© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

81
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Perfect Competition Chapter 11 Chapter 11

Transcript of © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

Page 1: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

Perfect CompetitionPerfect Competition

Chapter 11Chapter 11

Page 2: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 2

Perfect CompetitionPerfect Competition

The concept of competition is used in two ways in economics. Competition as a process is a rivalry

among firms. Competition as a market structure.

Page 3: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 3

Competition as a Competition as a ProcessProcess Competition involves one firm trying to

take away market share from another firm.

As a process, competition pervades the economy.

Page 4: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 4

A Perfectly Competitive A Perfectly Competitive MarketMarket A perfectly competitive market is one

which has highly restrictive assumptions, but which provides us with a reference point we can use in comparing different markets.

Page 5: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 5

A Perfectly Competitive A Perfectly Competitive MarketMarket In a perfectly competitive market:

The number of firms is large. The firms' products are identical. There is free entry and exit, that is,

there are no barriers to entry. There is complete information. Firms are profit maximizers. Both buyers and sellers are price

takers.

Page 6: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 6

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition The number of firms is large.

Large number of firms means that any one firm's output is very small when compared with the total market.

What one firm does has no bearing on market quantity or market price.

Page 7: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 7

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition Firms' products are identical.

This requirement means that each firm's output is indistinguishable from any other firm’s output.

Firms sell homogeneous product.

Page 8: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 8

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition There is free entry and free exit.

Firms are free to enter a market in response to market signals such as price and profit.

Barriers to entry are social, political, or economic impediments that prevent other firms from entering the market.

Page 9: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 9

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition There is free entry and free exit.

Technology may prevent some firms from entering the market.

There must also be free exit, without incurring a loss.

Page 10: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 10

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition There is complete information.

Firms and consumers know all there is to know about the market – prices, products, and available technology.

Any technological advancement would be instantly known to all in the market.

Page 11: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 11

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition Firms are profit maximizers.

The goal of all firms in a perfectly competitive market is profit and only profit.

There is no non-price competition (based on quality, brand name, or the like).

Page 12: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 12

The Necessary The Necessary Conditions for Perfect Conditions for Perfect CompetitionCompetition Both buyers and sellers are price

takers. A price taker is a firm or individual

who takes the market price as given. Neither supplier nor buyer possesses

market power.

Page 13: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 13

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition Supply is a schedule of quantities of

goods that will be offered to the market at various prices.

Page 14: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 14

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition This definition of supply requires the

supplier to be a price taker.

Page 15: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 15

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition Because of the definition of supply, if

any of the conditions required for perfect competition are not met, the formal definition of supply disappears.

Page 16: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 16

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition That the number of suppliers be large

means that they do not have the ability to collude (act together with other firms to control price or market share).

Page 17: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 17

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition Other conditions make it impossible for

any firm to forget about the hundreds of other firms waiting to replace their supply.

A firm's goal is specified by the condition of profit maximization.

Page 18: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 18

The Definition of The Definition of Supply and Perfect Supply and Perfect CompetitionCompetition Even if the conditions for a perfectly

competitive market are not met, supply forces are still strong and many of the insights of the competitive model can be applied to firm behavior in other market structures.

Page 19: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 19

Demand Curves for the Demand Curves for the Firm and the IndustryFirm and the Industry The demand curve facing the firm is

different from the industry demand curve.

A perfectly competitive firm’s demand is horizontal (perfectly elastic), even though the demand curve for the industry is downward sloping.

Page 20: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 20

Demand Curves for the Demand Curves for the Firm and the IndustryFirm and the Industry Each firm in a competitive industry is so

small that it does not need to lower its price in order to sell additional output.

Page 21: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 21

Market supply

Marketdemand

1,000 3,000

Price$10

8

6

4

2

0Quantity

Market Firm

Individual firm demand

Market Demand Curve Market Demand Curve Versus Individual Firm Versus Individual Firm Demand Curve, Demand Curve, Fig 11-1(a and b), p Fig 11-1(a and b), p 236236

10 20 30

Price$10

8

6

4

2

0Quantity

A B C

Page 22: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 22

The Profit-Maximizing The Profit-Maximizing Level of OutputLevel of Output The goal of the firm is to maximize

profits. When it decides what quantity to

produce it continually asks how changes in quantity would affect its profit.

Page 23: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 23

Profit-Maximizing Level Profit-Maximizing Level of Outputof Output Since profit is the difference between

total revenue and total cost, what happens to profit in response to a change in output is determined by marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC).

