossRef]

116. Anurag Priyadarshee, Farhad Hossain. 2010. Decentralisation, Service Delivery, and People'sPerspectives: Empirical Observations on Selected Social Protection Programs in India. InternationalJournal of Public Administration 33, 752-766. [CrossRef]

117. DARIUS TIRTOSUHARTO. 2010. THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION ANDSTATE ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY ON REGIONAL GROWTH IN INDONESIA. Journal ofInternational Commerce, Economics and Policy 01, 287-307. [CrossRef]

118. Mikael Priks. 2010. Competition among officials and the abuse of power. Public Choice . [CrossRef]119. Arturo Vargas Bustamante. 2010. The tradeoff between centralized and decentralized health services:

Evidence from rural areas in Mexico. Social Science & Medicine 71, 925-934. [CrossRef]120. Klaus Abbink, Matthew Ellman. 2010. The Donor Problem: An Experimental Analysis of Beneficiary

Empowerment. Journal of Development Studies 46, 1327-1344. [CrossRef]121. A. Rodriguez-Pose, R. Ezcurra. 2010. Does decentralization matter for regional disparities? A cross-

country analysis. Journal of Economic Geography 10, 619-644. [CrossRef]122. Tobin Im. 2010. Does Decentralization Reform Always Increase Economic Growth?: A Cross

Country Comparison of the Performance. International Journal of Public Administration 33, 508-520.[CrossRef]

123. Pulak Mishra, Bhagirath Behera, Narayan Chandra Nayak. 2010. A Development Delivery Institutionfor the Tribal Communities: Experience of the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme inIndia. Development Policy Review 28, 457-479. [CrossRef]

124. 2010. Book Reviews. Journal of Economic Literature 48:2, 456-471. [Citation] [View PDF article][PDF with links]

125. 2010. Book Reviews. Journal of Economic Literature 48:2, 464-466. [Abstract] [View PDF article][PDF with links]

126. 2010. Book Reviews. Journal of Economic Literature 48:2, 462-464. [Abstract] [View PDF article][PDF with links]

127. Rupert Hodder. 2010. Informality in the Philippine Civil Service. Asian Studies Review 34, 231-251.[CrossRef]

128. BENJAMIN A. OLKEN. 2010. Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods: Evidence from a FieldExperiment in Indonesia. American Political Science Review 104, 243-267. [CrossRef]

129. Fernando Toboso, Eric Scorsone. 2010. How Much Power to Tax do Regional Governments Enjoyin Spain Since the 1996 and 2001 Reforms?. Regional & Federal Studies 20, 157-174. [CrossRef]

130. Francisco A Gallego. 2010. Historical Origins of Schooling: The Role of Democracy and PoliticalDecentralization. Review of Economics and Statistics 92, 228-243. [CrossRef]

Page 29: 089533002320951037

131. ARJAN H. SCHAKEL. 2010. Explaining Regional and Local Government: An Empirical Test ofthe Decentralization Theorem. Governance 23:10.1111/gove.2010.23.issue-2, 331-355. [CrossRef]

132. Muhammad Shakil Ahmad, Noraini Bt. Abu Talib. 2010. Decentralization initiatives, Economic andCommunity Development in Pakistan. International Journal of Trade, Economics and Finance 380-386.[CrossRef]

133. Jose Orville Solon, Raul Fabella, Joseph Capuno. 2009. Is Local Development Good Politics? LocalDevelopment Expenditures and the Re-Election of Governors in the Philippines in the 1990s. AsianJournal of Political Science 17, 265-284. [CrossRef]

134. ADRIAAN BEDNER. 2009. Consequences of Decentralization: Environmental Impact Assessmentand Water Pollution Control in Indonesia. Law & Policy . [CrossRef]

135. Syed Mansoob Murshed, Mohammad Zulfan Tadjoeddin, Anis Chowdhury. 2009. Is FiscalDecentralization Conflict Abating? Routine Violence and District Level Government in Java,Indonesia. Oxford Development Studies 37, 397-421. [CrossRef]

