© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior.

87
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior

Transcript of © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.

25 Monopoly Behavior

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2

How Should a Monopoly Price?

So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price to every customer. This is uniform pricing.

Can price-discrimination earn a monopoly higher profits?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3

Types of Price Discrimination

1st-degree: Each output unit is sold at a different price. Prices may differ across buyers.

2nd-degree: The price paid by a buyer can vary with the quantity demanded by the buyer. But all customers face the same price schedule. E.g., bulk-buying discounts.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4

Types of Price Discrimination

3rd-degree: Price paid by buyers in a given group is the same for all units purchased. But price may differ across buyer groups.E.g., senior citizen and student discounts vs. no discounts for middle-aged persons.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 5

First-degree Price Discrimination

Each output unit is sold at a different price. Price may differ across buyers.

It requires that the monopolist can discover the buyer with the highest valuation of its product, the buyer with the next highest valuation, and so on.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 6

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

p y( )

Sell the th unit for $y p y( ).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 7

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

p y( )

y

p y( )

Sell the th unit for $ Later onsell the th unit for $

y p y( ).y p y( ).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 8

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

p y( )

y y

p y( )

p y( )

Sell the th unit for $ Later onsell the th unit for $ Finally sell the th unit for marginal cost, $

y p y( ).y p y( ).

yp y( ).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 9

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

p y( )

y y

p y( )

p y( )

The gains to the monopoliston these trades are:

and zero.p y MC y p y MC y( ) ( ), ( ) ( )

The consumers’ gains are zero.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 10

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

So the sum of the gains tothe monopolist on all trades is the maximumpossible total gains-to-trade.

PS

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 11

First-degree Price Discrimination

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

The monopolist gets the maximum possible gains from trade.

PS

First-degree price discriminationis Pareto-efficient.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 12

First-degree Price Discrimination

First-degree price discrimination gives a monopolist all of the possible gains-to-trade, leaves the buyers with zero surplus, and supplies the efficient amount of output.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 13

Third-degree Price Discrimination

Price paid by buyers in a given group is the same for all units purchased. But price may differ across buyer groups.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14

Third-degree Price Discrimination

A monopolist manipulates market price by altering the quantity of product supplied to that market.

So the question “What discriminatory prices will the monopolist set, one for each group?” is really the question “How many units of product will the monopolist supply to each group?”

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 15

Third-degree Price Discrimination

Two markets, 1 and 2. y1 is the quantity supplied to market 1.

Market 1’s inverse demand function is p1(y1).

y2 is the quantity supplied to market 2. Market 2’s inverse demand function is p2(y2).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 16

Third-degree Price Discrimination

For given supply levels y1 and y2 the firm’s profit is

What values of y1 and y2 maximize profit?

( , ) ( ) ( ) ( ).y y p y y p y y c y y1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 17

Third-degree Price Discrimination

( , ) ( ) ( ) ( ).y y p y y p y y c y y1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2

The profit-maximization conditions are

y y

p y yc y y

y yy y

y1 11 1 1

1 2

1 2

1 2

1

0

( )( )

( )( )

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 18

Third-degree Price Discrimination

( , ) ( ) ( ) ( ).y y p y y p y y c y y1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2

The profit-maximization conditions are

y y

p y yc y y

y yy y

y1 11 1 1

1 2

1 2

1 2

1

0

( )( )

( )( )

y y

p y yc y y

y yy y

y2 22 2 2

1 2

1 2

1 2

2

0

( )( )

( )( )

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 19

Third-degree Price Discrimination

( )y y

y1 2

11

( )y yy

1 2

21

and so

the profit-maximization conditions are

y

p y yc y y

y y11 1 1

1 2

1 2( )

( )( )

and

y

p y yc y y

y y22 2 2

1 2

1 2( )

( )( )

.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 20

Third-degree Price Discrimination

y

p y yy

p y yc y y

y y11 1 1

22 2 2

1 2

1 2( ) ( )