A firm maximizes profit when MC = MR.

Page 24: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 24

Profit-Maximizing Level Profit-Maximizing Level of Outputof Output Marginal revenue (MR) is the change

in total revenue associated with a change in quantity.

Marginal cost (MC) is the change in total cost associated with a one unit change in quantity.

Page 25: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 25

Marginal RevenueMarginal Revenue

Since a perfect competitor accepts the market price as given, for a perfectly competitive firm marginal revenue is equal to price (MR = P).

Page 26: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 26

Marginal CostMarginal Cost

Initially, marginal cost falls and then begins to rise.

Page 27: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 27

How to Maximize ProfitHow to Maximize Profit

To maximize profits, a firm should produce where marginal cost equals marginal revenue.

Page 28: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 28

How to Maximize ProfitHow to Maximize Profit

If marginal revenue does not equal marginal cost, a firm can increase profit by changing output.

The supplier will continue to produce as long as marginal cost is less than marginal revenue.

Page 29: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 29

How to Maximize ProfitHow to Maximize Profit

The supplier will cut back on production if marginal cost is greater than marginal revenue.

Thus, the profit-maximizing condition of a competitive firm is MC = MR = P.

Page 30: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 30

Marginal Cost, Marginal Marginal Cost, Marginal Revenue, and PriceRevenue, and Price Fig. 11- Fig. 11-

2a, p. 2372a, p. 237Price = MR Quantity Total Cost Marginal Cost

35 0 40        28

35 1 68        20

35 2 88        16

35 3 104        14

35 4 118        12

35 5 130        17

35 6 147        22

35 7 169        30

35 8 199        40

35 9 239        54

35 10 293  

Page 31: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 31

BC

Area1

P = D = MR

Costs

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

A

MC

Marginal Cost, Marginal Marginal Cost, Marginal Revenue, and Price,Revenue, and Price, Fig. 11- Fig. 11-

2b, p. 2372b, p. 237

Area 2

Page 32: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 32

The Marginal Cost The Marginal Cost Curve Is the Supply Curve Is the Supply CurveCurve The marginal cost curve, above the

point where price exceeds average variable cost, is the firm's supply curve

Page 33: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 33

The Marginal Cost The Marginal Cost Curve Is the Supply Curve Is the Supply CurveCurve The MC curve tells the competitive firm

how much it should produce at a given price.

The firm can do no better than producing the quantity at which marginal cost equals price which in turn equals marginal revenue.

Page 34: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 34

The Marginal Cost Curve The Marginal Cost Curve Is the Firm’s Supply Is the Firm’s Supply Curve,Curve, Fig. 11-3, p. 239Fig. 11-3, p. 239

A

CMarginal cost$70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0 1 Quantity2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

B

Cost, Price

Page 35: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 35

Firms Maximize Total Firms Maximize Total ProfitProfit Firms maximize total profit, not profit per

unit. As long as an increase in output yields

even a small amount of additional profit, a profit-maximizing firm will increase output.

Page 36: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 36

Profit Maximization Profit Maximization Using Total Revenue Using Total Revenue and Total Costand Total Cost Profit is maximized where the vertical

distance between total revenue and total cost is greatest.

At that output, MR (the slope of the total revenue curve) and MC (the slope of the total cost curve) are equal.

Page 37: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 37

TC TR

0

$385350315280245210175140105

7035

Quantity1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Profit Determination by Profit Determination by Total Cost and Revenue Total Cost and Revenue Curves, Curves, Fig. 11-4b, p 240Fig. 11-4b, p 240

Maximum profit =$81

$130

Loss

Loss

Profit

Total cost, revenue

Page 38: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 38

Total Profit at the Total Profit at the Profit-Maximizing Level Profit-Maximizing Level of Outputof Output While the P = MR = MC condition tells

us how much output a competitive firm should produce to maximize profit, it does not tell us the profit the firm makes.

Page 39: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 39

Determining Profit and Determining Profit and Loss From a Table of Loss From a Table of CostsCosts Profit can be calculated from a table of

costs and revenues. Profit is determined by total revenue

minus total cost.

Page 40: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 40

Determining Profit and Determining Profit and Loss From a Table of Loss From a Table of CostsCosts The profit-maximizing output choice is

not necessarily a position that minimizes either average variable cost or average total cost.

It is only the choice that maximizes total profit.