136. John Mcpeak, Cheryl Doss, Christopher Barrett, Patti Kristjanson. 2009. Do Community MembersShare Development Priorities? Results of a Ranking Exercise in East African Rangelands. Journal ofDevelopment Studies 45, 1663-1683. [CrossRef]

137. Ben D'Exelle. 2009. Excluded Again: Village Politics at the Aid Interface. Journal of DevelopmentStudies 45, 1453-1471. [CrossRef]

138. C. R. Hankla. 2009. When is Fiscal Decentralization Good for Governance?. Publius: The Journal ofFederalism 39, 632-650. [CrossRef]

139. Priyanka Pandey, Sangeeta Goyal, Venkatesh Sundararaman. 2009. Community participation in publicschools: impact of information campaigns in three Indian states. Education Economics 17, 355-375.[CrossRef]

140. ANDRÉS RODRÍGUEZ-POSE, ANNE KRØIJER. 2009. Fiscal Decentralization and EconomicGrowth in Central and Eastern Europe. Growth and Change 40:10.1111/grow.2009.40.issue-3,387-417. [CrossRef]

141. Karen T. Fisher. 2009. Urban water supply and local neoliberalism in Tagbilaran City, the Philippines.Asia Pacific Viewpoint 50:10.1111/apv.2009.50.issue-2, 185-197. [CrossRef]

142. Jing Vivian Zhan. 2009. Undermining State Capacity: Vertical and Horizontal Diffusions of FiscalPower in China. Asian Politics & Policy 1:10.1111/aspp.2009.1.issue-3, 390-408. [CrossRef]

143. NOBUO AKAI, MASAYO HOSOI, YUKIHIRO NISHIMURA. 2009. FISCALDECENTRALIZATION AND ECONOMIC VOLATILITY: EVIDENCE FROM STATE-LEVEL CROSS-SECTION DATA OF THE USA. Japanese Economic Review 60:10.1111/jere.2009.60.issue-2, 223-235. [CrossRef]

144. Barry R. Weingast. 2009. Second generation fiscal federalism: The implications of fiscal incentives.Journal of Urban Economics 65, 279-293. [CrossRef]

145. Benedict S. Jimenez. 2009. Anatomy of Autonomy: Assessing the Organizational Capacity andExternal Environment of the Autonomous Region in Muslim Mindanao. Asian Politics & Policy1:10.1111/aspp.2009.1.issue-2, 282-306. [CrossRef]

146. Azmat Gani. 2009. Governance and foreign aid in Pacific Island countries. Journal of InternationalDevelopment 21:10.1002/jid.v21:1, 112-125. [CrossRef]

147. Azmat Gani, Biman Chand Prasad. 2008. The relationship between institutional quality and trade inPacific Island countries. Journal of International Trade Law and Policy 7, 123-138. [CrossRef]

148. Jean-Pierre Tranchant. 2008. Fiscal decentralisation, institutional quality and ethnic conflict: A paneldata analysis, 1985–2001. Conflict, Security & Development 8, 491-514. [CrossRef]

Page 30: 089533002320951037

149. Krister Andersson, Clark C. Gibson. 2008. Decentralized governance and environmental change:Local institutional moderation of deforestation in Bolivia. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management26:10.1002/pam.v26:1, 99-123. [CrossRef]

150. Anne M. Larson, Fernanda Soto. 2008. Decentralization of Natural Resource Governance Regimes.Annual Review of Environment and Resources 33, 213-239. [CrossRef]

151. M. Ravallion. 2008. Decentralizing Eligibility for a Federal Antipoverty Program: A Case Study forChina. The World Bank Economic Review 23, 1-30. [CrossRef]