( )( )

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 21

Third-degree Price Discrimination

y

p y yy

p y yc y y

y y11 1 1

22 2 2

1 2

1 2( ) ( )

( )( )

MR1(y1) = MR2(y2) says that the allocation y1, y2 maximizes the revenue from selling y1 + y2 output units.E.g., if MR1(y1) > MR2(y2) then an output unitshould be moved from market 2 to market 1to increase total revenue.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 22

Third-degree Price Discrimination

y

p y yy

p y yc y y

y y11 1 1

22 2 2

1 2

1 2( ) ( )

( )( )

The marginal revenue common to bothmarkets equals the marginal production cost if profit is to be maximized.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 23

Third-degree Price Discrimination

MR1(y1) MR2(y2)

y1 y2y1* y2*

p1(y1*) p2(y2*)

MC MC

p1(y1)p2(y2)

Market 1 Market 2

MR1(y1*) = MR2(y2*) = MC

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 24

Third-degree Price Discrimination

MR1(y1) MR2(y2)

y1 y2y1* y2*

p1(y1*) p2(y2*)

MC MC

p1(y1)p2(y2)

Market 1 Market 2

MR1(y1*) = MR2(y2*) = MC and p1(y1*) p2(y2*).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25

Third-degree Price Discrimination

In which market will the monopolist cause the higher price?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 26

Third-degree Price Discrimination

In which market will the monopolist cause the higher price?

Recall thatMR y p y1 1 1 1

11

1( ) ( )

MR y p y2 2 2 22

11

( ) ( ) .

and

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27

Third-degree Price Discrimination

In which market will the monopolist cause the higher price?

Recall that

But,

MR y p y1 1 1 11

11

( ) ( )

MR y p y2 2 2 22

11

( ) ( ) .

and

MR y MR y MC y y1 1 2 2 1 2( ) ( ) ( )* * * *

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 28

Third-degree Price Discrimination

p y p y1 11

2 22

11

11

( ) ( ) .* *

So

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 29

Third-degree Price Discrimination

p y p y1 11

2 22

11

11

( ) ( ) .* *

So

Therefore, if and only ifp y p y1 1 2 2( ) ( )* *

11

11

1 2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 30

Third-degree Price Discrimination

p y p y1 11

2 22

11

11

( ) ( ) .* *

So

Therefore, if and only ifp y p y1 1 2 2( ) ( )* *

11

11

1 21 2

.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 31

Third-degree Price Discrimination

p y p y1 11

2 22

11

11

( ) ( ) .* *

So

Therefore, if and only ifp y p y1 1 2 2( ) ( )* *

11

11

1 21 2

.

The monopolist sets the higher price in the market where demand is least own-price elastic.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 32

Two-Part Tariffs

A two-part tariff is a lump-sum fee, p1, plus a price p2 for each unit of product purchased.

Thus the cost of buying x units of product is

p1 + p2x.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 33

Two-Part Tariffs

Should a monopolist prefer a two-part tariff to uniform pricing, or to any of the price-discrimination schemes discussed so far?

If so, how should the monopolist design its two-part tariff?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 34

Two-Part Tariffs

p1 + p2x

Q: What is the largest that p1 can be?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 35

Two-Part Tariffs

p1 + p2x

Q: What is the largest that p1 can be?

A: p1 is the “market entrance fee” so the largest it can be is the surplus the buyer gains from entering the market.

Set p1 = CS and now ask what should be p2?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 36

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit

MC(y)

y

)y(pp2

Should the monopolistset p2 above MC?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit

y

CS

Should the monopolistset p2 above MC?p1 = CS.

MC(y))y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 38

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit

y

CS

Should the monopolistset p2 above MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

MC(y)PS)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 39

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit

y

CS

Should the monopolistset p2 above MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

MC(y)PSTotal profit

)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 40

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit

y

)y(pp2

Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?