Page 41: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 41

Costs Relevant to a Firm, Costs Relevant to a Firm, Table 11-1, p 241Table 11-1, p 241

Page 42: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 42

Costs Relevant to a Firm, Costs Relevant to a Firm, Table 11-1, p 241Table 11-1, p 241

Page 43: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 43

Determining Profit and Determining Profit and Loss From a GraphLoss From a Graph Find output where MC = MR. The intersection of MC = MR (P)

determines the quantity the firm will produce if it wishes to maximize profits.

Page 44: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 44

Determining Profit and Determining Profit and Loss From a GraphLoss From a Graph Find profit per unit where MC = MR. To determine maximum profit, you must

first determine what output the firm will choose to produce.

See where MC equals MR, and then draw a line down to the ATC curve.

This is the profit per unit.

Page 45: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

(a) Positive economic profit (b) Zero economic profit (c) Economic loss

Determining Profits Determining Profits Graphically,Graphically, Fig. 11-5, p 243 Fig. 11-5, p 243

Quantity Quantity Quantity

Price65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10

5 0

65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10

5 01 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12

D

MC

A P = MR

B ATCAVC

E

Profit

C

MC

ATC

AVC

MC

ATC

AVC

Loss

65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10

5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 910 12

P = MRP = MR

Price Price

© The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 2000

Page 46: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 46

Zero Profit or Loss Zero Profit or Loss Where MC=MRWhere MC=MR Firms can also earn zero profit or even

a loss where MC = MR. Even though economic profit is zero, all

resources, including entrepreneurs, are being paid their opportunity costs.

Page 47: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 47

Zero Profit or Loss Zero Profit or Loss Where MC=MRWhere MC=MR In all three cases (profit, loss, zero

profit), determining the profit-maximizing output level does not depend on fixed cost or average total cost, but only where marginal cost equals price.

Page 48: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 48

The Role of Profits as The Role of Profits as Market Signals,Market Signals, Table 11-2, p 243 Table 11-2, p 243

Profit Calculation

Type of Profit Market Signal

> 0 Positive economic profit, or

Economic profit

Entry. Resources are drawn into the industry.

= 0 Zero economic profit,

Zero profit, or

Normal profit

Static. The industry is in long run equilibrium.

< 0 Economic loss Exit. Resources leave the industry.

Page 49: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 49

The Shutdown PointThe Shutdown Point

The firm will shut down if it cannot cover variable costs. A firm should continue to produce as

long as price is greater than average variable cost.

Once price falls below that point it will be cheaper to shut down temporarily and save the variable costs.

Page 50: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 50

The Shutdown PointThe Shutdown Point

The shutdown point is the point at which the firm will be better off by shutting down than it will if it stays in business.

Page 51: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 51

The Shutdown PointThe Shutdown Point

As long as total revenue is more than total variable cost, temporarily producing at a loss is the firm’s best strategy since it is taking less of a loss than it would by shutting down (loss minimization).

Page 52: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 52

MC

P = MR

2 4 6 8 Quantity

Price

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

ATC

AVC

Loss

A$17.80

The Shutdown The Shutdown Decision, Decision, Fig.11-6a, p 245Fig.11-6a, p 245

Page 53: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 53

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive Equilibrium, Equilibrium, Fig.11-6b, p 245Fig.11-6b, p 245

MC

P = MR

0

60

50

40

30

20

10

Price

2 4 6 8 Quantity

SRATC LRATC

Page 54: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 54

Short-Run Market Short-Run Market Supply and DemandSupply and Demand While the firm's demand curve is

perfectly elastic, the industry demand is downward sloping.

Industry supply is the sum of all firms’ supply curves.

Page 55: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 55

Short-Run Market Short-Run Market Supply and DemandSupply and Demand In the short run when the number of

firms in the market is fixed, the market supply curve is just the horizontal sum of all the firms' marginal cost curves.

Page 56: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 56

Short-Run Market Short-Run Market Supply and DemandSupply and Demand Since all firms have identical marginal

cost curves, a quick way of summing the quantities is to multiply the quantities from the marginal cost curve of a representative firm by the number of firms in the market.

Page 57: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 57

The market supplyThe market supply In the long run, the number of firms may

change in response to market signals, such as price and profit.

As firms enter the market in response to economic profits being made, the market supply shifts to the right.

As economic losses force some firms to exit, the market supply shifts to the left.

Page 58: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 58

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium Profits and losses are inconsistent with

long-run equilibrium. Profits create incentives for new firms to

enter, output will increase, and the price will fall until zero economic profits are made.

Only zero economic profit will stop entry.

Page 59: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 59

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium The existence of losses will cause some

firms to leave the industry. In a long run equilibrium firms make no

economic profit (the zero profit condition).