152. Shadiullah Khan. 2008. Local Governments and Local Elites. Local Government Studies 34, 509-528.[CrossRef]

153. Hal HILL. 2008. Globalization, Inequality, and Local-level Dynamics: Indonesia and the Philippines.Asian Economic Policy Review 3:10.1111/aepr.2008.3.issue-1, 42-61. [CrossRef]

154. Iwan J Azis. 2008. INSTITUTIONAL CONSTRAINTS AND MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA INDECENTRALIZATION. Review of Urban & Regional Development Studies 20, 22-33. [CrossRef]

155. Mieke Meurs. 2008. Decentralisation and development in post-socialism: local characteristics andoutcomes in post-socialist Bulgaria. Post-Communist Economies 20, 11-32. [CrossRef]

156. Yasuyuki Sawada. 2007. The impact of natural and manmade disasters on household welfare.Agricultural Economics 37, 59-73. [CrossRef]

157. Nicola Gennaioli, Ilia Rainer. 2007. The modern impact of precolonial centralization in Africa. Journalof Economic Growth 12, 185-234. [CrossRef]

158. Kenneth Broad, Alexander Pfaff, Renzo Taddei, A. Sankarasubramanian, Upmanu Lall, Franciso deAssis de Souza Filho. 2007. Climate, stream flow prediction and water management in northeastBrazil: societal trends and forecast value. Climatic Change 84, 217-239. [CrossRef]

159. Nobuo Akai, Yukihiro Nishimura, Masayo Sakata. 2007. Complementarity, fiscal decentralization andeconomic growth. Economics of Governance 8, 339-362. [CrossRef]

160. Azmat Gani, Ron Duncan. 2007. Measuring Good Governance Using Time Series Data: Fiji Islands.Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 12, 367-385. [CrossRef]

161. Azmat Gani. 2007. Governance and foreign direct investment links: evidence from panel dataestimations. Applied Economics Letters 14, 753-756. [CrossRef]

162. Tom De Herdt, Séverin Abega. 2007. The Political Complexity of Pro-poor Policy Processes in theMandara Mountains, Cameroon. Journal of Human Development 8, 303-323. [CrossRef]

163. Roberta Benini, Adam Czyzewski. 2007. Regional disparities and economic growth in Russia: newgrowth patterns and catching up. Economic Change and Restructuring 40, 91-135. [CrossRef]

164. LILY L. TSAI. 2007. Solidary Groups, Informal Accountability, and Local Public Goods Provisionin Rural China. American Political Science Review 101. . [CrossRef]

165. Henglong Zhang, Xian Chen. 2007. Fiscal competition and the structure of local public expenditurein China. Frontiers of Economics in China 2, 237-249. [CrossRef]

166. Aniruddha Dasgupta, Victoria A. Beard. 2007. Community Driven Development, Collective Actionand Elite Capture in Indonesia. Development and Change 38:10.1111/dech.2007.38.issue-2, 229-249.[CrossRef]

167. Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. 2007. Whither Russia? A Review of Andrei Shleifer's A Normal Country.Journal of Economic Literature 45:1, 127-146. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]

168. Maxime Lebovics. 2007. Analyse des apports et des contraintes du développement participatif. Afriquecontemporaine 223-224, 403. [CrossRef]

169. Abhijit Banerjee, Lakshmi Iyer, Rohini SomanathanChapter 49 Public Action for Public Goods3117-3154. [CrossRef]

Page 31: 089533002320951037

170. Joan Costa-Font, Ana Rico. 2006. Devolution and the Interregional Inequalities in Health andHealthcare in Spain. Regional Studies 40, 875-887. [CrossRef]

171. Maria Carmen Lemos, Arun Agrawal. 2006. Environmental Governance. Annual Review ofEnvironment and Resources 31, 297-325. [CrossRef]

172. YUKIHIRO NISHIMURA. 2006. Human Fallibility, Complementarity, and Fiscal Decentralization.Journal of Public Economic Theory 8:10.1111/jpet.2006.8.issue-3, 487-501. [CrossRef]