MC(y)

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 41

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?p1 = CS.

CS

y

MC(y))y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 42

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

y

MC(y)CS

PS)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 43

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

y

MC(y)CS

Total profitPS)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 44

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

y

MC(y)CS

PS)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 45

Two-Part Tariffs

p(y)

y

$/output unit Should the monopolistset p2 = MC?p1 = CS.PS is profit from sales.

y

MC(y)CS

Additional profit from setting p2 = MC.

PS)y(pp2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 46

Two-Part Tariffs

The monopolist maximizes its profit when using a two-part tariff by setting its per unit price p2 at marginal cost and setting its lump-sum fee p1 equal to Consumers’ Surplus.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 47

Two-Part Tariffs

A profit-maximizing two-part tariff gives an efficient market outcome in which the monopolist obtains as profit the total of all gains-to-trade.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 48

Differentiating Products

In many markets the commodities traded are very close, but not perfect, substitutes.

E.g., the markets for T-shirts, watches, cars, and cookies.

Each individual supplier thus has some slight “monopoly power.”

What does an equilibrium look like for such a market?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 49

Differentiating Products

Free entry zero profits for each seller.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 50

Differentiating Products

Free entry zero profits for each seller.

Profit-maximization MR = MC for each seller.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 51

Differentiating Products

Free entry zero profits for each seller.

Profit-maximization MR = MC for each seller.

Less than perfect substitution between commodities slight downward slope for the demand curve for each commodity.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 52

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

Slight downward slope

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 53

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 54

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

MarginalCost

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 55

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

MarginalCost

y*

p(y*)

Profit-maximizationMR = MC

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 56

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

AverageCost

MarginalCost

y*

p(y*)

Profit-maximizationMR = MC

Zero profitPrice = Av. Cost

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 57

Differentiating Products

Such markets are monopolistically competitive.

Are these markets efficient? No, because for each commodity the

equilibrium price p(y*) > MC(y*).

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 58

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

AverageCost

MarginalCost

y*

p(y*)

Profit-maximizationMR = MC

Zero profitPrice = Av. Cost

MC(y*)

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 59

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

AverageCost

MarginalCost

y*

p(y*)

Profit-maximizationMR = MC

Zero profitPrice = Av. Cost

MC(y*)

ye

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 60

Differentiating Products

Each seller supplies less than the efficient quantity of its product.

Also, each seller supplies less than the quantity that minimizes its average cost and so, in this sense, each supplier has “excess capacity.”

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 61

Differentiating ProductsPrice

QuantitySupplied

Demand

MarginalRevenue

AverageCost

MarginalCost

y*

p(y*)

Profit-maximizationMR = MC

Zero profitPrice = Av. Cost

MC(y*) Excesscapacity

ye

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 62

Differentiating Products by Location

Think a region in which consumers are uniformly located along a line.

Each consumer prefers to travel a shorter distance to a seller.

There are n ≥ 1 sellers. Where would we expect these sellers

to choose their locations?

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 63

0

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 1 (monopoly) then the sellermaximizes its profit at x = ??

1x

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 64

0

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 1 (monopoly) then the sellermaximizes its profit at x = ½ and minimizes the consumers’ travel cost.

1x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 65

0

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 2 (duopoly) then the equilibrium locations of the sellers, A and B, are xA = ?? and xB = ??

1x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 66

0

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 2 (duopoly) then the equilibrium locations of the sellers, A and B, are xA = ?? and xB = ??

How about xA = 0 and xB = 1; i.e. the sellers separate themselves as much as is possible?

1x

½ A B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 67

10

Differentiating Products by Location

If xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all consumers in (½,1].

Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A increase its profit?

x

½ A B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 68

10

Differentiating Products by Location

If xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all consumers in (½,1].

Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A increase its profit? What if A moves to x’?

x

½ A B

x’

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 69

10

Differentiating Products by Location

If xA = 0 and xB = 1 then A sells to all consumers in [0,½) and B sells to all consumers in (½,1].