Page 60: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 60

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium Zero profit does not mean that the

entrepreneur does not get anything for his efforts.

Page 61: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 61

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium In order to stay in business the

entrepreneur must receive his opportunity cost or normal profits (the amount the owners of business would have received in the next-best alternative).

Page 62: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 62

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium Normal profits are included as a cost.

Economic profits are profits above normal profits.

Page 63: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 63

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium Even if some firm has super efficient

workers or machines that produce rent, it will not take long for competitors to match these efficiencies and drive down the price, until all economic profits are eliminated.

Page 64: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 64

Long-Run Competitive Long-Run Competitive EquilibriumEquilibrium The zero profit condition is enormously

powerful. As long as there is free entry and exit,

price will be pushed down to the average total cost of production.

Page 65: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 65

Adjustment from the Adjustment from the Short Run to the Long Short Run to the Long RunRun Industry supply and demand curves

come together to lead to long-run equilibrium.

Page 66: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 66

An Increase in DemandAn Increase in Demand

An increase in demand leads to higher prices and higher profits.

Existing firms increase output and new firms will enter the market, increasing industry output still more, price will fall until all profit is competed away.

Page 67: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 67

An Increase in DemandAn Increase in Demand

If the the market is a constant-cost industry, the new equilibrium will be at the original price but with a higher market output.

A market is a constant-cost industry if the long-run industry supply curve is perfectly elastic (horizontal).

Page 68: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 68

An Increase in DemandAn Increase in Demand

The original firms return to their original output but since there are more firms in the market, the total market output increases.

Page 69: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 69

An Increase in DemandAn Increase in Demand

In the short run, the price does more of the adjusting.

In the long run, more of the adjustment is done by quantity.

Page 70: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 70

Profit$9

10120

FirmPrice

Quantity

B

A

Market Response to an Market Response to an Increase in Demand,Increase in Demand,Fig. 11-Fig. 11-

7, p 2487, p 248

Market

Quantity

Price

0

B

A

C

MC

AC

SLR

S0SR

D0

7

700

$9

8401,200

D1

S1SR

7

Page 71: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 71

Long-Run Market Long-Run Market SupplySupply Two other possibilities exist:

Increasing-cost industry – factor prices rise as new firms enter the market and existing firms expand capacity.

Decreasing-cost industry – factor prices fall as industry output expands.

Page 72: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 72

An Increasing-Cost An Increasing-Cost IndustryIndustry If inputs are specialized, factor prices

are likely to rise when the increase in the industry-wide demand for inputs to production increases.

Page 73: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 73

An Increasing-Cost An Increasing-Cost IndustryIndustry This rise in factor costs would raise

costs for each firm in the industry and increase the price at which firms earn zero profit (break even).

Page 74: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 74

An Increasing-Cost An Increasing-Cost IndustryIndustry Therefore, in increasing-cost industries,

the long-run supply curve is upward sloping.

Page 75: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 75

A Decreasing-Cost A Decreasing-Cost IndustryIndustry If input prices decline when industry

output expands, individual firms' cost curves shift down.

The price at which firms break even now decreases, and the long-run market supply curve is downward sloping.

Page 76: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 76

An Example: Canadian An Example: Canadian Retail IndustryRetail Industry During the 1990s the Canadian retail

industry illustrated how a competitive market adjusts to changing market conditions.

Page 77: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 77

An Example: Canadian An Example: Canadian Retail IndustryRetail Industry Many retailers were lost or absorbed by

competitors: Eaton’s, Bretton’s, Pascal’s, Robinson’s, K-Mart and many others.

Initially, these firms saw their losses as the temporary result of reduced demand in a slowing economy.

Page 78: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 78

An Example: Canadian An Example: Canadian Retail IndustryRetail Industry As prices fell, P=MR fell below their

ATC. But since price remained above the

AVC, many firms closed their less profitable locations and continued to operate.

Page 79: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 79

An Example: Canadian An Example: Canadian Retail IndustryRetail Industry When demand did not recover, firms ran

out of options. Many firms realized as they moved into

the long run that they have to exit the Canadian retail industry.

Page 80: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

11 - 80

Price

Quantity

MC

ATC

AVC

P = MR

Loss

An Example: A An Example: A Shutdown Decision, Shutdown Decision, Fig. 11-Fig. 11-

8, p 2508, p 250

Page 81: © 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Perfect Competition Chapter 11.

© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.

Perfect CompetitionPerfect Competition

End of Chapter 11End of Chapter 11