173. P BARDHAN, D MOOKHERJEE. 2006. Pro-poor targeting and accountability of local governmentsin West Bengal. Journal of Development Economics 79, 303-327. [CrossRef]

174. Santosh Mehrotra. 2006. Governance and basic social services: ensuring accountability in servicedelivery through deep democratic decentralization. Journal of International Development 18:10.1002/jid.v18:2, 263-283. [CrossRef]

175. Pranab Bardhan, Dilip Mookherjee. 2006. Decentralisation and Accountability in InfrastructureDelivery in Developing Countries*. The Economic Journal 116:10.1111/ecoj.2006.116.issue-508,101-127. [CrossRef]

176. Ross Williams. 2005. Fiscal Federalism: Aims, Instruments and Outcomes. The Australian EconomicReview 38:10.1111/aere.2005.38.issue-4, 351-369. [CrossRef]

177. Elio Londero. 2005. 'Market Discipline', Lending Ceilings and Subnational Finance. Kyklos58:10.1111/kykl.2005.58.issue-4, 575-590. [CrossRef]

178. Blane D. Lewis. 2005. Indonesian Local Government Spending, Taxing and Saving: AnExplanation of Pre- and Post-decentralization Fiscal Outcomes*. Asian Economic Journal 19:10.1111/asej.2005.19.issue-3, 291-317. [CrossRef]

179. Fitria Fitrani, Bert Hofman, Kai Kaiser. 2005. Unity in diversity? The creation of new localgovernments in a decentralising Indonesia. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 41, 57-79.[CrossRef]

180. Timothy Besley, Rohini Pande, Vijayendra Rao. 2005. Participatory Democracy in Action:Survey Evidence from South India. Journal of the European Economic Association 3:10.1162/jeea.2005.3.issue-2-3, 648-657. [CrossRef]

181. Omotunde E. G. Johnson. 2005. Addressing Ethnicity in Sub-Saharan Africa: Institutions andAgency. Constitutional Political Economy 16, 49-69. [CrossRef]

182. 2005. Book Reviews. Development and Change 36:10.1111/dech.2005.36.issue-2, 405-421. [CrossRef]183. Alberto Alesina, Enrico Spolaore, Romain WacziargTrade, Growth and the Size of Countries

1499-1542. [CrossRef]184. Maria A Albino-War, Raju Jan Singh, Ehtisham Ahmad. 2005. Subnational Public Financial

Management: Institutions and Macroeconomic Considerations. IMF Working Papers 05, 1.[CrossRef]

185. Jean-Philippe Platteau. 2004. Monitoring Elite Capture in Community-Driven Development.Development and Change 35:10.1111/dech.2004.35.issue-2, 223-246. [CrossRef]

186. Bert Hofman, Kai Kaiser, Günther G Schulze. 2004. Dezentralisierung und Korruption – ErsteErfahrungen aus Indonesien. Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung 73, 226-246. [CrossRef]

187. Indira RajaramanTaxing Agriculture in a Developing Country: A Possible Approach 245-268.[CrossRef]

188. Sharma Shalendra D.. 2003. India's Gradualist Road to Economic Liberalization: Achievements andChallenges. Journal of East Asian Economic Integration 7, 209-237. [CrossRef]

189. Lars P Feld, Horst Zimmermann, Thomas Döring. 2003. Föderalismus, Dezentralität undWirtschaftswachstum. Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung 72, 361-377. [CrossRef]

Page 32: 089533002320951037

190. Jean-Philippe Platteau. 2003. Efficacité de l'aide et développement décentralisé. Reflets et perspectivesde la vie économique XLII, 21. [CrossRef]

191. Zamira DzhusupovaEnabling Democratic Local Governance through Rural E-Municipalities inKyrgyzstan 1009-1033. [CrossRef]

192. D. Brent EdwardsThe Approach of the World Bank to Participation in Development and EducationGovernance: Trajectories, Frameworks, Results 249-273. [CrossRef]