Given B’s location at xB = 1, can A increase its profit? What if A moves to x’? Then A sells to all customers in [0,½+½ x’) and increases its profit.

x

½ A B

x’x’/2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 70

10

Differentiating Products by Location

Given xA = x’, can B improve its profit by moving from xB = 1?

x

½ A B

x’

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 71

10

Differentiating Products by Location

Given xA = x’, can B improve its profit by moving from xB = 1? What if B moves to xB = x’’?

x

½ A B

x’ x’’

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 72

10

Differentiating Products by Location

Given xA = x’, can B improve its profit by moving from xB = 1? What if B moves to xB = x’’? Then B sells to all customers in ((x’+x’’)/2,1] and increases its profit.

So what is the NE?

x

½ A B

x’ x’’(1-x’’)/2

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 73

10

Differentiating Products by Location

Given xA = x’, can B improve its profit by moving from xB = 1? What if B moves to xB = x’’? Then B sells to all customers in ((x’+x’’)/2,1] and increases its profit.

So what is the NE? xA = xB = ½.

x

½ A&B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 74

10

Differentiating Products by Location

The only NE is xA = xB = ½. Is the NE efficient?

x

½ A&B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 75

10

Differentiating Products by Location

The only NE is xA = xB = ½. Is the NE efficient? No. What is the efficient location of A and

B?

x

½ A&B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 76

10

Differentiating Products by Location

The only NE is xA = xB = ½. Is the NE efficient? No. What is the efficient location of A and

B? xA = ¼ and xB = ¾ since this minimizes the consumers’ travel costs.

x

½

A

¼ ¾

B

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 77

10

Differentiating Products by Location

What if n = 3; sellers A, B and C?

x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 78

10

Differentiating Products by Location

What if n = 3; sellers A, B and C? Then there is no NE at all! Why?

x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 79

10

Differentiating Products by Location

What if n = 3; sellers A, B and C? Then there is no NE at all! Why? The possibilities are:

– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same point.– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same point.– (iii) Every seller locates at a different

point.

x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 80

10

Differentiating Products by Location

(iii) Every seller locates at a different point.

Cannot be a NE since, as for n = 2, the two outside sellers get higher profits by moving closer to the middle seller.

x

½

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 81

10

Differentiating Products by Location

(i) All 3 sellers locate at the same point.

Cannot be an NE since it pays one of the sellers to move just a little bit left or right of the other two to get all of the market on that side, instead of having to share those customers.

x

½ A

BC

C gets 1/3 of the market

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 82

10

Differentiating Products by Location

(i) All 3 sellers locate at the same point.

Cannot be an NE since it pays one of the sellers to move just a little bit left or right of the other two to get all of the market on that side, instead of having to share those customers.

x

½ BA C

C gets almost 1/2 of the market

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 83

10

Differentiating Products by Location

2 sellers locate at the same point. Cannot be an NE since it pays one of

the two sellers to move just a little away from the other.

x

½ BA C

A gets about 1/4 of the market

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 84

10

Differentiating Products by Location

2 sellers locate at the same point. Cannot be an NE since it pays one of

the two sellers to move just a little away from the other.

x

½ C

A gets almost 1/2 of the market

BA

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 85

10

Differentiating Products by Location

2 sellers locate at the same point. Cannot be an NE since it pays one of

the two sellers to move just a little away from the other.

x

½ C

A gets almost 1/2 of the market

BA

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 86

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 3 the possibilities are:– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same

point.– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same

point.– (iii) Every seller locates at a

different point. There is no NE for n = 3.

© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 87

Differentiating Products by Location

If n = 3 the possibilities are:– (i) All 3 sellers locate at the same

point.– (ii) 2 sellers locate at the same

point.– (iii) Every seller locates at a

different point. There is no NE for n = 3. However, this is a NE for every n ≥ 4.